text
stringlengths
27
15.8k
textbook_name
stringclasses
15 values
(cid:1) Self-Test 3 Suppose you could achieve full diversification in a portfolio constructed from stocks with an average beta of .5. If the standard deviation of the market is 20 percent per year, what is the standard deviation of the portfolio return? 414 SECTION FOUR FIGURE 4.9 (a) The slope of the fitted line shows that investors in the Windsor II mutual fund bore market risk slightly below that of the S&P 500 portfolio. Windsor II’s beta was .87. This was the average beta of the individual common stocks held by the fund. They also bore some unique risk, however; note the scatter of Windsor II’s returns above and below the fitted line. (b) The Vanguard 500 Portfolio is a fully diversified index fund designed to track the performance of the market. Note the fund’s beta (1.0) and the absence of unique risk. The fund’s returns lie almost precisely on the fitted line relating its returns to those of the S&P 500 portfolio. Windsor II return, percent 20 (cid:2)20 (cid:2)15 (cid:2)10 (cid:2)5 10 0 (cid:2)10 (cid:2)20 Index 500 return, percent 20 (cid:2)20 (cid:2)15 (cid:2)10 (cid:2)5 10 0 (cid:2)10 (cid:2)20 (a) (b) 5 10 15 20 Market return, percent 5 10 15 20 Market return, percent Risk and Return Earlier we looked at past returns on selected investments. The least risky investment was U.S. Treasury bills. Since the return on Treasury bills is fixed, it is unaffected by what happens to the market. Thus the beta of Treasury bills is zero. The most risky in- vestment that we considered was the market portfolio of common stocks. This has av- erage market risk: its beta is 1.0. Wise investors don’t run risks just for fun. They are playing with real money and therefore require a higher return from the market portfolio than from Treasury bills. The difference between the return on the market and the interest rate on bills is termed the market risk premium. Over the past 73 years the average market risk premium has been just over 9 percent a year. Of course, there is plenty of scope for argument as to whether the past 73 years constitute a typical period, but we will just assume here that 9 percent is the normal risk premium, that is, the additional return that an investor could reasonably expect from investing in the stock market rather than Treasury bills. MARKET RISK PREMIUM Risk premium of market portfolio. Difference between market return and return on risk-free Treasury bills. Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 415 In Figure 4.10a we plotted the risk and expected return from Treasury bills and the market portfolio. You can see that Treasury bills have a beta of zero and a risk-free re- turn; we’ll assume that return is 5 percent. The market portfolio has a beta of 1.0 and an assumed expected return of 14 percent.3 Now, given these two benchmarks, what expected rate of return should an investor require from a stock or portfolio with a beta of .5? Halfway between, of course. Thus in Figure 4.10b we drew a straight line through the Treasury bill return and the expected market return and marked with an X the expected return for a beta of .5, that is, 9.5 percent. This includes a risk premium of 4.5 percent above the Treasury bill return of 5 percent. You can calculate this return as follows: start with the difference between the ex- pected market return rm and the Treasury bill rate rf. This is the expected market risk premium. FIGURE 4.10 (a) Here we begin the plot of expected rate of return against beta. The first benchmarks are Treasury bills (beta = 0) and the market portfolio (beta = 1.0). We assume a Treasury bill rate of 5 percent and a market return of 14 percent. The market risk premium is 14 – 5 = 9 percent. (b) A portfolio split evenly between Treasury bills and the market will have beta = .5 and an expected return of 9.5 percent (point X). A portfolio invested 80 percent in the market and 20 percent in Treasury bills has beta = .8 and an expected rate of return of 12.2 percent (point Y). Note that the expected rate of return on any portfolio mixing Treasury bills and the market lies on a straight line. The risk
Brealey
premium is proportional to the portfolio beta. t n e c r e p , n r u t e r d e t c e p x E t n e c r e p , n r u t e r d e t c e p x E 14 5 0 9% (cid:1) market risk premium Treasury bills 14 12.2 9.5 5 0 Market portfolio 1.0 Beta (a) Market portfolio Y X .5 .8 1.0 Beta (b) 3 On past evidence the risk premium on the market is 9 percent. With a 5 percent Treasury bill rate, the ex- pected market return would be 5 + 9 = 14 percent. 416 SECTION FOUR Market risk premium = rm – rf = 14% – 5% = 9% Beta measures risk relative to the market. Therefore, the expected risk premium on any asset equals beta times the market risk premium: Risk premium on any asset = r – rf = β(rm – rf) With a beta of .5 and a market risk premium of 9 percent, Risk premium = β(rm – rf) = .5 × 9 = 4.5% The total expected rate of return is the sum of the risk-free rate and the risk premium: Expected return = risk-free rate + risk premium r = = rf 5% + β(rm – rf) + 4.5% = 9.5% You could have calculated the expected rate of return in one step from this formula: Expected return = r = rf + β(rm – rf) = 5% + (.5 × 9%) = 9.5% Theory of the CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM) relationship between risk and return which states that the expected risk premium on any security equals its beta times the market risk premium. This formula states the basic risk–return relationship called the capital asset pricing model, or CAPM. The CAPM has a simple interpretation: The expected rates of return demanded by investors depend on two things: (1) compensation for the time value of money (the risk-free rate rf), and (2) a risk premium, which depends on beta and the market risk premium. Note that the expected rate of return on an asset with β = 1 is just the market return. With a risk-free rate of 5 percent and market risk premium of 9 percent, r = rf + β(rm – rf) = 5% + (1 × 9%) = 14% (cid:1) Self-Test 4 What are the risk premium and expected rate of return on a stock with β = 1.5? Assume a Treasury bill rate of 6 percent and a market risk premium of 9 percent. WHY THE CAPM WORKS The CAPM assumes that the stock market is dominated by well-diversified investors who are concerned only with market risk. That makes sense in a stock market where trading is dominated by large institutions and even small fry can diversify at very low cost. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 3 How Would You Invest $1 Million? Have you ever daydreamed about receiving a $1 million check, no strings attached, from an unknown benefactor? Let’s daydream about how you would invest it. We have two good candidates: Treasury bills, which offer an absolutely safe return, and the market portfolio (possibly via the Vanguard index fund discussed earlier in this Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 417 material). The market has generated superior returns on average, but those returns have fluctuated a lot. (Look back to Figure 3.15.) So your investment policy is going to de- pend on your tolerance for risk. If you’re a cautious soul, you may invest only part of your money in the market port- folio and lend the remainder to the government by buying Treasury bills. Suppose that you invest 80 percent of your money in the market portfolio and lend out the other 20 percent to the government by buying U.S. Treasury bills. Then the beta of your portfo- lio will be a mixture of the beta of the market (β market = 1.0) and the beta of the T-bills (β T-bills = 0): Beta of portfolio = ( proportion × beta of) + (proportion × beta of) market T-bills in market market) β = (.8 × β = (.8 × 1.0) in T-bills T-bills) + (.2 × β + (.2 × 0) = .80 The fraction of funds that you invest in the market also affects your return. If you in- vest your entire million in the market portfolio, you earn the full market risk premium. But if you invest only 80 percent of your money in the market, you earn only 80 per- cent of the risk premium. risk premium = (proportion in × risk premium) + ( proportion in × market risk) on T-bills premium market T-bills Expected on portfolio = (.2 × 0) + (.8 × expected market risk premium) = .8 × expected market risk premium = .8 × 9 = 7.2% The expected return on your portfolio is equal to the risk-free interest rate plus the
Brealey
expected risk premium: Expected portfolio return = rportfolio = 5 + 7.2 = 12.2% In Figure 4.10b we show the beta and expected return on this portfolio by the letter Y. THE SECURITY MARKET LINE SECURITY MARKET LINE between expected return and beta. Relationship Example 3 illustrates a general point: by investing some proportion of your money in the market portfolio and lending (or borrowing)4 the balance, you can obtain any com- bination of risk and expected return along the sloping line in Figure 4.11. This line is generally known as the security market line. 4 Notice that the security market line extends above the market return at β = 1. How would you generate a portfolio with, say, β = 2? It’s easy, but it’s risky. Suppose you borrow $1 million and invest the loan plus $1 million in the market portfolio. That gives you $2 million invested and a $1 million liability. Your portfolio now has a beta of 2.0: Beta of portfolio = (proportion in market × beta of market) + (proportion in loan × beta of loan) β = (2 × β market) + (–1 × β loan) = (2 × 1.0) + (–1 × 0) = 2 Notice that the proportion in the loan is negative because you are borrowing, not lending money. By the way, borrowing from a bank or stockbroker would not be difficult or unduly expensive as long as you put up your $2 million stock portfolio as security for the loan. Can you calculate the risk premium and the expected rate of return on this borrow-and-invest strategy? 418 SECTION FOUR FIGURE 4.11 The security market line shows how expected rate of return depends on beta. According to the capital asset pricing model, expected rates of return for all securities and all portfolios lie on this line. n r u t e r d e t c e p x E rm rf 0 Security market line Beta 1.0 (cid:1) Self-Test 5 How would you construct a portfolio with a beta of .25? What is the expected return to this strategy? Assume Treasury bills yield 6 percent and the market risk premium is 9 percent. The security market line describes the expected returns and risks from investing different fractions of your funds in the market. It also sets a standard for other investments. Investors will be willing to hold other investments only if they offer equally good prospects. Thus the required risk premium for any investment is given by the security market line: Risk premium on investment = beta × expected market risk premium Look back to Figure 4.10b, which asserts that an individual common stock with β = .5 must offer a 9.5 percent expected rate of return when Treasury bills yield 5 percent and the market risk premium is 9 percent. You can now see why this has to be so. If that stock offered a lower rate of return, nobody would buy even a little of it—they could get 9.5 percent just by investing 50-50 in Treasury bills and the market. And if nobody wants to hold the stock, its price has to drop. A lower price means a better buy for investors, that is, a higher rate of return. The price will fall until the stock’s expected rate of return is pushed up to 9.5 percent. At that price and expected return the CAPM holds. If, on the other hand, our stock offered more than 9.5 percent, diversified investors would want to buy more of it. That would push the price up and the expected return down to the levels predicted by the CAPM. This reasoning holds for stocks with any beta. That’s why the CAPM makes sense, and why the expected risk premium on an investment should be proportional to its beta. (cid:1) Self-Test 6 Suppose you invest $400,000 in Treasury bills and $600,000 in the market portfolio. What is the return on your portfolio if bills yield 6 percent and the expected return on the market is 15 percent? What does the return on this portfolio imply for the expected return on individual stocks with betas of .6? Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 419 HOW WELL DOES THE CAPM WORK? The basic idea behind the capital asset pricing model is that investors expect a reward for both waiting and worrying. The greater the worry, the greater the expected return. If you invest in a risk-free Treasury bill, you just receive the rate of interest. That’s the
Brealey
reward for waiting. When you invest in risky stocks, you can expect an extra return or risk premium for worrying. The capital asset pricing model states that this risk premium is equal to the stock’s beta times the market risk premium. Therefore, Expected return on stock = risk-free interest rate + (beta × market risk premium) r = rf + β(rm – rf) How well does the CAPM work in practice? Do the returns on stocks with betas of .5 on average lie halfway between the return on the market portfolio and the interest rate on Treasury bills? Unfortunately, the evidence is conflicting. Let’s look back to the ac- tual returns earned by investors in low-beta stocks and in high-beta stocks. Imagine that in 1931 ten investors gathered in a Wall Street bar to discuss their port- folios. Each agreed to follow a different strategy. Investor 1 opted to buy each year the 10 percent of New York Stock Exchange stocks with the lowest betas; investor 2 chose the 10 percent with the next-lowest betas; and so on, up to investor 10, who agreed to buy the stocks with the highest betas. They also agreed that they would return 60 years later to compare results, and so they parted with much cordiality and good wishes. In 1991 the same 10 investors, now much older and wealthier, met again in the same bar. Figure 4.12 shows how they fared. Investor 1’s portfolio turned out to be much less risky than the market; its beta was only .49. However, investor 1 also realized the low- est return, 9 percent above the risk-free rate of interest. At the other extreme, the beta of investor 10’s portfolio was 1.52, about three times that of investor 1’s portfolio. But investor 10 was rewarded with the highest return, averaging 17 percent above the inter- est rate. So over this 60-year period returns did indeed increase with beta. As you can see from Figure 4.12, the market portfolio over the same 60-year period provides an average return of 14 percent above the interest rate5 and (of course) had a , i m u m e r p k s i r e g a r e v A t n e c r e p , 1 9 9 1 – 1 3 9 1 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Security market line Investor 1 M Market portfolio Investor 10 .2 .4 .6 .8 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.6 Portfolio beta Source: F. Black, “Beta and Return,” Journal of Portfolio Management 20:8–18 (Fall 1993). © 1993. Used by permission of Institutional Investor, Inc. 5 In Figure 4.12 the stocks in the “market portfolio” are weighted equally. Since the stocks of small firms have provided higher average returns than those of large firms, the risk premium on an equally weighted index is higher than on a value-weighted index. This is one reason for the difference between the 14 percent market risk premium in Figure 4.2 and the 9.4 percent premium reported in Table 3.9. FIGURE 4.12 The capital asset pricing model states that the expected risk premium from any investment should lie on the security market line. The dots show the actual average risk premiums from portfolios with different betas. The high-beta portfolios generated higher average returns, just as predicted by the CAPM. But the high-beta portfolios plotted below the security market line, and four of the five low-beta portfolios plotted above. A line fitted to the 10 portfolio returns would be flatter than the market line. 420 SECTION FOUR beta of 1.0. The CAPM predicts that the risk premium should lie on the upward- sloping security market line in Figure 4.12. Since the market provided a risk premium of 14 percent, investor 1’s portfolio, with a beta of .49, should have provided a risk pre- mium of a shade under 7 percent and investor 10’s portfolio, with a beta of 1.52, should have given a premium of a shade over 21 percent. You can see that while high-beta stocks performed better than low-beta stocks, the difference was not as great as the CAPM predicts. Figure 4.12 provides broad support for the CAPM, though it suggests that the line relating return to beta has been too flat. But recent years have been less kind to the CAPM. For example, if the 10 friends had invested their cash in 1966 rather than 1931,
Brealey
there would have been very little relation between their portfolio returns and beta. Does this imply that there has been a fundamental change in the relation between risk and re- turn in the last 30 years or did high-beta stocks just happen to perform worse during these years than investors expected? It is hard to be sure. There is little doubt that the CAPM is too simple to capture everything that is going on in the stock market. For example, it appears that stocks of small companies or stocks with low price-earnings ratios have offered higher rates of return than the CAPM pre- dicts. This has prompted headlines like “Is Beta Dead?” in the business press.6 It is not the first time that beta has been declared dead, but the CAPM is still being used. Only strong theories can have more than one funeral. The CAPM is not the only model of risk and return. It has several brothers and sis- ters as well as second cousins. However, the CAPM captures in a simple way two fun- damental ideas. First, almost everyone agrees that investors require some extra return for taking on risk. Second, investors appear to be concerned principally with the mar- ket risk that they cannot eliminate by diversification. That is why financial managers rely on the capital asset pricing model as a good rule of thumb. USING THE CAPM TO ESTIMATE EXPECTED RETURNS To calculate the returns that investors are expecting from particular stocks, we need three numbers—the risk-free interest rate, the expected market risk premium, and beta. In mid-1999, the interest rate on Treasury bills was about 4.8 percent. Assume that the market risk premium is about 9 percent. Finally, look back to Table 4.9, where we gave you betas of several stocks. Table 4.10 puts these numbers together to give an estimate of the expected return from each stock. Let’s take Exxon as an example: Expected return on Exxon = risk-free interest rate + (beta × expected market) risk premium r = 4.8% + (.61 × 9%) = 10.3% You can also use the capital asset pricing model to find the discount rate for a new capital investment. For example, suppose you are asked to analyze a proposal by Merck to expand its operations. At what rate should you discount the forecast cash flows? Ac- cording to Table 4.10 investors are looking for a return of 13.1 percent from investments with the risk of Merck stock. That is the opportunity cost of capital for Merck’s expan- sion project. In practice, choosing a discount rate is seldom this easy. (After all, you can’t expect 6 A. Wallace, “Is Beta Dead?” Institutional Investor 14 (July 1980), pp. 22–30. TABLE 4.10 Expected rates of return Stock Expected Return, % Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 421 Biogen Compaq Delta Airlines Exxon Ford Motor Co. MCI WorldCom Merck Microsoft PepsiCo Xerox 14.4 15.1 12.5 10.3 13.5 16.5 13.1 16.8 16.8 15.6 Note: Expected return = r = rf + β(rm – rf) = 4.8% + (β × 9%). to become a captain of finance simply by plugging numbers into a formula.) For ex- ample, you must learn how to estimate the return demanded by the company’s investors when the company has issued both equity and debt securities.7 We will come to such re- finements later. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 4 Comparing Project Returns and the Opportunity Cost of Capital You have forecast the cash flows on a project and calculated that its internal rate of re- turn is 15.0 percent. Suppose that Treasury bills offer a return of 5 percent and the ex- pected market risk premium is 9 percent. Should you go ahead with the project? To answer this question you need to figure out the opportunity cost of capital r. This depends on the project’s beta. For example, if the project is a sure thing, the beta is zero and the cost of capital equals the interest rate on Treasury bills: r = 5 + (0 × 9) = 5% If your project offers a return of 15.0 percent when the cost of capital is 5 percent, you should obviously go ahead.8 Sure-fire projects rarely occur outside finance texts. So let’s think about the cost of capital if the project has the same risk as the market portfolio. In this case beta is 1.0
Brealey
and the cost of capital is the expected return on the market: r = 5 + (1.0 × 9) = 14% The project appears less attractive than before but still worth doing. But what if the project has even higher risk? Suppose, for example, that it has a beta of 1.5. What is the cost of capital in this case? To find the answer, we plug a beta of 1.5 into our formula for r: 7 We could ignore this complication in the case of Merck, because Merck is financed almost entirely by com- mon stock. Therefore, the risk of its assets equals the risk of its stock. But most companies issue a mix of debt and common stock. 8 Earlier we described some special cases where you should prefer projects that offer a lower internal rate of return than the cost of capital. We assume here that your project is a “normal” one, and that you prefer high IRRs to low ones. 422 SECTION FOUR FIGURE 4.13 The expected return of this project is less than the expected return one could earn on stock market investments with the same market risk (beta). Therefore, the project’s expected return–risk combination lies below the security market line, and the project should be rejected. t n e c r e p , n r u t e r d e t c e p x E 18.5 15 14 5 0 Project Security market line 1.0 1.5 Beta r = 5 + (1.5 × 9) = 18.5% A project this risky would need a return of at least 18.5 percent to justify going ahead. The 15 percent project should be rejected. This rejection occurs because, as Figure 4.13 shows, the project’s expected rate of re- turn plots below the security market line. The project offers a lower return than investors can get elsewhere, so it is a negative-NPV investment. The security market line provides a standard for project acceptance. If the project’s return lies above the security market line, then the return is higher than investors could expect to get by investing their funds in the capital market and therefore is an attractive investment opportunity. (cid:1) Self-Test 7 Suppose that Merck’s expansion project is forecast to produce cash flows of $50 mil- lion a year for each of 10 years. What is its present value? Use data from Table 4.10. What would the present value be if the beta of the investment were .7? COMPANY COST OF CAPITAL Expected rate of return demanded by investors in a company, determined by the average risk of the company’s assets and operations. Capital Budgeting and Project Risk COMPANY VERSUS PROJECT RISK Long before the development of modern theories linking risk and return, smart finan- cial managers adjusted for risk in capital budgeting. They realized intuitively that, other things equal, risky projects are less desirable than safe ones and must provide higher rates of return. Many companies estimate the rate of return required by investors in their securities and use this company cost of capital to discount the cash flows on all new projects. Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 423 Since investors require a higher rate of return from a risky company, risky firms will have a higher company cost of capital and will set a higher discount rate for their new investment opportunities. For example, we showed in Table 4.9 that on past evidence Merck has a beta of .92 and the corresponding expected rate of return (see Table 4.10) is about 13 percent. According to the company cost of capital rule, Merck should use a 13 percent cost of capital to calculate project NPVs. This is a step in the right direction, but we must take care when the firm has issued securities other than equity. Moreover, this approach can get a firm in trouble if its new projects do not have the same risk as its existing business. Merck’s beta reflects in- vestors’ estimate of the risk of the pharmaceutical business and its company cost of cap- ital is the return that investors require for taking on this risk. If Merck is considering an expansion of its regular business, it makes sense to discount the forecast cash flows by the company cost of capital. But suppose that Merck is wondering whether to branch out into production of computer hardware. Its beta tells us nothing about the project
Brealey
cost of capital. That depends on the risk of the hardware business and the return that shareholders require from investing in such a business. The project cost of capital depends on the use to which that capital is put. Therefore, it depends on the risk of the project and not on the risk of the company. If a company invests in a low-risk project, it should discount the cash flows at a correspondingly low cost of capital. If it invests in a high-risk project, those cash flows should be discounted at a high cost of capital. PROJECT COST OF CAPITAL Minimum acceptable expected rate of return on a project given its risk. SEE BOX The nearby box discusses how companies decide on the discount rate. It notes, for example, that Siemens, a German industrial giant, uses 16 different discount rates, de- pending on the riskiness of each line of its business. (cid:1) Self-Test 8 The company cost of capital for Merck is about 13 percent (see Table 4.10); for Com- paq Computer it is about 15 percent. What would be the more reasonable discount rate for Merck to use for its proposed computer hardware division? Why? DETERMINANTS OF PROJECT RISK We have seen that the company cost of capital is the correct discount rate for projects that have the same risk as the company’s existing business, but not for those projects that are safer or riskier than the company’s average. How do we know whether a proj- ect is unusually risky? Estimating project risk is never going to be an exact science, but here are two things to bear in mind. First, we saw earlier that operating leverage increases the risk of a project. When a large fraction of your costs is fixed, any change in revenues can have a dramatic effect on earnings. Therefore, projects that involve high fixed costs tend to have higher betas. Second, many people intuitively associate risk with the variability of earnings. But much of this variability reflects diversifiable risk. Lone prospectors in search of gold look forward to extremely uncertain future earnings, but whether they strike it rich is not likely to depend on the performance of the rest of the economy. These investments have a high standard deviation but a low beta. FINANCE IN ACTION How High a Hurdle? It did raise some eyebrows at first. Two months ago, when Aegon, a Dutch life insurer known for taking care of its shareholders, bought Transamerica, a San Fran- cisco– based insurer, Aegon said it was expecting a re- turn of only 9% from the deal, well below the 11% “ hur- dle rate” it once proclaimed as its benchmark. Had this darling of the stock market betrayed its devoted in- vestors for the sake of an eye-catching deal? Not at all. Years of falling interest rates and rising eq- uity valuations have shrunk the cost of capital for firms such as Aegon. So companies that regularly adjust the hurdle rates they use to evaluate potential investment projects and acquisitions are not cheating their share- holders. Far from it: they are doing their investors a service. Unfortunately, such firms are rare in Europe. “ I don’t know many companies at all who lowered their hurdle rates in line with interest rates, so they’re all un- derinvesting,” says Greg Milano, a partner at Stern Stewart, a consultancy that helps companies estimate their cost of capital. This has a huge impact on corporate strategy. Com- panies generally make their investment decisions by discounting the net cash flows a project is estimated to generate to their present value. If the net present value is positive, the project should make shareholders better off. Generally speaking, says Paul Gibbs, an analyst at J.P. Morgan, an American bank, finance directors in America often review their hurdle rates; in continental Europe they do so sometimes, and in Britain, rarely. As a result, the Confederation of British Industry, a big- business lobby, worries about underinvestment, and of- ficials at the Bank of England grumble about firms’ re- luctance to lower hurdles. This reluctance seems
Brealey
surprising, since companies with high hurdle rates will tend to lose out in bidding for business assets or firms. The hurdle rate should reflect not only interest rates but also the riskiness of each individual project. For in- stance, Siemens, a German industrial giant, last year started assigning a different hurdle rate to each of its 16 businesses, ranging from household appliances to medical equipment and semiconductors. The hurdle rates— from 8% to 11%— are based on the volatility of shares in rival companies in the relevant industry, and are under constant review. Source: “How High a Hurdle?” The Economist, May 8, 1999, p. 82. © 1999 The Economist Newspaper Group, Inc. Reprinted with per- mission. Further reproduction prohibited. www.economist.com. What matters is the strength of the relationship between the firm’s earnings and the aggregate earnings of all firms. Thus cyclical businesses, whose revenues and earnings are strongly dependent on the state of the economy, tend to have high betas and a high cost of capital. By contrast, businesses that produce essentials, such as food, beer, and cosmetics, are less affected by the state of the economy. They tend to have low betas and a low cost of capital. DON’T ADD FUDGE FACTORS TO DISCOUNT RATES Risk to an investor arises because an investment adds to the spread of possible portfo- lio returns. To a diversified investor, risk is predominantly market risk. But in everyday usage risk simply means “bad outcome.” People think of the “risks” of a project as the things that can go wrong. For example, • A geologist looking for oil worries about the risk of a dry hole. • A pharmaceutical manufacturer worries about the risk that a new drug which re- verses balding may not be approved by the Food and Drug Administration. • The owner of a hotel in a politically unstable part of the world worries about the po- litical risk of expropriation. 424 Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 425 Managers sometimes add fudge factors to discount rates to account for worries such as these. This sort of adjustment makes us nervous. First, the bad outcomes we cited appear to reflect diversifiable risks which would not affect the expected rate of return de- manded by investors. Second, the need for an adjustment in the discount rate usually arises because managers fail to give bad outcomes their due weight in cash-flow fore- casts. They then try to offset that mistake by adding a fudge factor to the discount rate. For example, if a manager is worried about the possibility of a bad outcome such as a dry hole in oil exploration, he or she may reduce the value of the project by using a higher discount rate. This approach is unsound, however. Instead, the possibility of the dry hole should be included in the calculation of the expected cash flows to be derived from the well. Suppose that there is a 50 percent chance of a dry hole and a 50 percent chance that the well will produce oil worth $20 million. Then the expected cash flow is not $20 million but (.5 × 0) + (.5 × 20) = $10 million. You should discount the $10 mil- lion expected cash flow at the opportunity cost of capital: it does not make sense to dis- count the $20 million using a fudged discount rate. Expected cash-flow forecasts should already reflect the probabilities of all possible outcomes, good and bad. If the cash-flow forecasts are prepared properly, the discount rate should reflect only the market risk of the project. It should not have to be fudged to offset errors or biases in the cash-flow forecast. Summary How can you measure and interpret the market risk, or beta, of a security? The contribution of a security to the risk of a diversified portfolio depends on its market risk. But not all securities are equally affected by fluctuations in the market. The sensitivity of a stock to market movement is known as beta. Stocks with a beta greater than 1.0 are particularly sensitive to market fluctuations. Those with a beta of less than 1.0 are not so
Brealey
sensitive to such movements. The average beta of all stocks is 1.0. What is the relationship between the market risk of a security and the rate of re- turn that investors demand of that security? The extra return that investors require for taking risk is known as the risk premium. The market risk premium—that is, the risk premium on the market portfolio—averaged almost 9.4 percent between 1926 and 1998. The capital asset pricing model states that the expected risk premium of an investment should be proportional to both its beta and the market risk premium. The expected rate of return from any investment is equal to the risk- free interest rate plus the risk premium, so the CAPM boils down to r = rf + β(rm – rf) The security market line is the graphical representation of the CAPM equation. The security market line relates the expected return investors demand of a security to the beta. How can a manager calculate the opportunity cost of capital for a project? The opportunity cost of capital is the return that investors give up by investing in the project rather than in securities of equivalent risk. Financial managers use the capital asset pricing 426 SECTION FOUR Related Web Links Key Terms Quiz model to estimate the opportunity cost of capital. The company cost of capital is the expected rate of return demanded by investors in a company, determined by the average risk of the company’s assets and operations. The opportunity cost of capital depends on the use to which the capital is put. Therefore, required rates of return are determined by the risk of the project, not by the risk of the firm’s existing business. The project cost of capital is the minimum acceptable expected rate of return on a project given its risk. Your cash-flow forecasts should already factor in the chances of pleasant and unpleasant surprises. Potential bad outcomes should be reflected in the discount rate only to the extent that they affect beta. www.stanford.edu/~wfsharpe/ws/wksheets.htm William Sharpe’s site contains “portfolio opti- mizers,” spreadsheets that can be used to construct efficiently diversified portfolios www.riskmetrics.com RiskMetrics® Group maintains this site, which uses modern portfolio theory to help manage risk; some of the content at this site, including educational and demon- stration materials, is free. www.riskview.com A nice site with historical risk and return data as well as software to manage and measure portfolio risk www.finance.yahoo.com You can find stock betas as well as other risk measures and company profiles here market portfolio beta market risk premium capital asset pricing model (CAPM) security market line company cost of capital project cost of capital 1. Risk and Return. True or false? Explain or qualify as necessary. a. Investors demand higher expected rates of return on stocks with more variable rates of return. b. The capital asset pricing model predicts that a security with a beta of zero will provide an expected return of zero. c. An investor who puts $10,000 in Treasury bills and $20,000 in the market portfolio will have a portfolio beta of 2.0. d. Investors demand higher expected rates of return from stocks with returns that are highly exposed to macroeconomic changes. e. Investors demand higher expected rates of return from stocks with returns that are very sensitive to fluctuations in the stock market. 2. Diversifiable Risk. In light of what you’ve learned about market versus diversifiable (unique) risks, explain why an insurance company has no problem in selling life insurance to individuals but is reluctant to issue policies insuring against flood damage to residents of coastal areas. Why don’t the insurance companies simply charge coastal residents a premium that reflects the actuarial probability of damage from hurricanes and other storms? 3. Unique vs. Market Risk. Figure 4.14 plots monthly rates of return from 1993 to 1999 for the Snake Oil mutual fund. Was this fund well-diversified? Explain. 4. Risk and Return. Suppose that the risk premium on stocks and other securities did in fact
Brealey
Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 427 FIGURE 4.14 Monthly rates of return for the Snake Oil mutual fund and the Standard & Poor’s Composite Index. See problem 3. Snake Oil return, percent 5 4 3 2 1 Practice Problems (cid:2)3 (cid:2)2 (cid:2)1 1 2 3 Market return, percent 0 (cid:2)1 (cid:2)2 (cid:2)3 (cid:2)4 (cid:2)5 rise with total risk (that is, the variability of returns) rather than just market risk. Explain how investors could exploit the situation to create portfolios with high expected rates of re- turn but low levels of risk. 5. CAPM and Hurdle Rates. A project under consideration has an internal rate of return of 14 percent and a beta of .6. The risk-free rate is 5 percent and the expected rate of return on the market portfolio is 14 percent. a. Should the project be accepted? b. Should the project be accepted if its beta is 1.6? c. Why does your answer change? 6. CAPM and Valuation. You are considering acquiring a firm that you believe can generate expected cash flows of $10,000 a year forever. However, you recognize that those cash flows are uncertain. a. Suppose you believe that the beta of the firm is .4. How much is the firm worth if the risk-free rate is 5 percent and the expected rate of return on the market portfolio is 15 per- cent? b. By how much will you overvalue the firm if its beta is actually .6? 7. CAPM and Expected Return. If the risk-free rate is 6 percent and the expected rate of re- turn on the market portfolio is 14 percent, is a security with a beta of 1.25 and an expected rate of return of 16 percent overpriced or underpriced? 8. Using Beta. Investors expect the market rate of return this year to be 14 percent. A stock with a beta of .8 has an expected rate of return of 12 percent. If the market return this year turns out to be 10 percent, what is your best guess as to the rate of return on the stock? 9. Unique vs. Market Risk. Figure 4.15 shows plots of monthly rates of return on three stocks versus the stock market index. The beta and standard deviation of each stock is given beside its plot. a. Which stock is riskiest to a diversified investor? b. Which stock is riskiest to an undiversified investor who puts all her funds in one of these stocks? 428 SECTION FOUR FIGURE 4.15 These plots show monthly rates of return for (a) Exxon, (b) Polaroid, (c) Nike, and the market portfolio. See problem 9. (a) t n e c r e p , n r u t e r n o x x E 25 20 15 10 5 0 (cid:2)5 (cid:2)10 (cid:2)15 (cid:2)20 (cid:2)25 (cid:2)10 25 20 15 10 5 0 (cid:3)5 (cid:3)10 (cid:3)15 (cid:3)20 (cid:3)25 (cid:3)10 (b) t n e c r e p , n r u t e r d o r a o P l i Beta (cid:2) .61 Standard deviation (cid:2) 16% (cid:2)8 (cid:2)6 (cid:2)4 (cid:2)2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Market return, percent Beta (cid:2) .53 Standard deviation (cid:2) 22% (cid:3)8 (cid:3)6 (cid:3)4 (cid:3)2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Market return, percent c. Consider a portfolio with equal investments in each stock. What would this portfolio’s beta have been? d. Consider a well-diversified portfolio made up of stocks with the same beta as Exxon. What are the beta and standard deviation of this portfolio’s return? The standard devia- tion of the market portfolio’s return is 20 percent. e. What is the expected rate of return on each stock? Use the capital asset pricing model with a market risk premium of 8 percent. The risk-free rate of interest is 4 percent. 10. Calculating Beta. Following are several months’ rates of return for Tumblehome Canoe Company. Prepare a plot like Figure 4.7. What is Tumblehome’s beta? Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 429 FIGURE 4.15 (Continued) (c) t n e c r e p , n r u t e r e k N i 25 20 15 10 5 0 (cid:2)5 (cid:2)10 (cid:2)15 (cid:2)20 Beta (cid:2) 1.20 Standard deviation (cid:2) 31% (cid:2)25 (cid:3)10 (cid:2)8 (cid:2)6 (cid:2)4 (cid:2)2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Market return, percent Month Market Return, % Tumblehome Return, % 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 0 –1 –1 +1 +1 +2 +2 –2 –2 +1 –1 –2.5 –0.5 +2 +1 +4 +2 –2 –4 11. Expected Returns. Consider the following two scenarios for the economy, and the returns in each scenario for the market portfolio, an aggressive stock A, and a defensive stock D. Rate of Return Scenario Market Aggressive Stock A Defensive Stock D Bust Boom –8% 32 –10% 38 –6% 24 a. Find the beta of each stock. In what way is stock D defensive?
Brealey
b. If each scenario is equally likely, find the expected rate of return on the market portfolio and on each stock. c. If the T-bill rate is 4 percent, what does the CAPM say about the fair expected rate of re- turn on the two stocks? d. Which stock seems to be a better buy based on your answers to (a) through (c)? 12. CAPM and Cost of Capital. Draw the security market line when the Treasury bill rate is 10 percent and the market risk premium is 8 percent. What are the project costs of capital for new ventures with betas of .75 and 1.75? Which of the following capital investments have positive NPVs? 430 SECTION FOUR Project Beta Internal Rate of Return, % P Q R S T 1.0 0 2.0 0.4 1.6 20 10 25 16 25 13. CAPM and Valuation. You are a consultant to a firm evaluating an expansion of its current business. The cash-flow forecasts (in millions of dollars) for the project are: Years 0 1–10 Cash Flow –100 + 15 Based on the behavior of the firm’s stock, you believe that the beta of the firm is 1.4. As- suming that the rate of return available on risk-free investments is 5 percent and that the ex- pected rate of return on the market portfolio is 15 percent, what is the net present value of the project? 14. CAPM and Cost of Capital. Reconsider the project in the preceding problem. What is the project IRR? What is the cost of capital for the project? Does the accept–reject decision using IRR agree with the decision using NPV? 15. CAPM and Valuation. A share of stock with a beta of .75 now sells for $50. Investors ex- pect the stock to pay a year-end dividend of $2. The T-bill rate is 4 percent, and the market risk premium is 8 percent. If the stock is perceived to be fairly priced today, what must be investors’ expectation of the price of the stock at the end of the year? 16. CAPM and Expected Return. Reconsider the stock in the preceding problem. Suppose in- vestors actually believe the stock will sell for $54 at year-end. Is the stock a good or bad buy? What will investors do? At what point will the stock reach an “equilibrium” at which it again is perceived as fairly priced? 17. Portfolio Risk and Return. Suppose that the S&P 500, with a beta of 1.0, has an expected return of 13 percent and T-bills provide a risk-free return of 5 percent. a. What would be the expected return and beta of portfolios constructed from these two as- sets with weights in the S&P 500 of (i) 0; (ii) .25; (iii) .5; (iv) .75; (v) 1.0? b. Based on your answer to (a), what is the trade-off between risk and return, that is, how does expected return vary with beta? c. What does your answer to (b) have to do with the security market line relationship? 18. Portfolio Risk and Return. Suppose that the S&P 500, with a beta of 1.0, has an expected return of 15 percent and T-bills provide a risk-free return of 5 percent. a. How would you construct a portfolio from these two assets with an expected return of 12 percent? b. How would you construct a portfolio from these two assets with a beta of .4? c. Show that the risk premiums of the portfolios in (a) and (b) are proportional to their betas. 19. CAPM and Valuation. You are considering the purchase of real estate which will provide perpetual income that should average $50,000 per year. How much will you pay for the prop- erty if you believe its market risk is the same as the market portfolio’s? The T-bill rate is 5 percent, and the expected market return is 12.5 percent. 20. Risk and Return. According to the CAPM, would the expected rate of return on a security with a beta less than zero be more or less than the risk-free interest rate? Why would in- Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 431 vestors be willing to invest in such a security? Hint: Look back to the auto and gold exam- ple. 21. CAPM and Expected Return. The following table shows betas for several companies. Cal- culate each stock’s expected rate of return using the CAPM. Assume the risk-free rate of in- terest is 5 percent. Use a 9 percent risk premium for the market portfolio. Company Bristol-Myers Squibb
Brealey
General Mills McGraw-Hill Amazon.com Beta 1.13 0.70 0.92 2.48 22. CAPM and Expected Return. Stock A has a beta of .5 and investors expect it to return 5 percent. Stock B has a beta of 1.5 and investors expect it to return 13 percent. Use the CAPM to find the market risk premium and the expected rate of return on the market. 23. CAPM and Expected Return. If the expected rate of return on the market portfolio is 14 percent and T-bills yield 6 percent, what must be the beta of a stock that investors expect to return 10 percent? 24. Project Cost of Capital. Suppose General Mills is considering a new investment in the common stock of a publishing company. Which of the betas shown in the table in problem 21 is most relevant in determining the required rate of return for this venture? Explain why the expected return to General Mills stock is not the appropriate required return. 25. Risk and Return. True or false? Explain or qualify as necessary. a. The expected rate of return on an investment with a beta of 2 is twice as high as the ex- pected rate of return of the market portfolio. b. The contribution of a stock to the risk of a diversified portfolio depends on the market risk of the stock. c. If a stock’s expected rate of return plots below the security market line, it is underpriced. d. A diversified portfolio with a beta of 2 is twice as volatile as the market portfolio. e. An undiversified portfolio with a beta of 2 is twice as volatile as the market portfolio. 26. CAPM and Expected Return. A mutual fund manager expects her portfolio to earn a rate of return of 12 percent this year. The beta of her portfolio is .8. If the rate of return available on risk-free assets is 5 percent and you expect the rate of return on the market portfolio to be 15 percent, should you invest in this mutual fund? 27. Required Rate of Return. Reconsider the mutual fund manager in the previous problem. Explain how you would use a stock index mutual fund and a risk-free position in Treasury bills (or a money market mutual fund) to create a portfolio with the same risk as the manager’s but with a higher expected rate of return. What is the rate of return on that port- folio? 28. Required Rate of Return. In view of your answer to the preceding problem, explain why a mutual fund must be able to provide an expected rate of return in excess of that predicted by the security market line for investors to consider the fund an attractive investment op- portunity. 29. CAPM. We Do Bankruptcies is a law firm that specializes in providing advice to firms in financial distress. It prospers in recessions when other firms are struggling. Consequently, its beta is negative, –.2. a. If the interest rate on Treasury bills is 5 percent and the expected return on the market portfolio is 15 percent, what is the expected return on the shares of the law firm accord- ing to the CAPM? 432 SECTION FOUR Challenge Problem Solutions to Self-Test Questions FIGURE 4.16 Each point shows the performance of Anchovy Queen stock when the market is up or down by 1 percent. On average, Anchovy Queen stock follows the market; it has a beta of 1.0. b. Suppose you invested 90 percent of your wealth in the market portfolio and the remain- der of your wealth in the shares in the law firm. What would be the beta of your port- folio? 30. Leverage and Portfolio Risk. Footnote 4 in the material asks you to consider a borrow-and- invest strategy in which you use $1 million of your own money and borrow another $1 mil- lion to invest $2 million in a market index fund. If the risk-free interest rate is 4 percent and the expected rate of return on the market index fund is 12 percent, what is the risk premium and expected rate of return on the borrow-and-invest strategy? Why is the risk of this strat- egy twice that of simply investing your $1 million in the market index fund? 1 See Figure 4.16. Anchovy Queen’s beta is 1.0. 2 A portfolio’s beta is just a weighted average of the betas of the securities in the portfolio. In this case the weights are equal, since an equal amount is assumed invested in each of the
Brealey
stocks in Table 4.9. The average beta of these stocks is (1.07 + 1.14 + .88 + .61 + .97 + 1.30 + .92 + 1.33 + 1.33 + 1.20)/10 = 1.07. 3 The standard deviation of a fully diversified portfolio’s return is proportional to its beta. The standard deviation in this case is .5 × 20 = 10 percent. 4 r = rf + β(rm – rf) = 6 + (1.5 × 9) = 19.5% 5 Put 25 percent of your money in the market portfolio and the rest in Treasury bills. The portfolio’s beta is .25 and its expected return is rportfolio = (.75 × 6) + (.25 × 15) = 8.25% 6 rportfolio = (.4 × 6) + (.6 × 15) = 11.4% This portfolio’s beta is .6, since $600,000, which is 60 percent of the investment, is in the market portfolio. Investors in a stock with a beta of .6 would not buy it unless it also offered a rate of return of 11.4 percent and would rush to buy if it offered more. The stock price would adjust until the stock’s expected rate of return was 11.4 percent. Anchovy Queen return, percent 2 1.5 1 .5 0 (cid:2).4 (cid:2).2 (cid:2)1.0 (cid:2).8 (cid:2).6 .2 .4 .6 .8 1.0 Market return, percent (cid:2).5 (cid:2)1 (cid:2)1.5 (cid:2)2 Risk, Return, and Capital Budgeting 433 7 Present value = $50 million × 10-year annuity factor at 13.1% = $270.23 million If β = .7, then the cost of capital falls to r = 4.8% + (.7 × 9%) = 11.1% and the value of the 10-year annuity increases to $293.23 million. 8 Merck should use Compaq’s cost of capital. Merck’s company cost of capital tells us what expected rate of return investors demand from the pharmaceutical business. This is not the appropriate project cost of capital for Merck’s venture into computer hardware. THE COST OF CAPITAL Geothermal’s Cost of Capital Calculating the Weighted-Average Cost of Capital Calculating Company Cost of Capital as a Weighted Average Market versus Book Weights Taxes and the Weighted-Average Cost of Capital What If There Are Three (or More) Sources of Financing? Wrapping Up Geothermal Checking Our Logic Measuring Capital Structure Calculating Required Rates of Return The Expected Return on Bonds The Expected Return on Common Stock The Expected Return on Preferred Stock Big Oil’s Weighted-Average Cost of Capital Real Oil Company WACCs Interpreting the Weighted-Average Cost of Capital When You Can and Can’t Use WACC Some Common Mistakes How Changing Capital Structure Affects Expected Returns What Happens When the Corporate Tax Rate Is Not Zero Flotation Costs and the Cost of Capital Summary Jo Ann Cox needs to calculate the required rate of return on this geothermal plant. How should she do it? © Cameramann International, Ltd. 435 Y ou learned how to use the capital asset pricing model to estimate the ex- pected return on a company’s common stock. If the firm is financed wholly by common stock, then the stockholders own all the firm’s assets and are entitled to all the cash flows. In this case, the expected return required by investors in the common stock equals the company cost of capital.1 Most companies, however, are financed by a mixture of securities, including com- mon stock, bonds, and often preferred stock or other securities. Each of these securities has different risks and therefore investors in them look for different rates of return. In these circumstances, the company cost of capital is no longer the same as the expected return on the common stock. It depends on the expected return from all the securities that the company has issued. It also depends on taxes, because interest payments made by a corporation are tax-deductible expenses. Therefore, the company cost of capital is usually calculated as a weighted average of the after-tax interest cost of debt financing and the “cost of equity,” that is, the expected rate of return on the firm’s common stock. The weights are the fractions of debt and eq- uity in the firm’s capital structure. Managers refer to the firm’s weighted-average cost of capital, or WACC (rhymes with “quack”). Managers use the weighted-average cost of capital to evaluate average-risk capital investment projects. “Average risk” means that the project’s risk matches the risk of the
Brealey
firm’s existing assets and operations. This material explains how the weighted-average cost of capital is calculated in practice. After studying this material you should be able to (cid:1) Calculate a firm’s capital structure. (cid:1) Estimate the required rates of return on the securities issued by the firm. (cid:1) Calculate the weighted-average cost of capital. (cid:1) Understand when the weighted-average cost of capital is—or isn’t—the appropriate discount rate for a new project. Managers calculating WACC can get bogged down in formulas. We want you to un- derstand why WACC works, not just how to calculate it. Let’s start with “Why?” We’ll listen in as a young financial manager struggles to recall the rationale for project dis- count rates. Geothermal’s Cost of Capital Jo Ann Cox, a recent graduate of a prestigious eastern business school, poured a third cup of black coffee and tried again to remember what she once knew about project hur- 436 1 Investors will invest in the firm’s securities only if they offer the same expected return as that of other equally risky securities. When securities are properly priced, the return that investors can expect from their investments is therefore also the return that they require. The Cost of Capital 437 dle rates. Why hadn’t she paid more attention in Finance 101? Why had she sold her fi- nance text the day after passing the finance final? Costas Thermopolis, her boss and CEO of Geothermal Corporation, had told her to prepare a financial evaluation of a proposed expansion of Geothermal’s production. She was to report at 9:00 Monday morning. Thermopolis, whose background was geo- physics, not finance, not only expected a numerical analysis; he expected her to explain it to him. Thermopolis had founded Geothermal in 1993 to produce electricity from geother- mal energy trapped deep under Nevada. The company had pioneered this business and had been able to obtain perpetual production rights for a large tract on favorable terms from the United States government. When the 1999 oil shock drove up energy prices worldwide, Geothermal became an exceptionally profitable company. It was currently reporting a rate of return on book assets of 25 percent per year. Now, in 2001, production rights were no longer cheap. The proposed expansion would cost $30 million and should generate a perpetual after-tax cash flow of $4.5 mil- lion annually. The projected rate of return was 4.5/30 = .15, or 15 percent, much less than the profitability of Geothermal’s existing assets. However, once the new project was up and running, it would be no riskier than Geothermal’s existing business. Jo Ann realized that 15 percent was not necessarily a bad return—though of course 25 percent would have been better. Fifteen percent might still exceed Geothermal’s cost of capital, that is, exceed the expected rate of return that outside investors would de- mand to invest money in the project. If the cost of capital was less than the 15 percent expected return, expansion would be a good deal and would generate net value for Ge- othermal and its stockholders. Jo Ann remembered how to calculate the cost of capital for companies which used only common stock financing. Briefly she sketched the argument. “I need the expected rate of return investors would require from Geothermal’s real assets—the wells, pumps, generators, etc. That rate of return depends on the assets’ risk. However, the assets aren’t traded in the stock market, so I can’t observe how risky they have been. I can only observe the risk of Geothermal’s common stock. “But if Geothermal issues only stock—no debt—then owning the stock means own- ing the assets, and the expected return demanded by investors in the stock must also be the cost of capital for the assets.” She jotted down the following identities: Value of business = value of stock Risk of business = risk of stock Rate of return on business = rate of return on stock Investors’ required return from business = investors’ required return from stock
Brealey
Unfortunately, Geothermal had borrowed a substantial amount of money; its stock- holders did not have unencumbered ownership of Geothermal’s assets. The expansion project would also justify some extra debt finance. Jo Ann realized that she would have to look at Geothermal’s capital structure—its mix of debt and equity financing—and consider the required rates of return of debt as well as equity investors. Geothermal had issued 22.65 million shares, now trading at $20 each. Thus share- holders valued Geothermal’s equity at $20 × 22.65 million = $453 million. In addition, the company had issued bonds with a market value of $194 million. The market value of the company’s debt and equity was therefore $194 + 453 = $647 million. Debt was 194/647 = .3, or 30 percent of the total. “Geothermal’s worth more to investors than either its debt or its equity,” Jo Ann 438 SECTION FOUR mused. “But I ought to be able to find the overall value of Geothermal’s business by adding up the debt and equity.” She sketched a rough balance sheet: Assets Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity Market value of assets = value of Geothermal’s existing business Total value $647 $647 Market value of debt Market value of equity Total value $194 $453 $647 (30%) (70%) (100%) “Holy Toledo, I’ve got it!” Jo Ann exclaimed. “If I bought all the securities issued by Geothermal, debt as well as equity, I’d own the entire business. That means. . . .” She jotted again: Value of business = value of portfolio of all the firm’s debt and equity securities Risk of business = risk of portfolio Rate of return on business = rate of return on portfolio Investors’ required return on business investors’ required return on (company cost of capital) portfolio = “All I have to do is calculate the expected rate of return on a portfolio of all the firm’s securities. That’s easy. The debt’s yielding 8 percent, and Fred, that nerdy banker, says that equity investors want 14 percent. Suppose he’s right. The portfolio would contain 30 percent debt and 70 percent equity, so. . . .” Portfolio return = (.3 × 8%) + (.7 × 14%) = 12.2% It was all coming back to her now. The company cost of capital is just a weighted av- erage of returns on debt and equity, with weights depending on relative market values of the two securities. “But there’s one more thing. Interest is tax-deductible. If Geothermal pays $1 of in- terest, taxable income is reduced by $1, and the firm’s tax bill drops by 35 cents (as- suming a 35 percent tax rate). The net cost is only 65 cents. So the cost of debt is not 8 percent, but .65 × 8 = 5.2 percent. “Now I can finally calculate the weighted-average cost of capital: WACC = (.3 × 5.2%) + (.7 × 14%) = 11.4% “Looks like the expansion’s a good deal. Fifteen’s better than 11.4. But I sure need a break.” Calculating the Weighted-Average Cost of Capital Jo Ann’s conclusions were important. It should be obvious by now that the choice of the discount rate can be crucial, especially when the project involves large capital expendi- tures or is long-lived. The nearby box describes how a major investment in a power sta- tion—an investment with both a large capital expenditure and very long life—turned on the choice of the discount rate. Think again what the company cost of capital is, and what it is used for. We define FINANCE IN ACTION Choosing the Discount Rate Shortly before the British government began to sell off the electricity industry to private investors, controversy erupted over the industry’s proposal to build a 1,200- megawatt nuclear power station known as Hinkley Point C. The government argued that a nuclear station would both diversify the sources of electricity genera- tion and reduce sulfur dioxide and carbon dioxide emis- sions. Protesters emphasized the dangers of nuclear accidents and attacked the proposal as “ bizarre, dated and irrelevant.” At the public inquiry held to consider the proposal, opponents produced some powerful evidence that the nuclear station was also a very high cost option. Their principal witness, Professor Elroy Dimson, argued that
Brealey
the government-owned power company had employed an unrealistically low figure for the opportunity cost of capital. Had the government-owned industry used a more plausible figure, the cost of building and operating the nuclear station would have been higher than that of a comparable station based on fossil fuels. The reason why the choice of discount rate was so important was that nuclear stations are expensive to build but cheap to operate. If capital is cheap (i.e., the discount rate is low), then the high up-front cost is less serious. But if the cost of capital is high, then the high initial cost of nuclear stations made them uneconomic. Evidence produced at the inquiry suggested that the construction cost of a nuclear station was £1,527 mil- lion (or about $2.3 billion), while the cost of a compara- ble nonnuclear station was only £895 million. However, power stations last about 40 years and, once built, nu- clear stations cost much less to operate than nonnu- clear stations. If operated at 75 percent of theoretical capacity, the running costs of the nuclear station would be about £63 million a year, compared with running costs of £168 million a year for the nonnuclear station. The following table shows the cost advantage of the nuclear power station at different (real) discount rates. At a 5 percent discount rate, which was the figure used by the government, the present value of the costs of the nuclear option was nearly £1 billion lower than that of a station based on fossil fuels. But with a discount rate of 16 percent, which was the figure favored by Professor Dimson, the position was almost exactly reversed, so that the government could save nearly £1 billion by re- fusing the power company permission to build Hinkley Point C and relying instead on new fossil-fuel power stations. Eight years after the inquiry, the proposal to con- struct Hinkley Point C continues to gather dust, and British Energy, the privatized electric utility, has de- clared that it has no plans to build a new nuclear power station in the near future. Present value of the cost advantage to a nuclear rather than a fossil-fuel station (figures in billions of pounds) Real Discount Rate Present Value of the Cost Advantage of the Nuclear Station 5% 8 10 12 14 16 18 0.9 0.2 –0.1 –0.4 –0.7 –0.9 –1.2 Technical Notes: 1. Present values are measured at the date that the power station comes into operation. 2. The above table assumes for simplicity that construction costs for nuclear stations are spread evenly over the 8 years before the station comes into operation, while the costs for fossil-fuel stations are as- sumed to be spread evenly over the 4 years before operation. As a re- sult the present value of the costs of the two stations may differ slightly from the more precise estimates produced by Professor Dim- son. Source: Adapted with permission from Energy Economics, July 1989, E. Dimson, “The Discount Rate for a Power Station,” 1989, Elsevier Science Ltd., Oxford, England. it as the opportunity cost of capital for the firm’s existing assets; we use it to value new assets that have the same risk as the old ones. The weighted-average cost of capital is a way of estimating the company cost of capital; it also incorporates an adjustment for the taxes a company saves when it borrows. 439 440 SECTION FOUR CALCULATING COMPANY COST OF CAPITAL AS A WEIGHTED AVERAGE Calculating the company cost of capital is straightforward, though not always easy, when only common stock is outstanding. For example, a financial manager could esti- mate beta and calculate shareholders’ required rate of return using the capital asset pric- ing model (CAPM). This would be the expected rate of return investors require on the company’s existing assets and operations and also the expected return they will require on new investments that do not change the company’s market risk. But most companies issue debt as well as equity. The company cost of capital is a weighted average of the returns demanded by
Brealey
debt and equity investors. The weighted average is the expected rate of return investors would demand on a portfolio of all the firm’s outstanding securities. Let’s review Jo Ann Cox’s calculations for Geothermal. To avoid complications, we’ll ignore taxes for the next two or three pages. The total market value of Geother- mal, which we denote as V, is the sum of the values of the outstanding debt D and the equity E. Thus firm value is V = D + E = $194 million + $453 million = $647 million. Debt accounts for 30 percent of the value and equity accounts for the remaining 70 percent. If you held all the shares and all the debt, your investment in Geothermal would be V = $647 million. Between them, the debt and equity holders own all the firm’s assets. So V is also the value of these assets—the value of Geothermal’s existing business. Suppose that Geothermal’s equity investors require a 14 percent rate of return on their investment in the stock. What rate of return must a new project provide in order that all investors—both debtholders and stockholders—earn a fair rate of return? The debtholders require a rate of return of rdebt = 8 percent. So each year the firm will need × D = .08 × $194 million = $15.52 million. The shareholders, who to pay interest of rdebt have invested in a riskier security, require a return of requity = 14 percent on their investment of $453 million. Thus in order to keep shareholders happy, the company × E = .14 × $453 million = $63.42 million. To satisfy needs additional income of requity both the debtholders and the shareholders, Geothermal needs to earn $15.52 million + $63.42 million = $78.94 million. This is equivalent to earning a return of rassets = 78.94/647 = .122, or 12.2 percent. Figure 4.17 illustrates the reasoning behind our calculations. The figure shows the amount of income needed to satisfy the debt and equity investors. Notice that debthold- ers account for 30 percent of Geothermal’s capital structure but receive less than 30 per- cent of its expected income. On the other hand, they bear less than a 30 percent share of risk, since they have first cut at the company’s income, and also first claim on its as- sets if the company gets in trouble. Shareholders expect a return of more than 70 per- cent of Geothermal’s income because they bear correspondingly more risk. However, if you buy all Geothermal’s debt and equity, you own its assets lock, stock, and barrel. You receive all the income and bear all the risks. The expected rate of return you’d require on this portfolio of securities is the same return you’d require from unen- cumbered ownership of the business. This rate of return—12.2 percent, ignoring taxes—is therefore the company cost of capital and the required rate of return from an equal-risk expansion of the business. The bottom line (still ignoring taxes) is Company cost of capital = weighted average of debt and equity returns The Cost of Capital 441 FIGURE 4.17 Geothermal’s debtholders account for 30 percent of the company’s capital structure, but they get a smaller share of income because their return is guaranteed by the company. Geothermal’s stockholders bear more risk and receive, on average, greater return. Of course if you buy all the debt and all the equity, you get all the income. Share of capital structure Share of income Debt $194 (30%) Debt $15.5 (19.7%) Equity $453 (70%) Equity $63.4 (80.3%) Total (cid:2) $647 (100%) Total (cid:2) $78.9 (100%) × D) and the equity The underlying algebra is simple. Debtholders need income of (rdebt × D) + investors need income of (requity × E). The amount of their combined existing investment in the company is V. So (requity to calculate the return that is needed on the assets, we simply divide the income by the investment: × E). The total income that is needed is (rdebt rassets = = total income value of investment (D (cid:1) rdebt) + (E (cid:1) requity) V For Geothermal, = ( D (cid:1) rdebt) + ( E (cid:1) requity) V V
Brealey
(cid:1) Self-Test 1 rassets = (.30 × 8%) + (.70 × 14%) = 12.2% This figure is the expected return demanded by investors in the firm’s assets. Hot Rocks Corp., one of Geothermal’s competitors, has issued long-term bonds with a market value of $50 million and an expected return of 9.0 percent. It has 4 million shares outstanding trading for $10 each. At this price the shares offer an expected re- turn of 17 percent. What is the weighted-average cost of capital for Hot Rocks’s assets and operations? Assume Hot Rocks pays no taxes. MARKET VERSUS BOOK WEIGHTS The company cost of capital is the expected rate of return that investors demand from the company’s assets and operations. The cost of capital must be based on what investors are actually willing to pay for the company’s outstanding securities—that is, based on the securities’ market values. 442 SECTION FOUR Market values usually differ from the values recorded by accountants in the com- pany’s books. The book value of Geothermal’s equity reflects money raised in the past from shareholders or reinvested by the firm on their behalf. If investors recognize Ge- othermal’s excellent prospects, the market value of equity may be much higher than book, and the debt ratio will be lower when measured in terms of market values rather than book values. Financial managers use book debt-to-value ratios for various other purposes, and sometimes they unthinkingly look to the book ratios when calculating weights for the company cost of capital. That’s a mistake, because the company cost of capital meas- ures what investors want from the company, and it depends on how they value the com- pany’s securities. That value depends on future profits and cash flows, not on account- ing history. Book values, while useful for many other purposes, only measure net cumulative historical outlays; they don’t generally measure market values accurately. (cid:1) Self-Test 2 Here is a book balance sheet for Duane S. Burg Associates. Figures are in millions. Assets Assets (book value) Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity $75 $75 Debt Equity $25 50 $75 Unfortunately, the company has fallen on hard times. The 6 million shares are trading for only $4 apiece, and the market value of its debt securities is 20 percent below the face (book) value. Because of the company’s large cumulative losses, it will pay no taxes on future income. Suppose shareholders now demand a 20 percent expected rate of return. The bonds are now yielding 14 percent. What is the weighted-average cost of capital? TAXES AND THE WEIGHTED-AVERAGE COST OF CAPITAL Thus far in this section our examples have ignored taxes. Taxes are important because interest payments are deducted from income before tax is calculated. Therefore, the cost to the company of an interest payment is reduced by the amount of this tax saving. The interest rate on Geothermal’s debt is rdebt = 8 percent. However, with a corporate tax rate of Tc = .35, the government bears 35 percent of the cost of the interest payments. The government doesn’t send the firm a check for this amount, but the income tax that the firm pays is reduced by 35 percent of its interest expense. Therefore, Geothermal’s after-tax cost of debt is only 100 – 35 = 65 percent of the 8 percent pretax cost: After-tax cost of debt = pretax cost (cid:1) (1 – tax rate) (cid:1) (1 – Tc) = rdebt = 8% × (1 – .35) = 5.2% We can now adjust our calculation of Geothermal’s cost of capital to recognize the tax saving associated with interest payments: Company cost of capital, after-tax = (.3 × 5.2%) + (.7 × 14%) = 11.4% (cid:1) Self-Test 3 WEIGHTED-AVERAGE COST OF CAPITAL (WACC) Expected rate of return on a portfolio of all the firm’s securities, adjusted for tax savings due to interest payments. (cid:1) Self-Test 4 The Cost of Capital 443 Criss-cross Industries has earnings before interest and taxes (EBIT) of $10 million. In- terest payments are $2 million and the corporate tax rate is 35 percent. Construct a sim- ple income statement to show that the debt interest reduces the taxes the firm owes to
Brealey
the government. How much more tax would Criss-cross pay if it were financed solely by equity? Now we’re back to the weighted-average cost of capital, or WACC. The general formula is WACC = [ D (cid:1) (1 – Tc)rdebt]+( E (cid:1) requity) V V Calculate WACC for Hot Rocks (Self-Test 1) and Burg Associates (Self-Test 2) assum- ing the companies face a 35 percent corporate income tax rate. WHAT IF THERE ARE THREE (OR MORE) SOURCES OF FINANCING? We have simplified our discussion of the cost of capital by assuming the firm has only two classes of securities: debt and equity. Even if the firm has issued other classes of securities, our general approach to calculating WACC remains unchanged. You simply calculate the weighted-average after-tax return of each security type. For example, suppose the firm also has outstanding preferred stock. Preferred stock has some of the characteristics of both common stock and fixed-income securities. Like bonds, preferred stock promises to pay a given, usually level, stream of dividends. Un- like bonds, however, there is no maturity date for the preferred stock. The promised div- idends constitute a perpetuity as long as the firm stays in business. Moreover, a failure to come up with the cash to pay the dividends does not push the firm into bankruptcy. Instead, dividends owed simply cumulate; the common stockholders do not receive div- idends until the accumulated preferred dividends have been paid. Finally, unlike inter- est payments, preferred stock dividends are not considered tax-deductible expenses. How would we calculate WACC for a firm with preferred stock as well as common stock and bonds outstanding? Using P to denote preferred stock, we simply generalize the formula for WACC as follows: WACC = [ D (cid:1) (1 – Tc)rdebt]+ (P (cid:1) rpreferred) + ( E (cid:1) requity) V V V Let’s try an example to make this concrete. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 1 Weighted-Average Cost of Capital for Executive Fruit Unlike Geothermal, Executive Fruit has issued three types of securities—debt, pre- ferred stock, and common stock. The debtholders require a return of 6 percent, the pre- ferred stockholders require an expected return of 12 percent, and the common stock- holders require 18 percent. The debt is valued at $4 million (D = 4), the preferred stock 444 SECTION FOUR at $2 million (P = 2), and the common stock at $6 million (E = 6). The corporate tax rate is 35 percent. What is Executive’s weighted-average cost of capital? Don’t be put off by the third security, preferred stock. We simply work through the following three steps. Step 1. Calculate the value of each security as a proportion of the firm’s value. Firm value is V = D + P + E = 4 + 2 + 6 = $12 million. So D/V = 4/12 = .33; P/V = 2/12 = .17; and E/V = 6/12 = .5. Step 2. Determine the required rate of return on each security. We have already given you the answers: rdebt = 6%, rpreferred = 12%, and requity = 18%.2 Step 3. Calculate a weighted average of the cost of the after-tax return on debt and the return on the preferred and common stock: Weighted-average cost of capital = [ D × (1 – Tc)rdebt] + (P × rpreferred) = (E × requity) V V V = [.33 × (1 – .35) 6%] + (.17 × 12%) + (.5 × 18%) = 12.3% WRAPPING UP GEOTHERMAL We now turn one last time to Jo Ann Cox and Geothermal’s proposed expansion. We want to make sure that she—and you—know how to use the weighted-average cost of capital. Remember that the proposed expansion cost $30 million and should generate a per- petual cash flow of $4.5 million per year. A simple cash-flow worksheet might look like this:3 Revenue – Operating expenses = Pretax operating cash flow – Tax at 35% After-tax cash flow $10.00 million – 3.08 6.92 – 2.42 $ 4.50 million Note that these cash flows do not include the tax benefits of using debt. Geothermal’s managers and engineers forecast revenues, costs, and taxes as if the project was to be all-equity financed. The interest tax shields generated by the project’s actual debt financing are not forgotten, however. They are accounted for by using the
Brealey
after-tax cost of debt in the weighted-average cost of capital. Project net present value is calculated by discounting the cash flow (which is a per- petuity) at Geothermal’s 11.4 percent weighted-average cost of capital: NPV = –30 + 4.5 .114 = +$9.5 million Expansion will thus add $9.5 million to the net wealth of Geothermal’s owners. 2 Financial managers often use “equity” to refer to common stock, even though a firm’s equity strictly includes both common and preferred stock. We continue to use requity to refer specifically to the expected return on the common stock. 3 For this example we ignore depreciation, a noncash but tax-deductible expense. (If the project were really perpetual, why depreciate?) The Cost of Capital 445 CHECKING OUR LOGIC Any project offering a rate of return more than 11.4 percent will have a positive NPV, assuming that the project has the same risk and financing as Geothermal’s business. A project offering exactly 11.4 percent would be just break-even; it would generate just enough cash to satisfy both debtholders and stockholders. Let’s check that out. Suppose the proposed expansion had revenues of only $8.34 million and after-tax cash flows of $3.42 million: Revenue – Operating costs = Pretax operating cash flow – Tax at 35% After-tax cash flow $8.34 million – 3.08 5.26 – 1.84 $3.42 million With an investment of $30 million, the internal rate of return on this perpetuity is ex- actly 11.4 percent: NPV is exactly zero: Rate of return = 3.42 30 = .114, or 11.4% NPV = –30 + 3.42 .114 = 0 When we calculated Geothermal’s weighted-average cost of capital, we recognized that the company’s debt ratio was 30 percent. When Geothermal’s analysts use the weighted-average cost of capital to evaluate the new project, they are assuming that the $30 million additional investment would support the issue of additional debt equal to 30 percent of the investment, or $9 million. The remaining $21 million is provided by the shareholders. The following table shows how the cash flows would be shared between the debtholders and shareholders. We start with the pretax operating cash flow of $5.26 mil- lion: Cash flow before tax and interest – Interest payment (.08 × $9 million) = Pretax cash flow – Tax at 35% Cash flow after tax $5.26 million – .72 4.54 – 1.59 $2.95 million Project cash flows before tax and interest are forecast to be $5.26 million. Out of this figure, Geothermal needs to pay interest of 8 percent of $9 million, which comes to $.72 million. This leaves a pretax cash flow of $4.54 million, on which the company must pay tax. Taxes equal .35 × 4.54 = $1.59 million. Shareholders are left with $2.95 mil- lion, just enough to give them the 14 percent return that they need on their $21 million investment. (Note that 2.95/21 = .14, or 14 percent.) Therefore, everything checks out. If a project has zero NPV when the expected cash flows are discounted at the weighted-average cost of capital, then the project’s cash flows are just sufficient to give debtholders and shareholders the returns they require. 446 SECTION FOUR Measuring Capital Structure We have explained the formula for calculating the weighted-average cost of capital. We will now look at some of the practical problems in applying that formula. Suppose that the financial manager of Big Oil has asked you to estimate the firm’s weighted-average cost of capital. Your first step is to work out Big Oil’s capital structure. But where do you get the data? Financial managers usually start with the company’s accounts, which show the book value of debt and equity, whereas the weighted-average cost of capital formula calls for their market values. A little work and a dash of judgment are needed to go from one to the other. Table 4.11 shows the debt and equity issued by Big Oil. The firm has borrowed $200 million from banks and has issued a further $200 million of long-term bonds. These bonds have a coupon rate of 8 percent and mature at the end of 12 years. Finally, there are 100 million shares of common stock outstanding, each with a par value of $1.00.
Brealey
But the accounts also recognize that Big Oil has in past years plowed back into the firm $300 million of retained earnings. The total book value of the equity shown in the ac- counts is $100 million + $300 million = $400 million. The figures shown in Table 4.11 are taken from Big Oil’s annual accounts and are therefore book values. Sometimes the differences between book values and market val- ues are negligible. For example, consider the $200 million that Big Oil owes the bank. The interest rate on bank loans is usually linked to the general level of interest rates. Thus if interest rates rise, the rate charged on Big Oil’s loan also rises to maintain the loan’s value. As long as Big Oil is reasonably sure to repay the loan, the loan is worth close to $200 million. Most financial managers most of the time are willing to accept the book value of bank debt as a fair approximation of its market value. What about Big Oil’s long-term bonds? Since the bonds were originally issued, long- term interest rates have risen to 9 percent.4 We can calculate the value today of each bond as follows.5 There are 12 coupon payments of .08 × 200 = $16 million, and then repayment of face value 12 years out. Thus the final cash payment to the bondholders is $216 million. All the bond’s cash flows are discounted back at the current interest rate of 9 percent. PV = 16 1.09 + 16 (1.09)2 + 16 (1.09)3 + . . . + 216 (1.09)12 = $185.7 TABLE 4.11 The book value of Big Oil’s debt and equity (dollar figures in millions) Bank debt Long-term bonds (12-year maturity, 8% coupon) Common stock (100 million shares, par value $1) Retained earnings Total $200 200 100 300 $800 25.0% 25.0 12.5 37.5 100.0% 4 If Big Oil’s bonds are traded, you can simply look up their price. But many bonds are not regularly traded, and in such cases you need to infer their price by calculating the bond’s value using the rate of interest of- fered by similar bonds. 5 We assume that coupon payments are annual. Most bonds in the United States actually pay interest twice a year. TABLE 4.12 The market values of Big Oil’s debt and equity (dollar figures in millions) Bank debt Long-term bonds Total debt Common stock, 100 million shares at $12 Total $ 200.0 185.7 385.7 1,200.0 $1,585.7 12.6% 11.7 24.3 75.7 100.0% The Cost of Capital 447 Therefore, the bonds are worth only $185.7 million, 92.8 percent of their face value. If you used the book value of Big Oil’s long-term debt rather than its market value, you would be a little bit off in your calculation of the weighted-average cost of capital, but probably not seriously so. The really big errors are likely to arise if you use the book value of equity rather than its market value. The $400 million book value of Big Oil’s equity measures the total amount of cash that the firm has raised from shareholders in the past or has retained and invested on their behalf. But perhaps Big Oil has been able to find projects that were worth more than they originally cost or perhaps the value of the assets has increased with inflation. Perhaps investors see great future investment opportunities for the com- pany. All these considerations determine what investors are willing to pay for Big Oil’s common stock. In September 2001 Big Oil stock was $12 a share. Thus the total market value of the stock was Number of shares × share price = 100 million × $12 = $1,200 million In Table 4.12 we show the market value of Big Oil’s debt and equity. You can see that debt accounts for 24.3 percent of company value (D/V = .243) and equity accounts for 75.7 percent (E/V = .757). These are the proportions to use when calculating the weighted-average cost of capital. Notice that if you looked only at the book values shown in the company accounts, you would mistakenly conclude that debt and equity each accounted for 50 percent of value. (cid:1) Self-Test 5 Here is the capital structure shown in Executive Fruit’s book balance sheet: Debt Preferred stock Common stock Total $4.1 million 2.2 2.8 $9.1 million 45 % 24.2 30.8 100 % Explain why the percentage weights given above should not be used in calculating Ex-
Brealey
ecutive Fruit’s WACC. Calculating Required Rates of Return To calculate Big Oil’s weighted-average cost of capital, you also need the rate of return that investors require from each security. 448 SECTION FOUR THE EXPECTED RETURN ON BONDS We know that Big Oil’s bonds offer a yield to maturity of 9 percent. As long as the com- pany does not go belly-up, that is the rate of return investors can expect to earn from holding Big Oil’s bonds. If there is any chance that the firm may be unable to repay the debt, however, the yield to maturity of 9 percent represents the most favorable outcome and the expected return is lower than 9 percent. For most large and healthy firms, the probability of bankruptcy is sufficiently low that financial managers are content to take the promised yield to maturity on the bonds as a measure of the expected return. But beware of assuming that the yield offered on the bonds of Fly-by-Night Corporation is the return that investors could expect to receive. THE EXPECTED RETURN ON COMMON STOCK Estimates Based on the Capital Asset Pricing Model. Earlier we showed you how to use the capital asset pricing model to estimate the expected rate of return on common stock. The capital asset pricing model tells us that investors demand a higher rate of re- turn from stocks with high betas. The formula is Expected return on stock = risk-free interest rate + ( stock’s × expected market) risk premium beta (cid:1) Self-Test 6 Financial managers and economists measure the risk-free rate of interest by the yield on Treasury bills. To measure the expected market risk premium, they usually look back at capital market history, which suggests that investors have received an extra 8 to 9 per- cent a year from investing in common stocks rather than Treasury bills. Yet wise finan- cial managers use this evidence with considerable humility, for who is to say whether investors in the past received more or less than they expected, or whether investors today require a higher or lower reward for risk than their parents did? Let’s suppose Big Oil’s common stock beta is estimated at .85, the risk-free interest rate of rf is 6 percent, and the expected market risk premium (rm – rf) is 9 percent. Then the CAPM would put Big Oil’s cost of equity at Cost of equity = requity = rf + β(rm – rf) = 6% + .85(9%) = 13.65% Of course no one can estimate expected rates of return to two decimal places, so we’ll just round to 13.5 percent. Jo Ann Cox decides to check whether Fred, the nerdy banker, was correct in claiming that Geothermal’s cost of equity is 14 percent. She estimates Geothermal’s beta at 1.20. The risk-free interest rate in 2001 is 6 percent, and the long-run average market risk pre- mium is 9 percent. What is the expected rate of return on Geothermal’s common stock, assuming of course that the CAPM is true? Recalculate Geothermal’s weighted-average cost of capital. Dividend Discount Model Cost of Equity Estimates. Whenever you are given an estimate of the expected return on a common stock, always look for ways to check whether it is reasonable. One check on the estimates provided by the CAPM can be ob- tained from the dividend discount model (DDM). Earlier we showed you how to use the constant-growth DDM formula to estimate the return that investors expect from differ- ent common stocks. Remember the formula: if dividends are expected to grow indefi- nitely at a constant rate g, then the price of the stock is equal to: The Cost of Capital 449 P0 = DIV1 requity – g where P0 is the current stock price, DIV1 is the forecast dividend at the end of the year, and requity is the expected return from the stock. We can rearrange this formula to pro- vide an estimate of requity: requity = DIV1 + g P0 In other words, the expected return on equity is equal to the dividend yield (DIV1/P0) plus the expected perpetual growth rate in dividends (g). This constant-growth dividend discount model is widely used in estimating expected rates of return on common stocks of public utilities. Utility stocks have a fairly stable
Brealey
growth pattern and are therefore tailor-made for the constant-growth formula. Remember that the constant-growth formula will get you into trouble if you apply it to firms with very high current rates of growth. Such growth cannot be sustained indefinitely. Using the formula in these circumstances will lead to an overestimate of the expected return. Beware of False Precision. Do not expect estimates of the cost of equity to be pre- cise. In practice you can’t know whether the capital asset pricing model fully explains expected returns or whether the assumptions of the dividend discount model hold ex- actly. Even if your formulas were right, the required inputs would be noisy and subject to error. Thus a financial analyst who can confidently locate the cost of equity in a band of two or three percentage points is doing pretty well. In this endeavor it is perfectly OK to conclude that the cost of equity is, say, “about 15 percent” or “somewhere between 14 and 16 percent.”6 Sometimes accuracy can be improved by estimating the cost of equity or WACC for an industry or a group of comparable companies. This cuts down the “noise” that plagues single-company estimates. Suppose, for example, that Jo Ann Cox is able to identify three companies with investments and operations similar to Geothermal’s. The average WACC for these three companies would be a valuable check on her estimate of WACC for Geothermal alone. Or suppose that Geothermal is contemplating investment in oil refining. For this venture Geothermal’s existing WACC is probably not right; it needs a discount rate reflecting the risks of the refining business. It could therefore try to estimate WACC for a sample of oil refining companies. If too few “pure-play” refining companies were available—most oil companies invest in production and marketing as well as refining— an industry WACC for a sample of large oil companies could be a useful check or benchmark. (We report estimates of oil industry WACCs at the end of the next section.) THE EXPECTED RETURN ON PREFERRED STOCK Preferred stock that pays a fixed annual dividend can be valued from the perpetuity for- mula: 6 The calculations have been done to one or two decimal places only to avoid confusion from rounding. 450 SECTION FOUR Price of preferred = dividend rpreferred where rpreferred is the appropriate discount rate for the preferred stock. Therefore, we can infer the required rate of return on preferred stock by rearranging the valuation formula to rpreferred = dividend price of preferred For example, if a share of preferred stock sells for $20 and pays a dividend of $2 per share, the expected return on preferred stock is rpreferred = $2/$20 = 10 percent, which is simply the dividend yield. Big Oil’s Weighted-Average Cost of Capital Now that you have worked out Big Oil’s capital structure and estimated the expected re- turn on its securities, you need only simple arithmetic to calculate the weighted-average cost of capital. Table 4.13 summarizes the necessary data. Now all you need to do is plug the data in Table 4.13 into the weighted-average cost of capital formula: WACC = [ D × (1 – Tc)rdebt] + ( E × requity) V = [.243 × (1 – .35) 9%] + (.757 × 13.5%) = 11.6% V Suppose that Big Oil needed to evaluate a project with the same risk as its existing busi- ness that would also support a 24.3 percent debt ratio. The 11.6 percent weighted- average cost of capital is the appropriate discount rate for the cash flows. REAL OIL COMPANY WACCs Big Oil is entirely hypothetical—and not even very big compared to actual oil compa- nies. Figure 4.18 shows estimated average costs of equity (requity) and WACCs for a sam- ple of 10 to 12 large oil companies from 1965 to 1997. The latest estimates seem to fall below 10 percent, less than our hypothetical figure for Big Oil. The WACC estimates in Figure 4.18 decline steadily since the early 1980s. Some of that decline can be attributed to a decline in interest rates over the 1980s and early
Brealey
1990s. We have included a plot of the risk-free rate (rf) in Figure 4.18 as a reference point. However, the spread between the WACC estimates and these interest rates has also narrowed, suggesting that investors viewed the oil business as less risky in the early 1990s than a decade earlier. TABLE 4.13 Data needed to calculate Big Oil’s weighted-average cost of capital (dollar figures in millions) Security Type Capital Structure Required Rate of Return Debt Common stock Total D = $ 385.7 E = $1,200.0 V = $1,585.7 D/V = .243 E/V = .757 rdebt = .09, or 9% requity = .135, or 13.5% Note: Corporate tax rate = Tc = .35. FIGURE 4.18 The middle line represents average weighted-average costs of capital for a sample of large oil companies. Average costs of equity (for the same sample) and the risk-free rate of interest are also plotted for comparison. The Cost of Capital 451 30 t 25 n e c r e p 20 Weighted-average cost of capital Cost of equity capital , n r u t e r f o s e t a r d e r i u q e R 15 10 5 0 Treasury rate 1965 ’70 ’75 ’80 ’85 ’90 ’95 Year Remember, the WACCs shown in Figure 4.18 are industry averages and therefore cover a wide range of activities. The large oil companies sampled are involved in some risky activities, such as exploration, and some relatively safe activities, such as fran- chising retail gas stations. The industry average will not be right for everything the in- dustry does. Interpreting the Weighted-Average Cost of Capital WHEN YOU CAN AND CAN’T USE WACC Earlier discussed the company cost of capital, but at that stage we did not know how to measure the company cost of capital when the firm has issued different types of secu- rities or how to adjust for the tax-deductibility of interest payments. The weighted-av- erage cost of capital formula solves those problems. The weighted-average cost of capital is the rate of return that the firm must expect to earn on its average-risk investments in order to provide a fair expected return to all its security holders. We use it to value new assets that have the same risk as the old ones and that support the same ratio of debt. Strictly speaking, the weighted-average cost of capital is an appropriate discount rate only for a project that is a carbon copy of the firm’s existing business. But often it is used as a companywide benchmark discount rate; the benchmark is adjusted upward for unusually risky projects and downward for unusually safe ones. There is a good musical analogy here. Most of us, lacking perfect pitch, need a well- defined reference point, like middle C, before we can sing on key. But anyone who can carry a tune gets relative pitches right. Businesspeople have good intuition about 452 SECTION FOUR relative risks, at least in industries they are used to, but not about absolute risk or re- quired rates of return. Therefore, they set a company- or industrywide cost of capital as a benchmark. This is not the right hurdle rate for everything the company does, but judgmental adjustments can be made for more risky or less risky ventures. SOME COMMON MISTAKES One danger with the weighted-average formula is that it tempts people to make logical errors. Think back to your estimate of the cost of capital for Big Oil: WACC = [ D × (1 – Tc)rdebt] + ( E × requity) V V = [.243 × (1 – .35) 9%] + (.757 × 13.5%) = 11.6% Now you might be tempted to say to yourself, “Aha! Big Oil has a good credit rating. It could easily push up its debt ratio to 50 percent. If the interest rate is 9 percent and the required return on equity is 13.5 percent, the weighted-average cost of capital would be WACC = [.50 × (1 – .35) 9%] + (.50 × 13.5%) = 9.7% At a discount rate of 9.7 percent, we can justify a lot more investment.” That reasoning will get you into trouble. First, if Big Oil increased its borrowing, the lenders would almost certainly demand a higher rate of interest on the debt. Second, as the borrowing increased, the risk of the common stock would also increase and there- fore the stockholders would demand a higher return. There are actually two costs of debt finance. The explicit cost of debt is the
Brealey
rate of interest that bondholders demand. But there is also an implicit cost, because borrowing increases the required return to equity. When you jumped to the conclusion that Big Oil could lower its weighted-average cost of capital to 9.7 percent by borrowing more, you were recognizing only the explicit cost of debt and not the implicit cost. (cid:1) Self-Test 7 Jo Ann Cox’s boss has pointed out that Geothermal proposes to finance its expansion entirely by borrowing at an interest rate of 8 percent. He argues that this is therefore the appropriate discount rate for the project’s cash flows. Is he right? HOW CHANGING CAPITAL STRUCTURE AFFECTS EXPECTED RETURNS We will illustrate how changes in capital structure affect expected returns by focusing on the simplest possible case, where the corporate tax rate Tc is zero. Think back to our earlier example of Geothermal. Geothermal, you may remember, has the following market-value balance sheet: Assets Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity Assets = value of Geothermal’s $647 Debt $194 (30%) existing business Total value $647 Equity Value $453 $647 (70%) (100%) The Cost of Capital 453 Geothermal’s debtholders require a return of 8 percent and the shareholders require a return of 14 percent. Since we assume here that Geothermal pays no corporate tax, its weighted-average cost of capital is simply the expected return on the firm’s assets: WACC = rassets = (.3 × 8%) + (.7 × 14%) = 12.2% This is the return you would expect if you held all Geothermal’s securities and therefore owned all its assets. Now think what will happen if Geothermal borrows an additional $97 million and uses the cash to buy back and retire $97 million of its common stock. The revised mar- ket-value balance sheet is Assets Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity Assets = value of Geothermal’s $647 Debt $291 (45%) existing business Total value $647 Equity Value 356 $647 (55%) (100%) If there are no corporate taxes, the change in capital structure does not affect the total cash that Geothermal pays out to its security holders and it does not affect the risk of those cash flows. Therefore, if investors require a return of 12.2 percent on the total package of debt and equity before the financing, they must require the same 12.2 percent return on the package afterward. The weighted-average cost of capital is there- fore unaffected by the change in the capital structure. Although the required return on the package of the debt and equity is unaffected, the change in capital structure does affect the required return on the individual securities. Since the company has more debt than before, the debt is riskier and debtholders are likely to demand a higher return. Increasing the amount of debt also makes the equity riskier and increases the return that shareholders require. WHAT HAPPENS WHEN THE CORPORATE TAX RATE IS NOT ZERO We have shown that when there are no corporate taxes the weighted-average cost of cap- ital is unaffected by a change in capital structure. Unfortunately, taxes can complicate the picture.7 For the moment, just remember • The weighted-average cost of capital is the right discount rate for average- risk capital investment projects. • The weighted-average cost of capital is the return the company needs to • earn after tax in order to satisfy all its security holders. If the firm increases its debt ratio, both the debt and the equity will become more risky. The debtholders and equity holders require a higher return to compensate for the increased risk. 7 There’s nothing wrong with our formulas and examples, provided that the tax deductibility of interest pay- ments doesn’t change the aggregate risk of the debt and equity investors. However, if the tax savings from deducting interest are treated as safe cash flows, the formulas get more complicated. If you really want to dive into the tax-adjusted formulas showing how WACC changes with capital structure, we suggest later in R. A. Brealey and S. C. Myers, Principles of Corporate Finance, 6th ed. (New York: Irwin/McGraw-Hill, 2000).
Brealey
454 SECTION FOUR Flotation Costs and the Cost of Capital To raise the necessary cash for a new project, the firm may need to issue stocks, bonds, or other securities. The costs of issuing these securities to the public can easily amount to 5 percent of funds raised. For example, a firm issuing $100 million in new equity may net only $95 million after incurring the costs of the issue. Flotation costs involve real money. A new project is less attractive if the firm must spend large sums on issuing new securities. To illustrate, consider a project that will cost $900,000 to install and is expected to generate a level perpetual cash-flow stream of $90,000 a year. At a required rate of return of 10 percent, the project is just barely viable, with an NPV of zero: –$900,000 + $90,000/.10 = 0. Now suppose that the firm needs to raise equity to pay for the project, and that flotation costs are 10 percent of funds raised. To raise $900,000, the firm actually must sell $1 million of equity. Since the installed project will be worth only $90,000/.10 = $900,000, NPV including flotation costs is actually –$1 million + $900,000 = –$100,000. In our example, we recognized flotation costs as one of the incremental costs of un- dertaking the project. But instead of recognizing these costs explicitly, some companies attempt to cope with flotation costs by increasing the cost of capital used to discount project cash flows. By using a higher discount rate, project present value is reduced. This procedure is flawed on practical as well as theoretical grounds. First, on a purely practical level, it is far easier to account for flotation costs as a negative cash flow than to search for an adjustment to the discount rate that will give the right NPV. Finding the necessary adjustment is easy only when cash flows are level or will grow indefinitely at a constant trend rate. This is almost never the case in practice, however. Of course, there always exists some discount rate that will give the right measure of the project’s NPV, but this rate could no longer be interpreted as the rate of return available in the capital market for investments with the same risk as the project. The cost of capital depends only on interest rates, taxes, and the risk of the project. Flotation costs should be treated as incremental (negative) cash flows; they do not increase the required rate of return. Summary Why do firms compute weighted-average costs of capital? They need a standard discount rate for average-risk projects. An “average-risk” project is one that has the same risk as the firm’s existing assets and operations. What about projects that are not average? The weighted-average cost of capital can still be used as a benchmark. The benchmark is adjusted up for unusually risky projects and down for unusually safe ones. How do firms compute weighted-average costs of capital? Here’s the WACC formula one more time: The Cost of Capital 455 WACC = rdebt × (1 – Tc) × D/V + requity × E/V The WACC is the expected rate of return on the portfolio of debt and equity securities issued by the firm. The required rate of return on each security is weighted by its proportion of the firm’s total market value (not book value). Since interest payments reduce the firm’s × (1 – Tc). income tax bill, the required rate of return on debt is measured after tax, as rdebt This WACC formula is usually written assuming the firm’s capital structure includes just two classes of securities, debt and equity. If there is another class, say preferred stock, the formula expands to include it. In other words, we would estimate rpreferred, the rate of return demanded by preferred stockholders, determine P/V, the fraction of market value accounted × P/V to the equation. Of course the weights in the WACC for by preferred, and add rpreferred formula always add up to 1.0. In this case D/V + P/V + E/V = 1.0. How are the costs of debt and equity calculated? The cost of debt (rdebt) is the market interest rate demanded by bondholders. In other words,
Brealey
it is the rate that the company would pay on new debt issued to finance its investment projects. The cost of preferred (rpreferred) is just the preferred dividend divided by the market price of a preferred share. The tricky part is estimating the cost of equity (requity), the expected rate of return on the firm’s shares. Financial managers use the capital asset pricing model to estimate expected return. But for mature, steady-growth companies, it can also make sense to use the constant- growth dividend discount model. Remember, estimates of expected return are less reliable for a single firm’s stock than for a sample of comparable-risk firms. Therefore, some managers also consider WACCs calculated for industries. What happens when capital structure changes? The rates of return on debt and equity will change. For example, increasing the debt ratio will increase the risk borne by both debt and equity investors and cause them to demand higher returns. However, this does not necessarily mean that the overall WACC will increase, because more weight is put on the cost of debt, which is less than the cost of equity. In fact, if we ignore taxes, the overall cost of capital will stay constant as the fractions of debt and equity change. Should WACC be adjusted for the costs of issuing securities to finance a project? No. If acceptance of a project would require the firm to issue securities, the flotation costs of the issue should be added to the investment required for the project. This reduces project NPV dollar for dollar. There is no need to adjust WACC. Related Web Links www.geocities.com/WallStreet/Market/1839/irates.html Incorporating risk premiums into the cost of capital www.financeadvisor.com/coc.htm Another approach to calculating cost of capital Key Terms Quiz capital structure weighted-average cost of capital (WACC) 1. Cost of Debt. Micro Spinoffs, Inc., issued 20-year debt a year ago at par value with a coupon rate of 9 percent, paid annually. Today, the debt is selling at $1,050. If the firm’s tax bracket is 35 percent, what is its after-tax cost of debt? 456 SECTION FOUR Practice Problems 2. Cost of Preferred Stock. Micro Spinoffs also has preferred stock outstanding. The stock pays a dividend of $4 per share, and the stock sells for $40. What is the cost of preferred stock? 3. Calculating WACC. Suppose Micro Spinoffs’s cost of equity is 12.5 percent. What is its WACC if equity is 50 percent, preferred stock is 20 percent, and debt is 30 percent of total capital? 4. Cost of Equity. Reliable Electric is a regulated public utility, and it is expected to provide steady growth of dividends of 5 percent per year for the indefinite future. Its last dividend was $5 per share; the stock sold for $60 per share just after the dividend was paid. What is the company’s cost of equity? 5. Calculating WACC. Reactive Industries has the following capital structure. Its corporate tax rate is 35 percent. What is its WACC? Security Market Value Required Rate of Return Debt Preferred stock Common stock $20 million $10 million $50 million 8% 10% 15% 6. Company versus Project Discount Rates. Geothermal’s WACC is 11.4 percent. Executive Fruit’s WACC is 12.3 percent. Now Executive Fruit is considering an investment in geother- mal power production. Should it discount project cash flows at 12.3 percent? Why or why not? 7. Flotation Costs. A project costs $10 million and has NPV of $+2.5 million. The NPV is computed by discounting at a WACC of 15 percent. Unfortunately, the $10 million invest- ment will have to be raised by a stock issue. The issue would incur flotation costs of $1.2 million. Should the project be undertaken? 8. WACC. The common stock of Buildwell Conservation & Construction, Inc., has a beta of .80. The Treasury bill rate is 4 percent and the market risk premium is estimated at 8 per- cent. BCCI’s capital structure is 30 percent debt paying a 5 percent interest rate, and 70 per- cent equity. What is BCCI’s cost of equity capital? Its WACC? Buildwell pays no taxes. 9. WACC and NPV. BCCI (see the previous problem) is evaluating a project with an internal
Brealey
rate of return of 12 percent. Should it accept the project? If the project will generate a cash flow of $100,000 a year for 7 years, what is the most BCCI should be willing to pay to ini- tiate the project? 10. Calculating WACC. Find the WACC of William Tell Computers. The total book value of the firm’s equity is $10 million; book value per share is $20. The stock sells for a price of $30 per share, and the cost of equity is 15 percent. The firm’s bonds have a par value of $5 mil- lion and sell at a price of 110 percent of par. The yield to maturity on the bonds is 9 percent, and the firm’s tax rate is 40 percent. 11. WACC. Nodebt, Inc., is a firm with all-equity financing. Its equity beta is .80. The Treasury bill rate is 5 percent and the market risk premium is expected to be 10 percent. What is Nodebt’s asset beta? What is Nodebt’s weighted-average cost of capital? The firm is exempt from paying taxes. 12. Cost of Capital. A financial analyst at Dawn Chemical notes that the firm’s total interest payments this year were $10 million while total debt outstanding was $80 million, and he concludes that the cost of debt was 12.5 percent. What is wrong with this conclusion? 13. Cost of Equity. Bunkhouse Electronics is a recently incorporated firm that makes electronic entertainment systems. Its earnings and dividends have been growing at a rate of 30 percent, The Cost of Capital 457 and the current dividend yield is 2 percent. Its beta is 1.2, the market risk premium is 8 per- cent, and the risk-free rate is 4 percent. a. Calculate two estimates of the firm’s cost of equity. b. Which estimate seems more reasonable to you? Why? 14. Cost of Debt. Olympic Sports has two issues of debt outstanding. One is a 9 percent coupon bond with a face value of $20 million, a maturity of 10 years, and a yield to maturity of 10 percent. The coupons are paid annually. The other bond issue has a maturity of 15 years, with coupons also paid annually, and a coupon rate of 10 percent. The face value of the issue is $25 million, and the issue sells for 92.8 percent of par value. The firm’s tax rate is 35 percent. a. What is the before-tax cost of debt for Olympic? b. What is Olympic’s after-tax cost of debt? 15. Capital Structure. Examine the following book-value balance sheet for University Prod- ucts, Inc. What is the capital structure of the firm based on market values? The preferred stock currently sells for $15 per share and the common stock for $20 per share. There are one million common shares outstanding. BOOK VALUE BALANCE SHEET (all values in millions) Assets Liabilities and Net Worth Cash and short-term securities $ 1 Bonds, coupon = 8%, paid $10.0 Accounts receivable Inventories Plant and equipment Total annually (maturity = 10 years, current yield to maturity = 9%) Preferred stock (par value $20 per share) Common stock (par value $.10) Additional paid in stockholders’ capital Retained earnings Total 2.0 .1 9.9 10.0 $32.0 3 7 21 $32 16. Calculating WACC. Turn back to University Products’s balance sheet from the previous problem. If the preferred stock pays a dividend of $2 per share, the beta of the stock is .8, the market risk premium is 10 percent, the risk-free rate is 6 percent, and the firm’s tax rate is 40 percent, what is University’s weighted-average cost of capital? 17. Project Discount Rate. University Products is evaluating a new venture into home com- puter systems (see problems 15 and 16). The internal rate of return on the new venture is estimated at 13.4 percent. WACCs of firms in the personal computer industry tend to average around 14 percent. Should the new project be pursued? Will University Products make the correct decision if it discounts cash flows on the proposed venture at the firm’s WACC? 18. Cost of Capital. The total market value of Okefenokee Real Estate Company is $6 million, and the total value of its debt is $4 million. The treasurer estimates that the beta of the stock currently is 1.5 and that the expected risk premium on the market is 10 percent. The Trea-
Brealey
sury bill rate is 4 percent. a. What is the required rate of return on Okefenokee stock? b. What is the beta of the company’s existing portfolio of assets? The debt is perceived to be virtually risk-free. 458 SECTION FOUR Challenge Problems Solutions to Self-Test Questions c. Estimate the weighted-average cost of capital assuming a tax rate of 40 percent. d. Estimate the discount rate for an expansion of the company’s present business. e. Suppose the company wants to diversify into the manufacture of rose-colored glasses. The beta of optical manufacturers with no debt outstanding is 1.2. What is the required rate of return on Okefenokee’s new venture? 19. Changes in Capital Structure. Look again at our calculation of Big Oil’s WACC. Suppose Big Oil is excused from paying taxes. How would its WACC change? Now suppose Big Oil makes a large stock issue and uses the proceeds to pay off all its debt. How would the cost of equity change? 20. Changes in Capital Structure. Refer again to problem 19. Suppose Big Oil starts from the financing mix in Table 4.13, and then borrows an additional $200 million from the bank. It then pays out a special $200 million dividend, leaving its assets and operations unchanged. What happens to Big Oil’s WACC, still assuming it pays no taxes? What happens to the cost of equity? 21. WACC and Taxes. “The after-tax cost of debt is lower when the firm’s tax rate is higher; therefore, the WACC falls when the tax rate rises. Thus, with a lower discount rate, the firm must be worth more if its tax rate is higher.” Explain why this argument is wrong. 22. Cost of Capital. An analyst at Dawn Chemical notes that its cost of debt is far below that of equity. He concludes that it is important for the firm to maintain the ability to increase its borrowing because if it cannot borrow, it will be forced to use more expensive equity to fi- nance some projects. This might lead it to reject some projects that would have seemed at- tractive if evaluated at the lower cost of debt. Comment on this reasoning. 1 Hot Rocks’s 4 million common shares are worth $40 million. Its market value balance sheet is: Assets Assets $90 Value $90 Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity Debt Equity Value $50 40 $90 (56%) (44%) WACC = (.56 × 9%) + (.44 × 17%) = 12.5% We use Hot Rocks’s pretax return on debt because the company pays no taxes. 2 Burg’s 6 million shares are now worth only 6 million × $4 = $24 million. The debt is sell- ing for 80 percent of book, or $20 million. The market value balance sheet is: Assets Assets $44 Value $44 Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity Debt Equity Value $20 24 $44 (45%) (55%) WACC = (.45 × 14%) + (.55 × 20%) = 17.3% Note that this question ignores taxes. The Cost of Capital 459 3 Compare the two income statements, one for Criss-cross Industries and the other for a firm with identical EBIT but no debt in its capital structure. (All figures in millions.) Criss-cross Firm with No Debt EBIT Interest expense Taxable income Taxes owed Net income Total income accruing to debt & equity holders $10.0 2.0 8.0 2.8 5.2 7.2 $10.0 0.0 10.0 3.5 6.5 6.5 Notice that Criss-cross pays $.7 million less in taxes than its debt-free counterpart. Ac- cordingly, the total income available to debt plus equity holders is $.7 million higher. 4 For Hot Rocks, WACC = [.56 × 9 × (1 – .35)] + (.44 × 17) = 10.76% For Burg Associates, WACC = [.45 × 14 × (1 – .35)] + (.55 × 20) = 15.1% 5 WACC measures the expected rate of return demanded by debt and equity investors in the firm (plus a tax adjustment capturing the tax-deductibility of interest payments). Thus the calculation must be based on what investors are actually paying for the firm’s debt and eq- uity securities. In other words, it must be based on market values. 6 From the CAPM: requity = rf + β equity (rm – rf) = 6% + 1.20(9%) = 16.8% WACC = .3(1 – .35) 8% + .7(16.8%) = 13.3% 7 Jo Ann’s boss is wrong. The ability to borrow at 8 percent does not mean that the cost of capital is 8 percent. This analysis ignores the side effects of the borrowing, for example, that at the higher indebtedness of the firm the equity will be riskier, and therefore the equity-
Brealey
holders will demand a higher rate of return on their investment. MINICASE Bernice Mountaindog was glad to be back at Sea Shore Salt. Employees were treated well. When she had asked a year ago for a leave of absence to complete her degree in finance, top man- agement promptly agreed. When she returned with an honors de- gree, she was promoted from administrative assistant (she had been secretary to Joe-Bob Brinepool, the president) to treasury analyst. Bernice thought the company’s prospects were good. Sure, table salt was a mature business, but Sea Shore Salt had grown steadily at the expense of its less well-known competitors. The company’s brand name was an important advantage, despite the difficulty most customers had in pronouncing it rapidly. went smoothly. Then Mr. Brinepool’s cost of capital memo as- signed her to explain Sea Shore Salt’s weighted-average cost of capital to other managers. The memo came as a surprise to Ber- nice, so she stayed late to prepare for the questions that would surely come the next day. Bernice first examined Sea Shore Salt’s most recent balance sheet, summarized in Table 4.14. Then she jotted down the fol- lowing additional points: • The company’s bank charged interest at current market rates, and the long-term debt had just been issued. Book and market values could not differ by much. Bernice started work on January 2, 2000. The first two weeks • But the preferred stock had been issued 35 years ago, when 460 SECTION FOUR TABLE 4.14 Sea Shore Salt’s balance sheet, taken from the company’s 1999 balance sheet (figures in millions) Assets Working capital Plant and equipment Other assets Total $200 360 40 $600 Liabilities and Net Worth Bank loan Long-term debt Preferred stock Common stock, including retained earnings Total $120 80 100 300 $600 Notes: 1. At year-end 1999, Sea Shore Salt had 10 million common shares outstanding. 2. The company had also issued 1 million preferred shares with book value of $100 per share. Each share receives an annual dividend of $6.00. interest rates were much lower. The preferred stock was now trading for only $70 per share. • The common stock traded for $40 per share. Next year’s earn- ings per share would be about $4.00 and dividends per share probably $2.00. Sea Shore Salt had traditionally paid out 50 percent of earnings as dividends and plowed back the rest. • Earnings and dividends had grown steadily at 6 to 7 percent per year, in line with the company’s sustainable growth rate: Sustainable growth rate × plowback ratio = return on equity = 4.00/30 × .5 = .067, or 6.7% • Sea Shore Salt’s beta had averaged about .5, which made sense, Bernice thought, for a stable, steady-growth business. She made a quick cost of equity calculation using the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). With current interest rates of about 7 percent, and a market risk premium of 8 percent, CAPM cost of equity = rE = rf + β(rm – rf) = 7% + .5(8%) = 11% This cost of equity was significantly less than the 16 percent decreed in Mr. Brinepool’s memo. Bernice scanned her notes ap- prehensively. What if Mr. Brinepool’s cost of equity was wrong? Was there some other way to estimate the cost of equity as a check on the CAPM calculation? Could there be other errors in his calculations? Bernice resolved to complete her analysis that night. If neces- sary, she would try to speak with Mr. Brinepool when he arrived at his office the next morning. Her job was not just finding the right number. She also had to figure out how to explain it all to Mr. Brinepool. The Cost of Capital 461 Sea Shore Salt Company Spring Vacation Beach, Florida CONFIDENTIAL MEMORANDUM DATE: TO: FROM: SUBJECT: January 15, 2000 S.S.S. Management Joe-Bob Brinepool, President Cost of Capital This memo states and clarifies our company’s long-standing policy regarding hurdle rates for capital investment decisions. There have been many recent questions, and some evident confusion, on this matter. Sea Shore Salt evaluates replacement and expansion investments by discounted cash flow.
Brealey
The discount or hurdle rate is the company’s after-tax weighted-average cost of capital. The weighted-average cost of capital is simply a blend of the rates of return expected by investors in our company. These investors include banks, bond holders, and preferred stock investors in addition to common stockholders. Of course many of you are, or soon will be, stockholders of our company. The following table summarizes the composition of Sea Shore Salt’s financing. Amount (in millions) Percent of Total Rate of Return Bank loan Bond issue Preferred stock Common stock $120 80 100 300 $600 20% 13.3 16.7 50 100% 8% 7.75 6 16 The rates of return on the bank loan and bond issue are of course just the interest rates we pay. However, interest is tax-deductible, so the after-tax interest rates are lower than shown above. For example, the after-tax cost of our bank financing, given our 35% tax rate, is 8(1 – .35) = 5.2%. The rate of return on preferred stock is 6%. Sea Shore Salt pays a $6 dividend on each $100 preferred share. Our target rate of return on equity has been 16% for many years. I know that some newcomers think this target is too high for the safe and mature salt business. But we must all aspire to superior profitability. Once this background is absorbed, the calculation of Sea Shore Salt’s weighted-average cost of capital (WACC) is elementary: WACC = 8(1 – .35)(.2) + 7.75(1 – .35)(.133) + 6(.167) + 16(.50) = 10.7% The official corporate hurdle rate is therefore 10.7%. If you have further questions about these calculations, please direct them to our new Treasury Analyst, Ms. Bernice Mountaindog. It is a pleasure to have Bernice back at Sea Shore Salt after a year’s leave of absence to complete her degree in finance. Section 5 Project Analysis An Overview of Corporate Financing How Corporations Issue Securities PROJECT ANALYSIS The Option to Expand Abandonment Options Flexible Production Facilities Investment Timing Options Summary How Firms Organize the Investment Process Stage 1: The Capital Budget Stage 2: Project Authorizations Problems and Some Solutions Some “What-If” Questions Sensitivity Analysis Scenario Analysis Break-Even Analysis Accounting Break-Even Analysis NPV Break-Even Analysis Operating Leverage Flexibility in Capital Budgeting Decision Trees “But Mr. Mitterand, have you thought of sensitivity analysis?” Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher and President Francois Mitterand meet to sign the treaty leading to construction of a railway tunnel under the English Channel between England and France. AP/Wide World Photos 465 I t helps to use discounted cash-flow techniques to value new projects but good investment decisions also require good data. Therefore, we start this material by thinking about how firms organize the capital budgeting operation to get the kind of information they need. In addition, we look at how they try to ensure that everyone involved works together toward a common goal. Project evaluation should never be a mechanical exercise in which the financial man- ager takes a set of cash-flow forecasts and cranks out a net present value. Cash-flow es- timates are just that—estimates. Financial managers need to look behind the forecasts to try to understand what makes the project tick and what could go wrong with it. A number of techniques have been developed to help managers identify the key assump- tions in their analysis. These techniques involve asking a number of “what-if ” ques- tions. What if your market share turns out to be higher or lower than you forecast? What if interest rates rise during the life of the project? In the second part of this material we show how managers use the techniques of sensitivity analysis, scenario analysis, and break-even analysis to help answer these what-if questions. Books about capital budgeting sometimes create the impression that once the man- ager has made an investment decision, there is nothing to do but sit back and watch the cash flows develop. But since cash flows rarely proceed as anticipated, companies con- stantly need to modify their operations. If cash flows are better than anticipated, the
Brealey
project may be expanded; if they are worse, it may be scaled back or abandoned alto- gether. In the third section of this material we describe how good managers take account of these options when they analyze a project and why they are willing to pay money today to build in future flexibility. After studying this material you should be able to (cid:1) Appreciate the practical problems of capital budgeting in large corporations. (cid:1) Use sensitivity, scenario, and break-even analysis to see how project profitability would be affected by an error in your forecasts and understand why an overestimate of sales is more serious for projects with high operating leverage. (cid:1) Recognize the importance of managerial flexibility in capital budgeting. How Firms Organize the Investment Process For most sizable firms, investments are evaluated in two separate stages. 466 ACAPITAL BUDGET List of planned investment projects. Project Analysis 467 STAGE 1: THE CAPITAL BUDGET Once a year, the head office generally asks each of its divisions and plants to provide a list of the investments that they would like to make.1 These are gathered together into a proposed capital budget. This budget is then reviewed and pruned by senior management and staff specializ- ing in planning and financial analysis. Usually there are negotiations between the firm’s senior management and its divisional management, and there may also be special analy- ses of major outlays or ventures into new areas. Once the budget has been approved, it generally remains the basis for planning over the ensuing year. Many investment proposals bubble up from the bottom of the organization. But sometimes the ideas are likely to come from higher up. For example, the managers of plants A and B cannot be expected to see the potential benefits of closing their plants and consolidating production at a new plant C. We expect divisional management to propose plant C. Similarly, divisions 1 and 2 may not be eager to give up their own data processing operations to a large central computer. That proposal would come from sen- ior management. Senior management’s concern is to see that the capital budget matches the firm’s strategic plans. It needs to ensure that the firm is concentrating its efforts in areas where it has a real competitive advantage. As part of this effort, management must also iden- tify declining businesses that should be sold or allowed to run down. The firm’s capital investment choices should reflect both “bottom-up” and “top- down” processes—capital budgeting and strategic planning, respectively. The two processes should complement each other. Plant and division managers, who do most of the work in bottom-up capital budgeting, may not see the forest for the trees. Strategic planners may have a mistaken view of the forest because they do not look at the trees. STAGE 2: PROJECT AUTHORIZATIONS The annual budget is important because it allows everybody to exchange ideas before attitudes have hardened and personal commitments have been made. However, the fact that your pet project has been included in the annual budget doesn’t mean you have per- mission to go ahead with it. At a later stage you will need to draw up a detailed proposal describing particulars of the project, engineering analyses, cash-flow forecasts, and present value calculations. If your project is large, this proposal may have to pass a number of hurdles before it is finally approved. The type of backup information that you need to provide depends on the project cat- egory. For example, some firms use a fourfold breakdown: 1. Outlays required by law or company policy, for example, for pollution control equip- ment. These outlays do not need to be justified on financial grounds. The main issue is whether requirements are satisfied at the lowest possible cost. The decision is therefore likely to hinge on engineering analyses of alternative technologies. 2. Maintenance or cost reduction, such as machine replacement. Engineering analysis
Brealey
is also important in machine replacement, but new machines have to pay their own way. 3. Capacity expansion in existing businesses. Projects in this category are less straight- 1 Large firms may be divided into several divisions. For example, International Paper has divisions that spe- cialize in printing paper, packaging, specialty products, and forest products. Each of these divisions may be responsible for a number of plants. 468 SECTION FIVE forward; these decisions may hinge on forecasts of demand, possible shifts in tech- nology, and the reactions of competitors. 4. Investment for new products. Projects in this category are most likely to depend on strategic decisions. The first projects in a new area may not have positive NPVs if considered in isolation, but they may give the firm a valuable option to undertake follow-up projects. More about this later. PROBLEMS AND SOME SOLUTIONS Valuing capital investment opportunities is hard enough when you can do the entire job yourself. In most firms, however, capital budgeting is a cooperative effort, and this brings with it some challenges. Ensuring that Forecasts Are Consistent. Inconsistent assumptions often creep into investment proposals. For example, suppose that the manager of the furniture division is bullish (optimistic) on housing starts but the manager of the appliance division is bearish (pessimistic). This inconsistency makes the projects proposed by the furniture division look more attractive than those of the appliance division. To ensure consistency, many firms begin the capital budgeting process by establish- ing forecasts of economic indicators, such as inflation and the growth in national in- come, as well as forecasts of particular items that are important to the firm’s business, such as housing starts or the price of raw materials. These forecasts can then be used as the basis for all project analyses. Eliminating Conflicts of Interest. Earlier we pointed out that while managers want to do a good job, they are also concerned about their own futures. If the interests of managers conflict with those of stockholders, the result is likely to be poor investment decisions. For example, new plant managers naturally want to demonstrate good per- formance right away. To this end, they might propose quick-payback projects even if NPV is sacrificed. Unfortunately, many firms measure performance and reward man- agers in ways that encourage such behavior. If the firm always demands quick results, it is unlikely that plant managers will concentrate only on NPV. Reducing Forecast Bias. Someone who is keen to get a project proposal accepted is also likely to look on the bright side when forecasting the project’s cash flows. Such overoptimism is a common feature in financial forecasts. For example, think of large public expenditure proposals. How often have you heard of a new missile, dam, or high- way that actually cost less than was originally forecast? Think back to the Eurotunnel project. The final cost of the project was about 50 percent higher than initial forecasts. It is probably impossible to ever eliminate bias completely, but if senior management is aware of why bias occurs, it is at least partway to solving the problem. Project sponsors are likely to overstate their case deliberately only if the head office encourages them to do so. For example, if middle managers believe that success de- pends on having the largest division rather than the most profitable one, they will pro- pose large expansion projects that they do not believe have the largest possible net pres- ent value. Or if divisions must compete for limited resources, they will try to outbid each other for those resources. The fault in such cases is top management’s—if lower level managers are not rewarded based on net present value and contribution to firm value, it should not be surprising that they focus their efforts elsewhere. Other problems stem from sponsors’ eagerness to obtain approval for their favorite Project Analysis 469
Brealey
projects. As the proposal travels up the organization, alliances are formed. Thus once a division has screened its own plants’ proposals, the plants in that division unite in com- peting against outsiders. The result is that the head office may receive several thousand investment proposals each year, all essentially sales documents presented by united fronts and designed to persuade. The forecasts have been doctored to ensure that NPV appears positive. Since it is difficult for senior management to evaluate each specific assumption in an investment proposal, capital investment decisions are effectively decentralized what- ever the rules say. Some firms accept this; others rely on head office staff to check cap- ital investment proposals. Sorting the Wheat from the Chaff. Senior managers are continually bombarded with requests for funds for capital expenditures. All these requests are supported with detailed analyses showing that the projects have positive NPVs. How then can managers ensure that only worthwhile projects make the grade? One response of senior managers to this problem of poor information is to impose rigid expenditure limits on individual plants or divisions. These limits force the subunits to choose among projects. The firm ends up using capital rationing not because capital is unobtainable but as a way of de- centralizing decisions.2 Senior managers might also ask some searching questions about why the project has a positive NPV. After all, if the project is so attractive, why hasn’t someone already un- dertaken it? Will others copy your idea if it is so profitable? Positive NPVs are plausi- ble only if your company has some competitive advantage. Such an advantage can arise in several ways. You may be smart or lucky enough to be the first to the market with a new or improved product for which customers will pay premium prices. Your competitors eventually will enter the market and squeeze out ex- cess profits, but it may take them several years to do so. Or you may have a proprietary technology or production cost advantage that competitors cannot easily match. You may have a contractual advantage such as the distributorship for a particular region. Or your advantage may be as simple as a good reputation and an established customer list. Analyzing competitive advantage can also help ferret out projects that incorrectly appear to have a negative NPV. If you are the lowest cost producer of a profitable prod- uct in a growing market, then you should invest to expand along with the market. If your calculations show a negative NPV for such an expansion, then you probably have made a mistake. Some “What-If” Questions SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS Uncertainty means that more things can happen than will happen. Therefore, whenever managers are given a cash-flow forecast, they try to determine what else might happen and the implications of those possible events. This is called sensitivity analysis. Put yourself in the well-heeled shoes of the financial manager of the Finefodder su- permarket chain. Finefodder is considering opening a new superstore in Gravenstein 2 We discussed capital rationing earlier. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS Analysis of the effects on project profitability of changes in sales, costs, and so on. 470 SECTION FIVE TABLE 5.1 Cash-flow forecasts for Finefodder’s new superstore FIXED COSTS Costs that do not depend on the level of output. VARIABLE COSTS Costs that change as the level of output changes. Investment –$5,400,000 Year 0 Years 1–12 1. Sales 2. Variable costs 3. Fixed costs 4. Depreciation 5. Pretax profit (1 – 2 – 3 – 4) 6. Taxes (at 40%) 7. Profit after tax 8. Cash flow from operations (4 + 7) $16,000,000 13,000,000 2,000,000 450,000 550,000 220,000 330,000 780,000 Net cash flow –$5,400,000 $ 780,000 and your staff members have prepared the figures shown in Table 5.1. The figures are fairly typical for a new supermarket, except that to keep the example simple we have assumed no inflation. We have also assumed that the entire investment can be depreci- ated straight-line for tax purposes, we have neglected the working capital requirement,
Brealey
and we have ignored the fact that at the end of the 12 years you could sell off the land and buildings. As an experienced financial manager, you recognize immediately that these cash flows constitute an annuity and therefore you calculate present value by multiplying the $780,000 cash flow by the 12-year annuity factor. If the cost of capital is 8 percent, present value is PV = $780,000 × 12-year annuity factor = $780,000 × 7.536 = $5.878 million Subtract the initial investment of $5.4 million and you obtain a net present value of $478,000: NPV = PV – investment = $5.878 million – $5.4 million = $478,000 Before you agree to accept the project, however, you want to delve behind these fore- casts and identify the key variables that will determine whether the project succeeds or fails. Some of the costs of running a supermarket are fixed. For example, regardless of the level of output, you still have to heat and light the store and pay the store manager. These fixed costs are forecast to be $2 million per year. Other costs vary with the level of sales. In particular, the lower the sales, the less food you need to buy. Also, if sales are lower than forecast, you can operate a lower number of checkouts and reduce the staff needed to restock the shelves. The new su- perstore’s variable costs are estimated at 81.25 percent of sales. Thus variable costs = .8125 × $16 million = $13 million. The initial investment of $5.4 million will be depreciated on a straight-line basis over the 12-year period, resulting in annual depreciation of $450,000. Profits are taxed at a rate of 40 percent. These seem to be the important things you need to know, but look out for things that may have been forgotten. Perhaps there will be delays in obtaining planning permission, Project Analysis 471 TABLE 5.2 Sensitivity analysis for superstore project Range NPV Variable Pessimistic Expected Optimistic Pessimistic Expected Optimistic Investment Sales Variable cost as percent of sales Fixed cost 6,200,000 14,000,000 5,400,000 16,000,000 5,000,000 18,000,000 –121,000 –1,218,000 +478,000 +478,000 +778,000 +2,174,000 83 2,100,000 81.25 2,000,000 80 1,900,000 –788,000 +26,000 +478,000 +478,000 +1,382,000 +930,000 or perhaps you will need to undertake costly landscaping. The greatest dangers often lie in these unknown unknowns, or “unk-unks,” as scientists call them. Having found no unk-unks (no doubt you’ll find them later), you look at how NPV may be affected if you have made a wrong forecast of sales, costs, and so on. To do this, you first obtain optimistic and pessimistic estimates for the underlying variables. These are set out in the left-hand columns of Table 5.2. Next you see what happens to NPV under the optimistic or pessimistic forecasts for each of these variables. You recalculate project NPV under these various forecasts to de- termine which variables are most critical to NPV. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 1 Sensitivity Analysis The right-hand side of Table 5.2 shows the project’s net present value if the variables are set one at a time to their optimistic and pessimistic values. For example, if fixed costs are $1.9 million rather than the forecast $2.0 million, annual cash flows are increased by (1 – tax rate) × ($2.0 million – $1.9 million) = .6 × $100,000 = $60,000. If the cash flow increases by $60,000 a year for 12 years, then the project’s present value increases by $60,000 times the 12-year annuity factor, or $60,000 × 7.536 = $452,000. Therefore, NPV increases from the expected value of $478,000 to $478,000 + $452,000 = $930,000, as shown in the bottom right corner of the table. The other entries in the three columns on the right in Table 5.2 similarly show how the NPV of the project changes when each input is changed. Your project is by no means a sure thing. The principal uncertainties appear to be sales and variable costs. For example, if sales are only $14 million rather than the fore- cast $16 million (and all other forecasts are unchanged), then the project has an NPV of –$1.218 million. If variable costs are 83 percent of sales (and all other forecasts are
Brealey
unchanged), then the project has an NPV of –$788,000. (cid:1) Self-Test 1 Recalculate cash flow as in Table 5.1 if variable costs are 83 percent of sales. Confirm that NPV will be –$788,000. Value of Information. Now that you know the project could be thrown badly off course by a poor estimate of sales, you might like to see whether it is possible to resolve 472 SECTION FIVE some of this uncertainty. Perhaps your worry is that the store will fail to attract suffi- cient shoppers from neighboring towns. In that case, additional survey data and more careful analysis of travel times may be worthwhile. On the other hand, there is less value to gathering additional information about fixed costs. Because the project is marginally profitable even under pessimistic assump- tions about fixed costs, you are unlikely to be in trouble if you have misestimated that variable. Limits to Sensitivity Analysis. Your analysis of the forecasts for Finefodder’s new superstore is known as a sensitivity analysis. Sensitivity analysis expresses cash flows in terms of unknown variables and then calculates the consequences of misestimating those variables. It forces the manager to identify the underlying factors, indicates where additional information would be most useful, and helps to expose confused or inappro- priate forecasts. Of course, there is no law stating which variables you should consider in your sen- sitivity analysis. For example, you may wish to look separately at labor costs and the costs of the goods sold. Or, if you are concerned about a possible change in the corpo- rate tax rate, you may wish to look at the effect of such a change on the project’s NPV. One drawback to sensitivity analysis is that it gives somewhat ambiguous results. For example, what exactly does optimistic or pessimistic mean? One department may be in- terpreting the terms in a different way from another. Ten years from now, after hundreds of projects, hindsight may show that one department’s pessimistic limit was exceeded twice as often as the other’s; but hindsight won’t help you now while you’re making the investment decision. Another problem with sensitivity analysis is that the underlying variables are likely to be interrelated. For example, if sales exceed expectations, demand will likely be stronger than you anticipated and your profit margins will be wider. Or, if wages are higher than your forecast, both variable costs and fixed costs are likely to be at the upper end of your range. Because of these connections, you cannot push one-at-a-time sensitivity analysis too far. It is impossible to obtain expected, optimistic, and pessimistic values for total proj- ect cash flows from the information in Table 5.2. Still, it does give a sense of which vari- ables should be most closely monitored. SCENARIO ANALYSIS SCENARIO ANALYSIS Project analysis given a particular combination of assumptions. When variables are interrelated, managers often find it helpful to look at how their proj- ect would fare under different scenarios. Scenario analysis allows them to look at dif- ferent but consistent combinations of variables. Forecasters generally prefer to give an estimate of revenues or costs under a particular scenario rather than giving some ab- solute optimistic or pessimistic value. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 2 Scenario Analysis You are worried that Stop and Scoff may decide to build a new store in nearby Salome. That would reduce sales in your Gravenstein store by 15 percent and you might be forced into a price war to keep the remaining business. Prices might be reduced to the point that variable costs equal 82 percent of revenue. Table 5.3 shows that under this TABLE 5.3 Scenario analysis, NPV of Finefodder’s Gravenstein superstore with scenario of new competing store in nearby Salome Project Analysis 473 Cash Flows Years 1–12 Base Case Competing Store Scenarioa 1. Sales 2. Variable costs 3. Fixed costs 4. Depreciation 5. Pretax profit (1 – 2 – 3 – 4) 6. Taxes (40%) 7. Profit after tax
Brealey
8. Cash flow from operations (4 + 7) Present value of cash flows NPV $16,000,000 13,000,000 2,000,000 450,000 550,000 220,000 330,000 780,000 5,878,000 478,000 $13,600,000 11,152,000 2,000,000 450,000 –2,000 –800 –1,200 448,800 3,382,000 –2,018,000 a Assumptions: Competing store causes (1) a 15 percent reduction in sales, and (2) variable costs to increase to 82 percent of sales. scenario of lower sales and smaller margins your new venture would no longer be worthwhile. SIMULATION ANALYSIS Estimation of the probabilities of different possible outcomes, e.g., from an investment project. An extension of scenario analysis is called simulation analysis. Here, instead of specifying a relatively small number of scenarios, a computer generates several hundred or thousand possible combinations of variables according to probability distributions specified by the analyst. Each combination of variables corresponds to one scenario. Project NPV and other outcomes of interest can be calculated for each combination of variables, and the entire probability distribution of outcomes can be constructed from the simulation results. (cid:1) Self-Test 2 What is the basic difference between sensitivity analysis and scenario analysis? BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS Analysis of the level of sales at which the company breaks even. Break-Even Analysis When we undertake a sensitivity analysis of a project or when we look at alternative scenarios, we are asking how serious it would be if we have misestimated sales or costs. Managers sometimes prefer to rephrase this question and ask how far off the estimates could be before the project begins to lose money. This exercise is known as break-even analysis. For many projects, the make-or-break variable is sales volume. Therefore, managers most often focus on the break-even level of sales. However, you might also look at other variables, for example, at how high costs could be before the project goes into the red. As it turns out, “losing money” can be defined in more than one way. Most often, the break-even condition is defined in terms of accounting profits. More properly, how- ever, it should be defined in terms of net present value. We will start with accounting 474 SECTION FIVE break-even, show that it can lead you astray, and then show how NPV break-even can be used as an alternative. ACCOUNTING BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS The accounting break-even point is the level of sales at which profits are zero or, equiv- alently, at which total revenues equal total costs. As we have seen, some costs are fixed regardless of the level of output. Other costs vary with the level of output. When you first analyzed the superstore project, you came up with the following es- timates: Sales Variable cost Fixed costs Depreciation $16 million 13 million 2 million 0.45 million Notice that variable costs are 81.25 percent of sales. So, for each additional dollar of sales, costs increase by only $.8125. We can easily determine how much business the superstore needs to attract to avoid losses. If the store sells nothing, the income statement will show fixed costs of $2 million and depreciation of $450,000. Thus there will be a loss of $2.45 million. Each dollar of sales reduces this loss by $1.00 – $.8125 = $.1875. Therefore, to cover fixed costs plus depreciation, you need sales of 2.45 million/.1875 = $13.067 million. At this sales level, the firm will break even. More generally, Break-even level of revenues = fixed costs including depreciation additional profit from each additional dollar of sales Table 5.4 shows how the income statement looks with only $13.067 million of sales. Figure 5.1 shows how the break-even point is determined. The 45-degree line shows accounting revenues. The cost line shows how costs vary with sales. If the store doesn’t sell a cent, it still incurs fixed costs and depreciation amounting to $2.45 mil- lion. Each extra dollar of sales adds $.8125 to these costs. When sales are $13.067 mil- lion, the two lines cross, indicating that costs equal revenues. For lower sales, revenues
Brealey
are less than costs and the project is in the red; for higher sales, revenues exceed costs and the project moves into the black. Is a project that breaks even in accounting terms an acceptable investment? If you TABLE 5.4 Income statement, break-even sales volume Item $ Thousands Revenues Variable costs Fixed costs Depreciation Pretax profit Taxes Profit after tax 13,067 10,617 2,000 450 0 0 0 (81.25 percent of sales) FIGURE 5.1 Accounting break-even analysis n o i l l i m $ , e u n e v e r d n a s t s o C 13.067 2.45 Project Analysis 475 Revenue Total costs Variable costs 13.067 Fixed costs Costs exceed revenue Revenue exceeds costs Sales revenue, $ million are not sure about the answer, here’s a possibly easier question. Would you be happy about an investment in a stock that after 5 years gave you a total rate of return of zero? We hope not. You might break even on such a stock but a zero return does not com- pensate you for the time value of money or the risk that you have taken. A project that simply breaks even on an accounting basis gives you your money back but does not cover the opportunity cost of the capital tied up in the project. A project that breaks even in accounting terms will surely have a negative NPV. Let’s check this with the superstore project. Suppose that in each year the store has sales of $13.067 million—just enough to break even on an accounting basis. What would be the cash flow from operations? Cash flow from operations = profit after tax + depreciation = 0 + $450,000 = $450,000 The initial investment is $5.4 million. In each of the next 12 years, the firm receives a cash flow of $450,000. So the firm gets its money back: Total cash flow from operations = initial investment 12 × $450,000 = $5.4 million But revenues are not sufficient to repay the opportunity cost of that $5.4 million in- vestment. NPV is negative. NPV BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS Instead of asking how bad sales can get before the project makes an accounting loss, it is more useful to focus on the point at which NPV switches from positive to negative. The cash flows of the project in each year will depend on sales as follows: 476 SECTION FIVE 1. Variable costs 2. Fixed costs 3. Depreciation 4. Pretax profit 5. Tax (at 40%) 6. Profit after tax 7. Cash flow (3 + 6) 81.25 percent of sales $2 million $450,000 (.1875 × sales) – $2.45 million .40 × (.1875 × sales – $2.45 million) .60 × (.1875 × sales – $2.45 million) $450,000 + .60 × (.1875 × sales – $2.45 million) = .1125 × sales – $1.02 million This cash flow will last for 12 years. So to find its present value we multiply by the 12-year annuity factor. With a discount rate of 8 percent, the present value of $1 a year for each of 12 years is $7.536. Thus the present value of the cash flows is PV (cash flows) = 7.536 × (.1125 × sales – $1.02 million) The project breaks even in present value terms (that is, has a zero NPV) if the pres- ent value of these cash flows is equal to the initial $5.4 million investment. Therefore, break-even occurs when PV (cash flows) = investment 7.536 × (.1125 × sales – $1.02 million) = $5.4 million –$7.69 million + .8478 × sales = $5.4 million sales = 5.4 + 7.69 .8478 = $15.4 million This implies that the store needs sales of $15.4 million a year for the investment to have a zero NPV. This is more than 18 percent higher than the point at which the project has zero profit. Figure 5.2 is a plot of the present value of the inflows and outflows from the super- store as a function of annual sales. The two lines cross when sales are $15.4 million. This is the point at which the project has zero NPV. As long as sales are greater than this, the present value of the inflows exceeds the present value of the outflows and the project has a positive NPV. FIGURE 5.2 NPV break-even analysis s r a l l o d f o s n o i l l i m , s e u a v l j t c e o r P 5.4 0 (cid:1)7.69 PV of project cash flows Investment Sales revenue, millions of dollars 15.4 NPV is negative NPV is positive (cid:1) Self-Test 3 What would be the NPV break-even level of sales if the capital investment was only $5 million? Project Analysis 477 (cid:1) EXAMPLE 3
Brealey
Break-Even Analysis We have said that projects that break even on an accounting basis are really making a loss—they are losing the opportunity cost of their investment. Here is a dramatic ex- ample. Lophead Aviation is contemplating investment in a new passenger aircraft, code- named the Trinova. Lophead’s financial staff has gathered together the following esti- mates: 1. The cost of developing the Trinova is forecast at $900 million, and this investment can be depreciated in 6 equal annual amounts. 2. Production of the plane is expected to take place at a steady annual rate over the fol- lowing 6 years. 3. The average price of the Trinova is expected to be $15.5 million. 4. Fixed costs are forecast at $175 million a year. 5. Variable costs are forecast at $8.5 million a plane. 6. The tax rate is 50 percent. 7. The cost of capital is 10 percent. How many aircraft does Lophead need to sell to break even in accounting terms? And how many does it need to sell to break even on the basis of NPV? (Notice that the break-even point is defined here in terms of number of aircraft, rather than revenue. But since revenue is proportional to planes sold, these two break-even concepts are inter- changeable.) To answer the first question we set out the profits from the Trinova program in rows 1 to 7 of Table 5.5 (ignore row 8 for a moment). In accounting terms the venture breaks even when pretax profit (and therefore net profit) is zero. In this case (7 × planes sold) – 325 = 0 Planes sold = 325 7 = 46 TABLE 5.5 Forecast profitability for production of the Trinova airliner (figures in millions of dollars) Investment 1. Sales 2. Variable costs 3. Fixed costs 4. Depreciation 5. Pretax profit (1 – 2 – 3 – 4) 6. Taxes (at 50%) 7. Net profit (5 – 6) 8. Net cash flow (4 + 7) Year 0 $900 Years 1–6 15.5 × planes sold 8.5 × planes sold 175 900/6 = 150 (7 × planes sold) – 325 (3.5 × planes sold) – 162.5 (3.5 × planes sold) – 162.5 (3.5 × planes sold) – 12.5 –$900 478 SECTION FIVE Thus Lophead needs to sell about 46 planes a year, or a total of about 280 planes over the 6 years to show a profit. Notice that we obtain the same result if we attack the problem in terms of the break- even level of revenue. The variable cost of each plane is $8.5 million, which is 54.8 per- cent of the $15.5 million price. Therefore, each dollar of sales increases pretax profits by $1 – $.548 = $.452. So Break-even revenue = fixed costs including depreciation additional profit from each additional dollar of sales = $325 million .452 = $719 million Since each plane cost $15.5 million, this revenue level implies sales of 719/15.5 = 46 planes per year. Now let us look at what sales are needed before the project has a zero NPV. Devel- opment of the Trinova costs $900 million. For each of the next 6 years the company ex- pects a cash flow of $3.5 million × planes sold – $12.5 million (see row 8 of Table 5.5). If the cost of capital is 10 percent, the 6-year annuity factor is 4.355. So NPV = –900 + 4.355(3.5 × planes sold – 12.5) = 15.24 × planes sold – 954.44 If the project has a zero NPV, 0 = 15.24 planes sold – 954.44 planes sold = 63 Thus Lophead can recover its initial investment with sales of 46 planes a year (about 280 in total), but it needs to sell 63 a year (or about 375 in total) to earn a return on this investment equal to the opportunity cost of capital. Our example may seem fanciful but it is based loosely on reality. In 1971 Lockheed was in the middle of a major program to bring out the L-1011 TriStar airliner. This pro- gram was to bring Lockheed to the brink of failure and it tipped Rolls-Royce (supplier of the TriStar engine) over the brink. In giving evidence to Congress, Lockheed argued that the TriStar program was commercially attractive and that sales would eventually ex- ceed the break-even point of about 200 aircraft. But in calculating this break-even point Lockheed appears to have ignored the opportunity cost of the huge capital investment in the project. Lockheed probably needed to sell about 500 aircraft to reach a zero net present value.3
Brealey
(cid:1) Self-Test 4 What is the basic difference between sensitivity analysis and break-even analysis? OPERATING LEVERAGE A project’s break-even point depends on both its fixed costs, which do not vary with sales, and the profit on each extra sale. Managers often face a trade-off between these 3 The true break-even point for the TriStar program is estimated in U. E. Reinhardt, “Break-Even Analysis for Lockheed’s TriStar: An Application of Financial Theory,” Journal of Finance 28 (September 1973), pp. 821–838. Project Analysis 479 variables. For example, we typically think of rental expenses as fixed costs. But super- market companies sometimes rent stores with contingent rent agreements. This means that the amount of rent the company pays is tied to the level of sales from the store. Rent rises and falls along with sales. The store thus replaces a fixed cost with a variable cost that rises along with sales. Because a greater proportion of the company’s expenses will fall when its sales fall, its break-even point is reduced. Of course, a high proportion of fixed costs is not all bad. The firm whose costs are largely fixed fares poorly when demand is low, but it may make a killing during a boom. Let us illustrate. Finefodder has a policy of hiring long-term employees who will not be laid off ex- cept in the most dire circumstances. For all intents and purposes, these salaries are fixed costs. Its rival, Stop and Scoff, has a much smaller permanent labor force and uses ex- pensive temporary help whenever demand for its product requires extra staff. A greater proportion of its labor expenses are therefore variable costs. Suppose that if Finefodder adopted its rival’s policy, fixed costs in its new superstore would fall from $2 million to $1.56 million but variable costs would rise from 81.25 to 84 percent of sales. Table 5.6 shows that with the normal level of sales, the two policies fare equally. In a slump a store that relies on temporary labor does better since its costs fall along with revenue. In a boom the reverse is true and the store with the higher pro- portion of fixed costs has the advantage. If Finefodder follows its normal policy of hiring long-term employees, each extra dollar of sales results in a change of $1.00 – $.8125 = $.1875 in pretax profits. If it uses temporary labor, an extra dollar of sales leads to a change of only $1.00 – $.84 = $.16 in profits. As a result, a store with high fixed costs is said to have high operating lever- age. High operating leverage magnifies the effect on profits of a fluctuation in sales. We can measure a business’s operating leverage by asking how much profits change for each 1 percent change in sales. The degree of operating leverage, often abbreviated as DOL, is this measure. DOL = percentage change in profits percentage change in sales For example, Table 5.6 shows that as the store moves from normal conditions to boom, sales increase from $16 million to $19 million, a rise of 18.75 percent. For the policy with high fixed costs, profits increase from $550,000 to $1,112,000, a rise of 102.2 per- cent. Therefore, DOL = 102.2 18.75 = 5.45 The percentage change in sales is magnified more than fivefold in terms of the per- centage impact on profits. High Fixed Costs High Variable Costs Slump Normal Boom Slump Normal Boom Sales – Variable costs – Fixed costs – Depreciation = Pretax profit 13,000 10,563 2,000 450 –13 16,000 13,000 2,000 450 550 19,000 15,438 2,000 450 1,112 13,000 10,920 1,560 450 70 16,000 13,440 1,560 450 550 19,000 15,960 1,560 450 1,030 OPERATING LEVERAGE Degree to which costs are fixed. DEGREE OF OPERATING LEVERAGE (DOL) change in profits given a 1 percent change in sales. Percentage TABLE 5.6 A store with high operating leverage performs relatively badly in a slump but flourishes in a boom (figures in thousands of dollars) 480 SECTION FIVE Now look at the operating leverage of the store if it uses the policy with low fixed costs but high variable costs. As the store moves from normal times to boom, profits in- crease from $550,000 to $1,030,000, a rise of 87.3 percent. Therefore, DOL = 87.3 18.75 = 4.65
Brealey
Because some costs remain fixed, a change in sales continues to have a magnified ef- fect on profits but the degree of operating leverage is lower. In fact, one can show that degree of operating leverage depends on fixed charges (in- cluding depreciation) in the following manner:4 DOL = 1 + fixed costs profits This relationship makes it clear that operating leverage increases with fixed costs. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 4 Operating Leverage Suppose the firm adopts the high-fixed-cost policy. Then fixed costs including depre- ciation will be 2.00 + .45 = $2.45 million. Since the store produces profits of $.55 mil- lion at a normal level of sales, DOL should be DOL = 1 + fixed costs profits = 1 + 2.00 + .45 .55 = 5.45 This value matches the one we obtained by comparing the actual percentage changes in sales and profits. You can see from this example that the risk of a project is affected by the degree of operating leverage. If a large proportion of costs is fixed, a shortfall in sales has a magnified effect on profits. We will have more to say about risk later. (cid:1) Self-Test 5 Suppose that sales increase by 10 percent from the values in the normal scenario. Com- pute the percentage change in pretax profits from the normal level for both policies in Table 5.6. Compare your answers to the values predicted by the DOL formula. 4 This formula for DOL can be derived as follows. If sales increase by 1 percent, then variable costs also should increase by 1 percent, and profits will increase by .01 × (sales – variable costs) = .01 × (profits + fixed costs). Now recall the definition of DOL: DOL = percentage change in profits percentage change in sales = change in profits/level of profits .01 = 100 × change in profits level of profits = 100 × .01 × (profits + fixed costs) level of profits = 1 + fixed costs profits Project Analysis 481 Flexibility in Capital Budgeting Sensitivity analysis and break-even analysis help managers understand why a venture might fail. Once you know this you can decide whether it is worth investing more time and effort in trying to resolve the uncertainty. Of course it is impossible to clear up all doubts about the future. Therefore, man- agers also try to build flexibility into the project and they value more highly a project that allows them to mitigate the effect of unpleasant surprises and to capitalize on pleasant ones. DECISION TREES The scientists of MacCaugh have developed a diet whiskey and the firm is ready to go ahead with pilot production and test marketing. The preliminary phase will take a year and cost $200,000. Management feels that there is only a 50-50 chance that the pilot production and market tests will be successful. If they are, then MacCaugh will build a $2 million plant which will generate an expected annual cash flow in perpetuity of $480,000 a year after taxes. Given an opportunity cost of capital of 12 percent, project NPV in this case will be –$2 million + $480,000/.12 = $2 million. If the tests are not successful, MacCaugh will discontinue the project and the cost of the pilot production will be wasted. How can MacCaugh decide whether to spend the money on the pilot program? Notice that the only decision MacCaugh needs to make now is whether to go ahead with the preliminary phase. Depending on how that works out, it may choose to go ahead with full-scale production. When faced with projects like this that involve sequential decisions, it is often help- ful to draw a decision tree, as in Figure 5.3. You can think of the problem as a game be- tween MacCaugh and fate. The square represents a decision point for MacCaugh and the circle represents a decision point for fate. MacCaugh starts the play at the left-hand box. If MacCaugh decides to test, then fate will cast the enchanted dice and decide the result of the tests. Given the test results, the firm faces a second decision: Should it in- vest $2 million and start full-scale production? Success Pursue project NPV (cid:1) $2 million Test (invest $200,000) Failure Stop project
Brealey
NPV (cid:1) 0 Don’t test NPV (cid:1) 0 DECISION TREE Diagram of sequential decisions and possible outcomes. FIGURE 5.3 Decision tree 482 SECTION FIVE The second-stage decision is obvious: Invest if the tests indicate that NPV is posi- tive, and stop if they indicate that NPV would be negative. Now the firm can easily de- cide between paying for the test program or stopping immediately. The net present value of stopping is zero, so the first-stage decision boils down to a simple problem: Should MacCaugh invest $200,000 now to obtain a 50 percent chance of a project with an NPV of $2 million a year later? If payoffs of zero and $2 million are equally likely, the ex- pected payoff is (.5 × 0) + (.5 × 2 million) = $1 million. Thus the pilot project offers an expected payoff of $1 million on an investment of $200,000. At any reasonable cost of capital this is a good deal. THE OPTION TO EXPAND Notice that MacCaugh’s expenditure on the pilot program buys a valuable managerial option. The firm has the option to produce the new product depending on the outcome of the tests. If the pilot program turns up disappointing results, the firm can walk away from the project without incurring additional costs. The option to walk away once the results are revealed introduces a valuable asymmetry. Good outcomes can be exploited, while bad outcomes can be limited by canceling the project. MacCaugh was not obliged to have a pilot program. Instead, it could have gone di- rectly into full-scale whiskey production. After all, if diet whiskey is a success, the sooner MacCaugh can clean up the market the better. But it is possible that the product will not take off; in that case the expenditure on the pilot operation may help the firm avoid a costly mistake. When it proposed a pilot project, MacCaugh’s management was simply following the fundamental rule of swimmers: If you know the water temperature (and depth), dive in; if you don’t, try putting a toe in first. Here is another example of an apparently unprofitable investment that has value be- cause of the flexibility it gives to make further follow-on investments. Some of the world’s largest oil reserves are found in the tar sands of Athabasca, Canada. Unfortu- nately, the cost of extracting oil from the sands is substantially higher than the current market price and almost certainly higher than most people’s estimate of the likely price in the future. Yet oil companies have been prepared to pay considerable sums for these tracts of barren land. Why? The answer is that ownership of these tracts gives the companies an option. They are not obliged to extract the oil. If oil prices remain below the cost of extraction, the Athabasca sands will remain undeveloped. But if prices do rise above the cost of ex- traction, those land purchases could prove very profitable. Notice that the option to develop the tar sands is valuable because the future price of oil is uncertain. If we knew that oil prices would remain at their current level, nobody would pay a cent for the tar sands. It is the possibility that oil prices may fluctuate sharply above or below their present level that gives the option value.5 As a general rule, flexibility is most valuable when the future is most uncertain. The ability to change course as events develop and new information becomes available is most valuable when it is hard to predict with confidence what the best action ultimately will turn out to be. 5 Oil prices sometimes move very sharply. They roughly halved between the beginning of 1997 and the end of 1998. By early 2000, they had almost trebled. Project Analysis 483 You can probably think of many other investments that take on added value because of the further opportunities that they may open up. For example, when designing a fac- tory, it may make sense to provide for the possibility in the future of an additional pro- duction line; when building a four-lane highway, it may pay to build six-lane bridges so that the road can be converted later to six lanes if traffic volume turns out to be higher
Brealey
than expected. ABANDONMENT OPTIONS If the option to expand has value, what about the option to bail out? Projects don’t just go on until the equipment disintegrates. The decision to terminate a project is usually taken by management, not by nature. Once the project is no longer profitable, the com- pany will cut its losses and exercise its option to abandon the project. Some assets are easier to bail out of than others. Tangible assets are usually easier to sell than intangible ones. It helps to have active secondhand markets, which really exist only for standardized, widely used items. Real estate, airplanes, trucks, and certain ma- chine tools are likely to be relatively easy to sell. On the other hand, the knowledge ac- cumulated by a drug company’s research and development program is a specialized in- tangible asset and probably would not have significant abandonment value. Some assets, such as old mattresses, even have negative abandonment value; you have to pay to get rid of them. It is very costly to decommission nuclear power plants or to reclaim land that has been strip-mined. Managers recognize the option to abandon when they make the initial investment. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 5 Abandonment Option Suppose that the Wigeon Company must choose between two technologies for the man- ufacture of a new product, a Wankel engine outboard motor: 1. Technology A uses custom-designed machinery to produce the complex shapes re- quired for Wankel engines at low cost. But if the Wankel engine doesn’t sell, this equipment will be worthless. 2. Technology B uses standard machine tools. Labor costs are much higher, but the tools can easily be sold if the motor doesn’t sell. Technology A looks better in an NPV analysis of the new product, because it was de- signed to have the lowest possible cost at the planned production volume. Yet you can sense the advantage of technology B’s flexibility if you are unsure whether the new out- board will sink or swim in the marketplace. When you are unsure about the success of a venture, you may wish to choose a flexible technology with a good resale market to preserve the option to abandon the project at low cost. (cid:1) Self-Test 6 Consider a firm operating a copper mine that incurs both variable and fixed costs of production. Suppose the mine can be shut down temporarily if copper prices fall below 484 SECTION FIVE the variable cost of mining copper. Why is this a valuable operating option? How does it increase the NPV of the mine to the operator? FLEXIBLE PRODUCTION FACILITIES Companies try to avoid becoming dependent on a single source of raw materials, build- ing flexibility into their production facilities whenever possible. For example, at current prices gas-fired industrial boilers are cheaper to operate than oil-fired ones. Yet most companies prefer to buy boilers that can use either oil or natural gas, even though these dual-fired boilers cost more than a gas-fired boiler.6 The reason is obvious. If gas prices rise relative to oil prices, the dual-fired boiler gives the company a valuable option to switch to low-cost oil. In effect the company has the option to exchange one asset (an oil-fired boiler) for another (a gas-fired boiler). If the firm is uncertain about the future demand for its products, it may also build in the option to vary the output mix. For example, in recent years automobile manufac- turers have made major investments in flexible production facilities that allow them to change their output rapidly in response to consumer demand. INVESTMENT TIMING OPTIONS Suppose that you have a project that might be a big winner or a big loser. The project’s upside potential outweighs its downside potential, and it has a positive NPV if under- taken today. However, the project is not “now-or-never.” Should you invest right away or wait? It’s hard to say. If the project truly is a winner, waiting means loss or deferral of its early cash flows. But if it turns out to be a loser, it may pay to wait and get a bet- ter fix on the likely demand.
Brealey
You can think of any project proposal as giving you the option to invest today. You don’t have to exercise that option immediately. Instead you need to weigh the value of the cash flows lost by delaying against the possibility that you will pick up some valu- able information. Think again of those tar sands in Athabasca. Suppose that the price of oil rises to 10 cents a barrel above your cost of production. You can extract the oil profitably at this price, and the required investment has a small positive NPV if the price stays where it is. But it still might be worth delaying production. After all, if the price plummets, you will by waiting avoid a costly mistake. If it rises further, however, you can invest and make a killing. We repeat, it is because the future is so uncertain that managers value flexibility. Ide- ally, a project will give the firm an option to expand if things go well and to bail out or switch production if they don’t. In addition, it may pay the firm to postpone the project. Some managers treat capital investment decisions as black boxes; they are handed cash-flow forecasts and they churn out present values without looking inside the black box. But successful firms ask not only what could be wrong with the forecasts but whether there are opportunities to respond to surprises. In other words, they recognize the value of flexibility. (cid:1) Self-Test 7 Investments in new products or production capacity often include an option to expand. What are the other major types of options encountered in capital investment decisions? 6 See N. Kulatilaka, “The Value of Flexibility: The Case of a Dual-Fuel Industrial Steam Boiler,” Financial Management 22 (Autumn 1993), pp. 271–280. Project Analysis 485 Summary What are some of the practical problems of capital budgeting in large corporations? For most large corporations there are two stages in the investment process: the preparation of the capital budget, which is a list of planned investments, and the authorization process for individual projects. This process is usually a cooperative effort. Investment projects should never be selected through a purely mechanical process. Managers need to ask why a project should have a positive NPV. A positive NPV is plausible only if the company has some competitive advantage that prevents its rivals from stealing most of the gains. How are sensitivity, scenario, and break-even analysis used to see the effect of an error in forecasts on project profitability? Why is an overestimate of sales more se- rious for projects with high operating leverage? Good managers realize that the forecasts behind NPV calculations are imperfect. Therefore, they explore the consequences of a poor forecast and check whether it is worth doing some more homework. They use the following principal tools to answer these what-if questions: • Sensitivity analysis, where one variable at a time is changed. • Scenario analysis, where the manager looks at the project under alternative scenarios. • Simulation analysis, an extension of scenario analysis in which a computer generates hundreds or thousands of possible combinations of variables. • Break-even analysis, where the focus is on how far sales could fall before the project begins to lose money. Often the phrase “lose money” is defined in terms of accounting losses, but it makes more sense to define it as “failing to cover the opportunity cost of capital”—in other words, as a negative NPV. • Operating leverage, the degree to which costs are fixed. A project’s break-even point will be affected by the extent to which costs can be reduced as sales decline. If the project has mostly fixed costs, it is said to have high operating leverage. High operating leverage implies that profits are more sensitive to changes in sales. Why is managerial flexibility important in capital budgeting? Some projects may take on added value because they give the firm the option to bail out if things go wrong or to capitalize on success by expanding. We showed how decision trees
Brealey
may be used to analyze such flexibility. Related Web Links Key Terms www.windpower.dk/tour/econ/econ.htm Evaluation of a sample energy-saving project www.palisade.com Software for Monte Carlo analysis capital budget sensitivity analysis fixed costs variable costs scenario analysis simulation analysis break-even analysis operating leverage degree of operating leverage (DOL) decision tree Quiz 1. Fixed and Variable Costs. In a slow year, Wimpy’s Burgers will produce 1 million ham- burgers at a total cost of $1.75 million. In a good year, it can produce 2 million hamburgers at a total cost of $2.25 million. What are the fixed and variable costs of hamburger produc- tion? 486 SECTION FIVE Practice Problems 2. Average Cost. Reconsider Wimpy’s Burgers from problem 1. a. What is the average cost per burger when the firm produces 1 million hamburgers? b. What is average cost when the firm produces 2 million hamburgers? c. Why is average cost lower when more burgers are produced? 3. Sensitivity Analysis. A project currently generates sales of $10 million, variable costs equal to 50 percent of sales, and fixed costs of $2 million. The firm’s tax rate is 35 percent. What are the effects of the following changes on after-tax profits and cash flow? a. Sales increase from $10 million to $11 million. b. Variable costs increase to 60 percent of sales. 4. Sensitivity Analysis. The project in the preceding problem will last for 10 years. The dis- count rate is 12 percent. a. What is the effect on project NPV of each of the changes considered in the problem? b. If project NPV under the base-case scenario is $2 million, how much can fixed costs in- crease before NPV turns negative? c. How much can fixed costs increase before accounting profits turn negative? 5. Sensitivity Analysis. Emperor’s Clothes Fashions can invest $5 million in a new plant for producing invisible makeup. The plant has an expected life of 5 years, and expected sales are 6 million jars of makeup a year. Fixed costs are $2 million a year, and variable costs are $1 per jar. The product will be priced at $2 per jar. The plant will be depreciated straight-line over 5 years to a salvage value of zero. The opportunity cost of capital is 12 percent, and the tax rate is 40 percent. a. What is project NPV under these base-case assumptions? b. What is NPV if variable costs turn out to be $1.20 per jar? c. What is NPV if fixed costs turn out to be $1.5 million per year? d. At what price per jar would project NPV equal zero? 6. Scenario Analysis. The most likely outcomes for a particular project are estimated as follows: Unit price: Variable cost: Fixed cost: Expected sales: $50 $30 $300,000 30,000 units per year However, you recognize that some of these estimates are subject to error. Suppose that each variable may turn out to be either 10 percent higher or 10 percent lower than the initial esti- mate. The project will last for 10 years and requires an initial investment of $1 million, which will be depreciated straight-line over the project life to a final value of zero. The firm’s tax rate is 35 percent and the required rate of return is 14 percent. What is project NPV in the “best-case scenario,” that is, assuming all variables take on the best possible value? What about the worst-case scenario? 7. Scenario Analysis. Reconsider the best- and worst-case scenarios in the previous problem. Do the best- and worst-case outcomes when each variable is treated independently seem to be reasonable scenarios in terms of the combinations of variables? For example, if price is higher than predicted, is it more or less likely that cost is higher than predicted? What other relationships may exist among the variables? 8. Break-Even. The following estimates have been prepared for a project under consideration: Project Analysis 487 Fixed costs: Depreciation: Price: Accounting break-even: $20,000 $10,000 $2 60,000 units What must be the variable cost per unit? 9. Break-Even. Dime a Dozen Diamonds makes synthetic diamonds by treating carbon. Each
Brealey
diamond can be sold for $100. The materials cost for a standard diamond is $30. The fixed costs incurred each year for factory upkeep and administrative expenses are $200,000. The machinery costs $1 million and is depreciated straight-line over 10 years to a salvage value of zero. a. What is the accounting break-even level of sales in terms of number of diamonds sold? b. What is the NPV break-even level of sales assuming a tax rate of 35 percent, a 10-year project life, and a discount rate of 12 percent? 10. Break-Even. Turn back to problem 9. a. Would the accounting break-even point in the first year of operation increase or decrease if the machinery were depreciated over a 5-year period? b. Would the NPV break-even point increase or decrease if the machinery were depreciated over a 5-year period? 11. Break-Even. You are evaluating a project that will require an investment of $10 million that will be depreciated over a period of 7 years. You are concerned that the corporate tax rate will increase during the life of the project. Would such an increase affect the accounting break-even point? Would it affect the NPV break-even point? 12. Break-Even. Define the cash-flow break-even point as the sales volume (in dollars) at which cash flow equals zero. Is the cash-flow break-even level of sales higher or lower than the zero-profit break-even point? 13. Break-Even and NPV. If a project operates at cash-flow break-even (see problem 12) for its entire life, what must be true of the project’s NPV? 14. Break-Even. Modern Artifacts can produce keepsakes that will be sold for $80 each. Non- depreciation fixed costs are $1,000 per year and variable costs are $60 per unit. a. If the project requires an initial investment of $3,000 and is expected to last for 5 years and the firm pays no taxes, what are the accounting and NPV break-even levels of sales? The initial investment will be depreciated straight-line over 5 years to a final value of zero, and the discount rate is 10 percent. b. How do your answers change if the firm’s tax rate is 40 percent? 15. Break-Even. A financial analyst has computed both accounting and NPV break-even sales levels for a project under consideration using straight-line depreciation over a 6-year period. The project manager wants to know what will happen to these estimates if the firm uses MACRS depreciation instead. The capital investment will be in a 5-year recovery period class under MACRS rules (see Table 7.4). The firm is in a 35 percent tax bracket. a. What (qualitatively) will happen to the accounting break-even level of sales in the first years of the project? b. What (qualitatively) will happen to NPV break-even level of sales? c. If you were advising the analyst, would the answer to (a) or (b) be important to you? Specifically, would you say that the switch to MACRS makes the project more or less at- tractive? 488 SECTION FIVE 16. Break-Even. Reconsider Finefodder’s new superstore. Suppose that by investing an addi- tional $600,000 initially in more efficient checkout equipment, Finefodder could reduce variable costs to 80 percent of sales. a. Using the base-case assumptions (Table 5.1), find the NPV of this alternative scheme. Hint: Remember to focus on the incremental cash flows from the project. b. At what level of sales will accounting profits be unchanged if the firm invests in the new equipment? Assume the equipment receives the same 12-year straight-line depreciation treatment as in the original example. Hint: Focus on the project’s incremental effects on fixed and variable costs. c. What is the NPV break-even point? 17. Break-Even and NPV. If the superstore project (see the previous problem) operates at ac- counting break-even, will net present value be positive or negative? 18. Operating Leverage. You estimate that your cattle farm will generate $1 million of profits on sales of $4 million under normal economic conditions, and that the degree of operating leverage is 7.5. What will profits be if sales turn out to be $3.5 million? What if they are
Brealey
$4.5 million? 19. Operating Leverage. a. What is the degree of operating leverage of Modern Artifacts (in problem 14) when sales are $8,000? b. What is the degree of operating leverage when sales are $10,000? c. Why is operating leverage different at these two levels of sales? 20. Operating Leverage. What is the lowest possible value for the degree of operating leverage for a profitable firm? Show with a numerical example that if Modern Artifacts (see problem 14a) has zero fixed costs, then DOL = 1 and in fact sales and profits are directly propor- tional so that a 1 percent change in sales results in a 1 percent change in profits. 21. Operating Leverage. A project has fixed costs of $1,000 per year, depreciation charges of $500 a year, revenue of $6,000 a year, and variable costs equal to two-thirds of revenues. a. If sales increase by 5 percent, what will be the increase in pretax profits? b. What is the degree of operating leverage of this project? c. Confirm that the percentage change in profits equals DOL times the percentage change in sales. 22. Project Options. Your midrange guess as to the amount of oil in a prospective field is 10 million barrels, but in fact there is a 50 percent chance that the amount of oil is 15 million barrels, and a 50 percent chance of 5 million barrels. If the actual amount of oil is 15 mil- lion barrels, the present value of the cash flows from drilling will be $8 million. If the amount is only 5 million barrels, the present value will be only $2 million. It costs $3 million to drill the well. Suppose that a seismic test that costs $100,000 can verify the amount of oil under the ground. Is it worth paying for the test? Use a decision tree to justify your answer. 23. Project Options. A silver mine can yield 10,000 ounces of copper at a variable cost of $8 per ounce. The fixed costs of operating the mine are $10,000 per year. In half the years, sil- ver can be sold for $12 per ounce; in the other years, silver can be sold for only $6 per ounce. Ignore taxes. a. What is the average cash flow you will receive from the mine if it is always kept in op- eration and the silver always is sold in the year it is mined? b. Now suppose you can shut down the mine in years of low silver prices. What happens to the average cash flow from the mine? Challenge Problems Solutions to Self-Test Questions Project Analysis 489 24. Project Options. An auto plant that costs $100 million to build can produce a new line of cars that will produce cash flows with a present value of $140 million if the line is success- ful, but only $50 million if it is unsuccessful. You believe that the probability of success is only about 50 percent. a. Would you build the plant? b. Suppose that the plant can be sold for $90 million to another automaker if the auto line is not successful. Now would you build the plant? c. Illustrate the option to abandon in (b) using a decision tree. 25. Production Options. Explain why options to expand or contract production are most valu- able when forecasts about future business conditions are most uncertain. 26. Abandonment Option. Hit or Miss Sports is introducing a new product this year. If its see- at-night soccer balls are a hit, the firm expects to be able to sell 50,000 units a year at a price of $60 each. If the new product is a bust, only 30,000 units can be sold at a price of $55. The variable cost of each ball is $30, and fixed costs are zero. The cost of the manufacturing equipment is $6 million, and the project life is estimated at 10 years. The firm will use straight-line depreciation over the 10-year life of the project. The firm’s tax rate is 35 per- cent and the discount rate is 12 percent. a. If each outcome is equally likely, what is expected NPV? Will the firm accept the proj- ect? b. Suppose now that the firm can abandon the project and sell off the manufacturing equip- ment for $5.4 million if demand for the balls turns out to be weak. The firm will make the decision to continue or abandon after the first year of sales. Does the option to aban-
Brealey
don change the firm’s decision to accept the project? 27. Expansion Option. Now suppose that Hit or Miss Sports from the previous problem can ex- pand production if the project is successful. By paying its workers overtime, it can increase production by 20,000 units; the variable cost of each ball will be higher, however, equal to $35 per unit. By how much does this option to expand production increase the NPV of the project? 1 Cash flow forecasts for Finefodder’s new superstore: Investment –5,400,000 Year 0 Years 1–12 1. Sales 2. Variable costs 3. Fixed costs 4. Depreciation 5. Pretax profit (1 – 2 – 3 – 4) 6. Taxes (at 40%) 7. Profit after tax 8. Cash flow from operations (4 + 7) Net cash flow –5,400,000 16,000,000 13,280,000 2,000,000 450,000 270,000 108,000 162,000 612,000 612,000 NPV = –$5.4 million + (7.536 × $612,000) = –$788,000 2 Both calculate how NPV depends on input assumptions. Sensitivity analysis changes inputs one at a time, whereas scenario analysis changes several variables at once. The changes should add up to a consistent scenario for the project as a whole. 490 SECTION FIVE 3 With the lower initial investment, depreciation is also lower; it now equals $417,000 per year. Cash flow is now as follows: 1. Variable costs 2. Fixed costs 3. Depreciation 4. Pretax profit 5. Tax (at 40%) 6. Profit after tax 7. Cash flow (3 + 6) 81.25 percent of sales $2 million $417,000 (.1875 × sales) – $2.417 million .4 × (.1875 × sales – $2.417 million) .6 × (.1875 × sales – $2.417 million) .6 × (.1875 × sales – $2.417 million) + $417,000 = .1125 × sales – $1.033 million Break-even occurs when PV (cash inflows) = investment 7.536 × (.1125 × sales – $1.033 million) = $5.0 million and sales = $15.08 million. 4 Break-even analysis finds the level of sales or revenue at which NPV = 0. Sensitivity analy- sis changes these and other input variables to optimistic and pessimistic values and recalcu- lates NPV. 5 Reworking Table 8.6 for the normal level of sales and 10 percent higher sales gives the fol- lowing: High Fixed Costs High Variable Costs Normal 10% Higher Sales Normal 10% Higher Sales Sales – Variable costs – Fixed costs – Depreciation = Pretax profit 16,000 13,000 2,000 450 550 17,600 14,300 2,000 450 850 16,000 13,440 1,560 450 550 17,600 14,784 1,560 450 806 For the high-fixed-cost policy, profits increase by 54.5 percent, from $550,000 to $850,000. For the low-fixed-cost policy, profits increase by 46.5 percent. In both cases the percentage increase in profits equals DOL times the percentage increase in sales. This illustrates that DOL measures the sensitivity of profits to changes in sales. 6 The option to shut down is valuable because the mine operator can avoid incurring losses when copper prices are low. If the shut-down option were not available, cash flow in the low- price periods would be negative. With the option, the worst cash flow is zero. By allowing managers to respond to market conditions, the option makes the worst-case cash flow bet- ter than it would be otherwise. The average cash flow (that is, averaging over all possible scenarios) therefore must improve, which increases project NPV. 7 Abandonment options, options due to flexible production facilities, investment timing op- tions. Project Analysis 491 MINICASE Maxine Peru, the CEO of Peru Resources, hardly noticed the plate of savory quenelles de brochet and the glass of Corton Charlemagne ’94 on the table before her. She was absorbed by the engineering report handed to her just as she entered the exec- utive dining room. The report described a proposed new mine on the North Ridge of Mt. Zircon. A vein of transcendental zirconium ore had been discovered there on land owned by Ms. Peru’s company. Test bor- ings indicated sufficient reserves to produce 340 tons per year of transcendental zirconium over a 7-year period. The vein probably also contained hydrated zircon gemstones. The amount and quality of these zircons were hard to predict, since they tended to occur in “pockets.” The new mine might come across one, two, or dozens of pockets. The mining engineer
Brealey
guessed that 150 pounds per year might be found. The current price for high-quality hydrated zircon gemstones was $3,300 per pound. Peru Resources was a family-owned business with total assets of $45 million, including cash reserves of $4 million. The outlay required for the new mine would be a major commitment. Fortu- nately, Peru Resources was conservatively financed, and Ms. Peru believed that the company could borrow up to $9 million at an in- terest rate of about 8 percent. The mine’s operating costs were projected at $900,000 per year, including $400,000 of fixed costs and $500,000 of variable costs. Ms. Peru thought these forecasts were accurate. The big question marks seemed to be the initial cost of the mine and the selling price of transcendental zirconium. Opening the mine, and providing the necessary machinery and ore-crunching facilities, was supposed to cost $10 million, but cost overruns of 10 percent or 15 percent were common in the mining business. In addition, new environmental regulations, if enacted, could increase the cost of the mine by $1.5 million. There was a cheaper design for the mine, which would reduce its cost by $1.7 million and eliminate much of the uncertainty about cost overruns. Unfortunately, this design would require much higher fixed operating costs. Fixed costs would increase to $850,000 per year at planned production levels. The current price of transcendental zirconium was $10,000 per ton, but there was no consensus about future prices.1 Some experts were projecting rapid price increases to as much as $14,000 per ton. On the other hand, there were pessimists saying that prices could be as low as $7,500 per ton. Ms. Peru did not have strong views either way: her best guess was that price would just increase with inflation at about 3.5 percent per year. (Mine operating costs would also increase with inflation.) Ms. Peru had wide experience in the mining business, and she knew that investors in similar projects usually wanted a fore- casted nominal rate of return of at least 14 percent. You have been asked to assist Ms. Peru in evaluating this proj- ect. Lay out the base-case NPV analysis and undertake sensitiv- ity, scenario, or break-even analyses as appropriate. Assume that Peru Resources pays tax at a 35 percent rate. For simplicity, also assume that the investment in the mine could be depreciated for tax purposes straight-line over 7 years. What forecasts or scenarios should worry Ms. Peru the most? Where would additional information be most helpful? Is there a case for delaying construction of the new mine? 1 There were no traded forward or futures contracts on transcendental zir- conium. AN OVERVIEW OF CORPORATE FINANCING Common Stock Book Value versus Market Value Dividends Stockholders’ Rights Voting Procedures Classes of Stock Corporate Governance in the United States and Elsewhere Preferred Stock Corporate Debt Debt Comes in Many Forms Innovation in the Debt Market Convertible Securities Patterns of Corporate Financing Do Firms Rely Too Heavily on Internal Funds? External Sources of Capital Summary There are more than 57 different kinds of security that a company can issue. Scott Goodwin Photography 493 T his material begins our analysis of long-term financing decisions. In later material this will involve a careful look at some classic finance prob- lems, such as how much firms should borrow and what dividends they should pay their shareholders. But before getting down to specifics, we will provide a brief overview of types of long-term finance. It is customary to classify sources of finance as debt or equity. When the firm bor- rows, it promises to repay the debt with interest. If it doesn’t keep its promise, the debtholders may force the firm into bankruptcy. However, no such commitments are made to the equityholders. They are entitled to whatever is left over after the debthold- ers have been paid off. For this reason, equity is called a residual claim on the firm.
Brealey
However, a simple division of sources of finance into debt and equity would miss the enormous variety of financing instruments that companies use today. For example, Table 5.7 shows the many long-term securities issued by H. J. Heinz. Yet H. J. Heinz has not come close to exhausting the menu of possible securities. This material introduces you to the principal families of securities and explains how they are used by corporations. We also draw attention to some of the interesting aspects of firms issuing these securities. After studying this material you should be able to (cid:1) Describe the major classes of securities issued by firms to raise capital. (cid:1) Summarize recent trends in the use made by firms of different sources of finance. Common Stock Most major corporations are far too large to be owned by one investor. For example, you would need to lay your hands on over $17 billion if you wanted to own the whole H. J. Heinz Company. Heinz is owned by about 61,000 different investors, each of whom holds a number of shares of common stock. These investors are therefore known as shareholders or stockholders. Altogether Heinz has outstanding 358 million shares of common stock. Thus if you were to buy one Heinz share, you would own 1/358,000,000, or about .00000028 percent of the company. Of course, a large pension fund might hold many thousands of Heinz shares. The 358 million shares held by investors are not the only shares that have been is- sued by Heinz. The company has also issued a further 72 million shares, which it later bought back from investors. These shares are held in the company’s treasury and are known as treasury stock. The shares held by investors are said to be issued and out- standing shares. By contrast, the 72 million treasury shares are said to be issued but not outstanding. If Heinz wishes to raise more money, it can sell more shares. However, there is a limit to the number that it can issue without getting the approval of the current share- TREASURY STOCK Stock that has been repurchased by the company and held in its treasury. ISSUED SHARES Shares that have been issued by the company. OUTSTANDING SHARES Shares that have been issued by the company and are held by investors. 494 TABLE 5.7 Large firms use many different kinds of securities. Look at the variety of securities issued by H. J. Heinz AUTHORIZED SHARE CAPITAL Maximum number of shares that the company is permitted to issue, as specified in the firm’s articles of incorporation. PAR VALUE Value of security shown on certificate. ADDITIONAL PAID-IN CAPITAL Difference between issue price and par value of stock. Also called capital surplus. TABLE 5.8 Book value of common stockholders’ equity of H. J. Heinz Company, April 28, 1999 (figures in millions) An Overview of Corporate Financing 495 Equity Common stock Preferred stock Debt Commercial paper Senior unsecured notes Revenue bonds Promissory notes Eurodollar bonds Sterling notes Italian lira notes Australian dollar notes Bank loans holders. The maximum number of shares that can be issued is known as the authorized share capital—for Heinz, this is 600 million shares. Since Heinz has already issued 431 million shares, it can issue 169 million more without shareholders’ approval. Table 5.8 shows how the investment by Heinz’s common stockholders is recorded in the company’s books. The price at which each share is recorded is known as its par value. In Heinz’s case each share has a par value of $.25. Thus the total par value of the issued shares is 431 million shares × $.25 per share = $108 million. Par value has little economic significance.1 The price at which new shares are sold to investors almost always exceeds par value. The difference is entered into the company’s accounts as additional paid-in capital, or capital surplus. For example, if Heinz sold an additional 100,000 shares at $50 a share, the par value of the common stock would increase by 100,000 × $.25 = $25,000 and ad- ditional paid-in capital would increase by 100,000 × ($50 – $.25) = $4,975,000. You can
Brealey
see from this example that the funds raised from the stock issue are divided between par value and additional paid-in capital. Since the choice of par value in the first place was immaterial, so is the allocation between par value and additional paid-in capital. Common shares ($.25 par value per share) Additional paid-in capital Retained earnings Treasury shares at cost Net common equity $108 278 3,853 (2,435) 1,803 Note: Authorized shares Issued shares, of which Outstanding shares Treasury shares 431 358 72 1 Because some states do not allow companies to sell new shares below par value, par value is generally set at a low figure. Some companies even issue shares with no par value, in which case the stock is listed in the accounts at an arbitrarily determined figure. 496 SECTION FIVE RETAINED EARNINGS Earnings not paid out as dividends. Besides buying new stock, shareholders also indirectly contribute new capital to the firm whenever profits that could be paid out as dividends are instead plowed back into the company. Table 5.8 shows that the cumulative amount of such retained earnings is $3,853. Heinz’s books also show the amount that the company has spent in the past on re- purchasing its own stock. The repurchase of the 72 million shares cost Heinz $2,435 million. This is money that has in effect been returned to shareholders. The sum of the par value, additional paid-in capital, and retained earnings, less re- purchased stock, is known as the net common equity of the firm. It equals the total amount contributed directly by shareholders when the firm issued new stock and indi- rectly when it plowed back part of its earnings. (cid:1) Self-Test 1 Generic Products has had one stock issue in which it sold 100,000 shares to the public at $15 per share. Can you fill in the following table? Common shares ($1.00 par value per share) Additional paid-in capital Retained earnings Net common equity ________ ________ ________ $4,500,000 BOOK VALUE VERSUS MARKET VALUE We discussed the distinction between book and market value earlier, but it bears repeating. Book value is a backward-looking measure. It tells us how much capital the firm has raised from shareholders in the past. It does not measure the value that investors place on those shares today. The market value of the firm is forward-looking; it depends on the future dividends that shareholders expect to receive. Heinz’s common equity has a book value of $1,803 million. With 358 million shares outstanding, this translates to a book value of $1,803/358 = $5.04 per share. But in April 1999 Heinz shares were priced at about $49 each. So the total market value of the com- mon stock was 358 million shares × $49 per share = $17.5 billion, nearly 10 times the book value. Market value is usually greater than book value. This is partly because inflation has driven the value of many assets above what they originally cost. Also, firms raise capi- tal to invest in projects with present values that exceed initial cost. These positive-NPV projects made the shareholders better off. So we would expect the market value of the firm to be higher than the amount of money put up by the shareholders. However, sometimes projects do go awry and companies fall on hard times. In this case, market value can fall below book value. An Overview of Corporate Financing 497 (cid:1) Self-Test 2 No-name News can be established by investing $10 million in a printing press. The newspaper is expected to generate a cash flow of $2 million a year for 20 years. If the cost of capital is 10 percent, is the firm’s market or book value greater? What if the cost of capital is 20 percent? DIVIDENDS Shareholders hope to receive a series of dividends on their investment. However, the company is not obliged to pay any dividend and the decision is up to the board of di- rectors. Because dividends are discretionary, they are not considered to be a business ex- pense. Therefore, companies are not allowed to deduct dividend payments when they calculate their taxable income.
Brealey
STOCKHOLDERS’ RIGHTS Stockholders have the ultimate control of the company’s affairs. Occasionally compa- nies need shareholder approval before they can take certain actions. For example, they need approval to increase the authorized capital or to merge with another company. On most other matters, shareholder control boils down to the right to vote on appointments to the board of directors. The board usually consists of the company’s top management as well as outside di- rectors, who are not employed by the firm. In principle, the board is elected as an agent of the shareholders. It appoints and oversees the management of the firm and meets to vote on such matters as new share issues. Most of the time the board will go along with the management, but in crisis situations it can be very independent. For example, when the management of RJR Nabisco announced that it wanted to take over the company, the outside directors stepped in to make sure that the company was sold to the highest bidder. VOTING PROCEDURES MAJORITY VOTING Voting system in which each director is voted on separately. CUMULATIVE VOTING Voting system in which all the votes one shareholder is allowed to cast can be cast for one candidate for the board of directors. In most companies stockholders elect directors by a system of majority voting. In this case each director is voted on separately and stockholders can cast one vote for each share they own. In some companies directors are elected by cumulative voting. The di- rectors are then voted on jointly and the stockholders can, if they choose, cast all their votes for just one candidate. For example, suppose there are five directors to be elected and you own 100 shares. You therefore have a total of 5 × 100 = 500 votes. Under ma- jority voting you can cast a maximum of 100 votes for any one candidate. With a cu- mulative voting system you can cast all 500 votes for your favorite candidate. Cumula- tive voting makes it easier for a minority group of the stockholders to elect a director to represent their interests. That is why minority groups devote so much effort to cam- paigning for cumulative voting. On many issues a simple majority of the votes cast is enough to carry the day, but there are some decisions that require a “supermajority” of, say, 75 percent of those 498 SECTION FIVE PROXY CONTEST Takeover attempt in which outsiders compete with management for shareholders’ votes. eligible to vote. For example, a supermajority vote is sometimes needed to approve a merger. This requirement makes it difficult for the firm to be taken over and therefore helps to protect the incumbent management. Shareholders can either vote in person or appoint a proxy to vote. The issues on which they are asked to vote are rarely contested, particularly in the case of large, pub- licly traded firms. Occasionally, however, there are proxy contests in which outsiders compete with the firm’s existing management and directors for control of the corpora- tion. But the odds are stacked against the outsiders, for the insiders can get the firm to pay all the costs of presenting their case and obtaining votes. CLASSES OF STOCK Most companies issue just one class of common stock. Sometimes, however, a firm may have two or more classes outstanding, which differ in their right to vote or receive div- idends. Suppose that a firm needs fresh capital but its present stockholders do not want to give up control of the firm. The existing shares could be labeled class A, and then class B shares could be issued to outside investors. The class B shares could have lim- ited voting rights, although they would probably sell for less as a result. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN THE UNITED STATES AND ELSEWHERE Heinz’s shareholders own the company but they don’t manage it. Management is dele- gated to a team of professional managers. Each shareholder owns only a small fraction of Heinz’s shares and can exert little influence on the way the company is run. If share- holders do not like the policies the management team pursues, they can try to vote in
Brealey
another board of directors who will bring about a change in policy. But such attempts are rarely successful, and the shareholders’ simplest solution is to sell the shares. The separation between ownership and management in major United States corpo- rations creates a potential conflict between shareholders (the principals who own the company) and managers (their agents who make the decisions). We noted earlier sev- eral mechanisms that have evolved to mitigate this conflict: • Shareholders elect a board of directors, which then appoints the managers, oversees them, and on occasion fires them. • Managers’ remuneration is tied to their performance. • Poorly performing companies are taken over and the management is replaced by a new team. These principles of corporate governance do not apply worldwide. The United States, Canada, Britain, Australia, and other English-speaking countries all have broadly similar systems, but other countries do not. In Japan industrial and financial companies are often linked together in a group, called a keiretsu. For example, the Mit- subishi keiretsu contains 29 core companies, including two banks, two insurance com- panies, an automobile manufacturer, a steel producer, and a cement company. Members of the keiretsu are tied together in several ways. First, managers may sit on the boards of directors of other group companies, and a “president’s council” of chief executives meets regularly. Second, each company in the group holds shares in many of the other companies. And third, companies generally borrow from the keiretsu’s bank or from elsewhere within the group. These links may have several advantages. Companies can obtain funds from other members of the group without the need to reveal confidential An Overview of Corporate Financing 499 information to the public, and if a member of the group runs into financial heavy weather, its problems can be worked out with other members of the group rather than in the bankruptcy court. The more stable and concentrated shareholder base of large Japanese corporations may make it easier for them to resist pressures for short-term performance and allow them to focus on securing long-term advantage. But the Japanese system of corporate governance also has its disadvantages, for the lack of market discipline may promote a too-cozy life and allow lagging or inefficient Japanese corporations to put off painful surgery. Keiretsus are found only in Japan. But large companies in continental Europe are linked in some similar ways. For example, banks and other companies often own or con- trol large blocks of shares and can push hard for changes in the management or strat- egy of poorly performing firms. (Banks in the United States are prohibited from large or permanent holdings of the stock of nonfinancial corporations.) Thus oversight and control are entrusted largely to banks and other corporations. Hostile takeovers of poorly performing companies are rare in Germany and virtually impossible in Japan. For large corporations, separation of ownership and control is seen the world over. In the United States, control of large public companies is exercised through the board of directors and pressure from the stock market. In other countries the stock market is less important, and control shifts to major stockholders, typically banks and other companies. Preferred Stock Usually when investors talk about equity or stock, they are referring to common stock. But Heinz has also issued $200,000 of preferred stock, and this too is part of the com- pany’s equity. The sum of Heinz’s common equity and preferred stock is known as its net worth. For most companies preferred stock is much less important than common stock. However, it can be a useful method of financing in mergers and certain other special sit- uations. Like debt, preferred stock promises a series of fixed payments to the investor and with relatively rare exceptions preferred dividends are paid in full and on time. Never-
Brealey
theless, preferred stock is legally an equity security. This is because payment of a pre- ferred dividend is almost invariably within the discretion of the directors. The only ob- ligation is that no dividends can be paid on the common stock until the preferred dividend has been paid.2 If the company goes out of business, the preferred stockhold- ers get in the queue after the debtholders but before the common stockholders. Preferred stock rarely confers full voting privileges. This is an advantage to firms that want to raise new money without sharing control of the firm with the new share- holders. However, if there is any matter that affects their place in the queue, preferred stockholders usually get to vote on it. Most issues also provide the holder with some voting power if the preferred dividend is skipped. Companies cannot deduct preferred dividends when they calculate taxable income. 2 These days this obligation is usually cumulative. In other words, before the common stockholders get a cent, the firm must pay any preferred dividends that have been missed in the past. PREFERRED STOCK Stock that takes priority over common stock in regard to dividends. NET WORTH Book value of common stockholders’ equity plus preferred stock. 500 SECTION FIVE FLOATING-RATE PREFERRED Preferred stock paying dividends that vary with short-term interest rates. (cid:1) Self-Test 3 Like common stock dividends, preferred dividends are paid from after-tax income. For most industrial firms this is a serious deterrent to issuing preferred. However, regulated public utilities can take tax payments into account when they negotiate with regulators the rates they charge customers. So they can effectively pass the tax disadvantage of preferred on to the consumer. A large fraction of the dollar value of new offerings of or- dinary preferred stock consists of issues by utilities. Preferred stock does have one tax advantage. If one corporation buys another’s stock, only 30 percent of the dividends it receives is taxed. This rule applies to dividends on both common and preferred stock, but it is most important for preferred, for which returns are dominated by dividends rather than capital gains. Suppose that your firm has surplus cash to invest. If it buys a bond, the interest will be taxed at the company’s tax rate of 35 percent. If it buys a preferred share, it owns an asset like a bond (the preferred dividends can be viewed as “interest”), but the effective tax rate is only 30 percent of 35 percent, .30 × .35 = .105, or 10.5 percent. It is no sur- prise that most preferred shares are held by corporations. If you invest your firm’s spare cash in a preferred stock, you will want to make sure that when it is time to sell the stock, it won’t have plummeted in value. One problem with garden-variety preferred stock that pays a fixed dividend is that the preferreds’ market prices go up and down as interest rates change (because present values fall when rates rise). So one ingenious banker thought up a wrinkle: Why not link the dividend on the preferred stock to interest rates so that it goes up when interest rates rise and vice versa? The result is known as floating-rate preferred. If you own floating-rate pre- ferred, you know that any change in interest rates will be counterbalanced by a change in the dividend payment, so the value of your investment is protected. A company in a 35 percent tax bracket can buy a bond yielding 10 percent or a pre- ferred stock of the same firm that is priced to yield 8 percent. Which will provide the higher after-tax yield? What if the purchaser is a private individual in a 35 percent tax bracket? Corporate Debt When they borrow money, companies promise to make regular interest payments and to repay the principal (that is, the original amount borrowed). However, corporations have limited liability. By this we mean that the promise to repay the debt is not always kept. If the company gets into deep water, the company has the right to default on the debt and to hand over the company’s
Brealey
assets to the lenders. Clearly it will choose bankruptcy only if the value of the assets is less than the amount of the debt. In practice, when companies go bankrupt, this handover of assets is far from straightforward. For example, when the furniture company Wickes went into bank- ruptcy, there were 250,000 creditors all jostling for a better place in the queue. Sorting out these problems is left to the bankruptcy court. Because lenders are not regarded as owners of the firm, they don’t normally have any An Overview of Corporate Financing 501 voting power. Also, the company’s payments of interest are regarded as a cost and are therefore deducted from taxable income. Thus interest is paid out of before-tax income, whereas dividends on common and preferred stock are paid out of after-tax income. This means that the government provides a tax subsidy on the use of debt, which it does not provide on stock. DEBT COMES IN MANY FORMS Some orderly scheme of classification is essential to cope with the almost endless va- riety of debt issues. We will walk you through the major distinguishing characteristics. Interest Rate. The interest payment, or coupon, on most long-term loans is fixed at the time of issue. If a $1,000 bond is issued with a coupon of 10 percent, the firm con- tinues to pay $100 a year regardless of how interest rates change. As we pointed out- earlier, you sometimes encounter zero-coupon bonds. In this case the firm does not make a regular interest payment. It just makes a single payment at maturity. Obviously, investors pay less for zero-coupon bonds. Most loans from a bank and some long-term loans carry a floating interest rate. For example, your firm may be offered a loan at “1 percent over prime.” The prime rate is the benchmark interest rate charged by banks to large customers with good to excellent credit. (But the largest and most creditworthy corporations can, and do, borrow at less than prime.) The prime rate is adjusted up and down with the general level of interest rates. When the prime rate changes, the interest on your floating-rate loan also changes. Floating-rate loans are not always tied to the prime rate. Often they are tied to the rate at which international banks lend to one another. This is known as the London In- terbank Offered Rate, or LIBOR. Would you expect the price of a 10-year floating-rate bond to be more or less sensitive to changes in interest rates than the price of a 10-year maturity fixed-rate bond? Maturity. Funded debt is any debt repayable more than 1 year from the date of issue. Debt due in less than a year is termed unfunded and is carried on the balance sheet as a current liability. Unfunded debt is often described as short-term debt and funded debt is described as long-term, although it is clearly artificial to call a 364-day debt short- term and a 366-day debt long-term (except in leap years). There are corporate bonds of nearly every conceivable maturity. For example, Walt Disney Co. has issued bonds with a 100-year maturity. Some British banks have issued perpetuities—that is, bonds which may survive forever. At the other extreme we find firms borrowing literally overnight. Repayment Provisions. Long-term loans are commonly repaid in a steady regular way, perhaps after an initial grace period. For bonds that are publicly traded, this is done by means of a sinking fund. Each year the firm puts aside a sum of cash into a sinking fund that is then used to buy back the bonds. When there is a sinking fund, investors are prepared to lend at a lower rate of interest. They know that they are more likely to be repaid if the company sets aside some cash each year than if the entire loan has to be repaid on one specified day. Firms issuing debt to the public sometimes reserve the right to call the debt—that is, PRIME RATE Benchmark interest rate charged by banks. (cid:1) Self-Test 4 FUNDED DEBT Debt with more than 1 year remaining to maturity. SINKING FUND Fund established to retire debt before maturity.
Brealey
502 SECTION FIVE CALLABLE BOND Bond that may be repurchased by firm before maturity at specified call price. (cid:1) Self-Test 5 SUBORDINATED DEBT Debt that may be repaid in bankruptcy only after senior debt is paid. SECURED DEBT Debt that has first claim on specified collateral in the event of default. issuers of callable bonds may buy back the bonds before the final maturity date. The price at which the firm can call the bonds is set at the time that the bonds are issued. This option to call the bond is attractive to the issuer. If interest rates decline and bond prices rise, the issuer may repay the bonds at the specified call price and borrow the money back at a lower rate of interest.3 The call provision comes at the expense of bondholders, for it limits investors’ cap- ital gain potential. If interest rates fall and bond prices rise, holders of callable bonds may find their bonds bought back by the firm for the call price. Suppose Heinz is considering two issues of 20-year maturity coupon bonds; one issue will be callable, the other not. For a given coupon rate, will the callable or noncallable bond sell at the higher price? If the bonds are both to be sold to the public at par value, which bond must have the higher coupon rate? Seniority. Some debts are subordinated. In the event of default the subordinated lender gets in line behind the firm’s general creditors. The subordinated lender holds a junior claim and is paid only after all senior creditors are satisfied. When you lend money to a firm, you can assume that you hold a senior claim unless the debt agreement says otherwise. However, this does not always put you at the front of the line, for the firm may have set aside some of its assets specifically for the pro- tection of other lenders. That brings us to our next classification. Security. When you borrow to buy your home, the savings and loan company will take out a mortgage on the house. The mortgage acts as security for the loan. If you de- fault on the loan payments, the S&L can seize your home. When companies borrow, they also may set aside certain assets as security for the loan. These assets are termed collateral and the debt is said to be secured. In the event of default, the secured lender has first claim on the collateral; unsecured lenders have a general claim on the rest of the firm’s assets but only a junior claim on the collateral. Default Risk. Seniority and security do not guarantee payment. A debt can be senior and secured but still as risky as a dizzy tightrope walker—it depends on the value and the risk of the firm’s assets. Earlier, we showed how the safety of most corporate bonds can be judged from bond ratings provided by Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s. Bonds that are rated “triple-A” seldom default. At the other extreme, many speculative-grade (or “junk”) bonds may be teetering on the brink. As you would expect, investors demand a high return from low-rated bonds. We saw evidence of this in Section 3, where Figure 3.9 showed yields on default-free U.S. Trea- sury bonds as well as on corporate bonds in various rating classes. The lower-rated bonds did in fact offer higher promised yields to maturity. Country and Currency. These days capital markets know few national boundaries and many large firms in the United States borrow abroad. For example, an American company may choose to finance a new plant in Switzerland by borrowing Swiss francs from a Swiss bank, or it may expand its Dutch operation by issuing a bond in Holland. 3 Sometimes callable bonds specify a period during which the firm is not allowed to call the bond if the pur- pose is simply to issue another bond at a lower interest rate. An Overview of Corporate Financing 503 Also many foreign companies come to the United States to borrow dollars, which are then used to finance their operations throughout the world. In addition to these national capital markets, there is also an international capital market centered mainly in London. There are some 500 banks in London from over 70
Brealey
different countries; they include such giants as Citicorp, Union Bank of Switzerland, Deutsche Bank, Bank of Tokyo–Mitsubishi, Banque Nationale de Paris, and Barclays Bank. One reason they are there is to collect deposits in the major currencies. For ex- ample, suppose an Arab sheikh has just received payment in dollars for a large sale of oil to the United States. Rather than depositing the check in the United States, he may choose to open a dollar account with a bank in London. Dollars held in a bank outside the United States came to be known as eurodollars. Similarly, yen held outside Japan were termed euroyen, and so on). When the new European currency was named the euro, the term eurodollars became confusing. Doubtless in time bankers will dream up a new name for dollars held outside the United States; until they do, we’ll just call them international dollars. The London bank branch that is holding the sheikh’s dollar deposit may temporarily lend those dollars to a company, in the same way that a bank in the United States may relend dollars that have been deposited with it. Thus a company can either borrow dol- lars from a bank in the United States or borrow dollars from a bank in London.4 If a firm wants to make an issue of long-term bonds, it can choose to do so in the United States. Alternatively, it can sell the bonds to investors in several countries. These bonds have traditionally been known as eurobonds, but international bonds may be a less misleading term. The payments on these bonds may be fixed in dollars, euros, or any other major currency. Companies usually sell these bonds to the London branches of the major international banks, which then resell them to investors throughout the world. Public versus Private Placements. Publicly issued bonds are sold to anyone who wishes to buy and, once they have been issued, they can be freely traded in the securi- ties markets. In a private placement, the issue is sold directly to a small number of banks, insurance companies, or other investment institutions. Privately placed bonds cannot be resold to individuals in the United States but only to other qualified institu- tional investors. However, there is increasingly active trading among these investors. We will have more to say about the difference between public issues and private placements later. Protective Covenants. When investors lend to a company, they know that they might not get their money back. But they expect that the company will use their money well and not take unreasonable risks. To help ensure this, lenders usually impose a number of conditions, or protective covenants, on companies that borrow from them. An hon- est firm is willing to accept these conditions because it knows that they enable the firm to borrow at a reasonable rate of interest. Companies that borrow in moderation are less likely to get into difficulties than those that are up to the gunwales in debt. So lenders usually restrict the amount of extra debt that the firm can issue. Lenders are also eager to prevent others from pushing ahead of them in the queue if trouble occurs. So they will not allow the company to cre- ate new debt that is senior to them or to put aside assets for other lenders. 4 Because the Federal Reserve requires banks in the United States to keep interest-free reserves, there is in ef- fect a tax on dollar deposits in the United States. Overseas dollar deposits are free of this tax and therefore banks can afford to charge the borrower slightly lower interest rates. EURODOLLARS Dollars held on deposit in a bank outside the United States. EUROBOND Bond that is marketed internationally. PRIVATE PLACEMENT Sale of securities to a limited number of investors without a public offering. PROTECTIVE COVENANT Restriction on a firm to protect bondholders. 504 SECTION FIVE SEE BOX (cid:1) Self-Test 6 LEASE Long-term rental agreement. Another possible hazard for lenders is that the company will pay a bumper dividend
Brealey
to the shareholders, leaving no cash for the debtholders. Therefore, lenders sometimes limit the size of the dividends that can be paid. The story of Marriott in the nearby box shows what can happen when bondholders are not sufficiently careful about the conditions they impose. In the wake of the large losses suffered by Marriott bondholders, several observers predicted that investors would demand more restrictive bond covenants in future transactions. In 1988 RJR Nabisco, the food and tobacco giant, had $5 billion of A-rated debt out- standing. In that year the company was taken over, and $19 billion of debt was issued and used to buy back equity. The debt ratio skyrocketed, and the debt was downgraded to a BB rating. The holders of the previously issued debt were furious, and one filed a lawsuit claiming that RJR had violated an implicit obligation not to undertake major fi- nancing changes at the expense of existing bondholders. Why did these bondholders be- lieve they had been harmed by the massive issue of new debt? What type of explicit re- striction would you have wanted if you had been one of the original bondholders? A Debt by Any Other Name. The word debt sounds straightforward, but companies enter into a number of financial arrangements that look suspiciously like debt yet are treated differently in the accounts. Some of these obligations are easily identifiable. For example, accounts payable are simply obligations to pay for goods that have already been delivered and are therefore like a short-term debt. Other arrangements are not so easy to spot. For example, instead of borrowing money to buy equipment, many companies lease or rent it on a long-term basis. In this case the firm promises to make a series of payments to the lessor (the owner of the equipment). This is just like the obligation to make payments on an outstanding loan. What if the firm can’t make the payments? The lessor can then take back the equipment, which is precisely what would happen if the firm had borrowed money from the lessor, using the equipment as collateral for the loan. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 1 The Terms of Heinz’s Bond Issue Now that you are familiar with some of the jargon, you might like to look at an exam- ple of a bond issue. Table 5.9 is a summary of the terms of a bond issue by Heinz taken from Moody’s Industrial Manual. We have added some explanatory notes. INNOVATION IN THE DEBT MARKET We have discussed domestic bonds and eurobonds, fixed-rate and floating-rate loans, secured and unsecured loans, senior and junior loans, and much more. You might think that this gives you all the choice you need. Yet almost every day companies and their advisers dream up a new type of debt. Here are some examples of unusual bonds. Indexed Bonds. We saw in earlier how the United States government has issued bonds whose payments rise in line with inflation. Occasionally borrowers have linked the payments on their bonds to the price of a particular commodity. For example, Mex- An Overview of Corporate Financing 505 TABLE 5.9 Heinz’s bond issue Comment 1. A debenture is an unsecured bond. 2. Coupon is 6.375 percent. Thus each bond makes an annual interest payment of .06375 × $1,000 = $63.75. Description of Bond H. J. Heinz Company 6.375% debentures, due 2028 3. Moody’s bond rating is A, the third-highest quality Rating—A rating. 4. Heinz is authorized to issue (and has outstanding) $250 AUTH. $250,000,000: outstg. $250,000,000. million of the bonds. 5. The bond was issued in July 1998 and is to be repaid in DATED July 10, 1998. DUE July 15, 2028. July 2028. 6. Interest is payable at 6-month intervals on January and INTEREST J&J 15. July 15. 7. A trustee is appointed to look after the bondholders’ TRUSTEE First National Bank of Chicago. interest. 8. The bonds are registered. The registrar keeps a record of DENOMINATION Fully registered. $1,000 and integral who owns the bonds. 9. The bond can be held in multiples of $1,000. 10. Unlike some bond issues, the Heinz issue does not give
Brealey
the company an option to call (i.e., repurchase) the bonds before maturity at specified prices. Also Heinz does not set aside money each year in a sinking fund that is then used to redeem the bonds. 11. The bonds are not secured, that is, no assets have been set aside to protect the bondholders in the event of default. 12. However, if Heinz sets aside assets to protect any other bondholders, the debenture will also be secured on these assets.This is termed a negative pledge clause. 13. The bonds were sold at a price of 99.549 percent of face value. After deducting the payment to the underwriters the company received $986.74 per bond. The bonds could be bought from the listed underwriters. multiples thereof. Transferable and exchangable without service charge. EARLY REDEMPTION The debentures are not redeemable prior to maturity. SECURITY Not secured. Ranks equally with all other unsecured and unsubordinated indebtedness of the Company. Company or any affiliate will not create as security for any indebtedness for borrowed money, any mortgage, pledge, security interest, or lien on any stock or any indebtedness of any affiliate . . . without effectively providing that the debentures shall be secured equally and ratably with such indebtedness, unless such secured debt would not exceed 10% of Consolidated Net Assets. OFFERED $250,000,000 at 99.549 plus accrued interest (proceeds to Company 98.674) thru Goldman, Sachs & Co., J. P. Morgan & Co., Warburg Dillon Read LLC. ico, which is a large oil producer, has issued billions of dollars worth of bonds that pro- vide an extra payoff if oil prices rise. Mexico reasons that oil-linked bonds reduce its risk. If the price of oil is high, it can afford the higher payments on the bond. If oil prices are low, its interest payments will also be lower. The Swiss insurance company Win- terthur has also issued an unusual bond with varying interest payments. The payments on the bonds are reduced if there is a hailstorm in Switzerland which damages at least 6,000 cars that have been insured by Winterthur.5 The bondholders receive a higher in- terest rate but take on some of the company’s risk. 5 The Winterthur bond is an example of a catastrophe (or CAT) bond. Its payments are linked to the occur- rence of a natural catastrophe. CAT bonds are discussed in M. S. Cantor, J. B. Cole, and R. L. Sandor, “In- surance Derivatives: A New Asset Class for the Capital Markets and a New Hedging Tool for the Insurance Industry,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 10 (Fall 1997), pp. 69–83. FINANCE IN ACTION Marriott Plan Enrages Holders of Its Bonds Marriott Corp. has infuriated bond investors with a re- structuring plan that may be a new way for companies to pull the rug out from under bondholders. Prices of Marriott’s existing bonds have plunged as much as 30% in the past two days in the wake of the hotel and food-services company’s announcement that it plans to separate into two companies, one burdened with virtually all of Marriott’s debt. On Monday, Marriott said that it will divide its opera- tions into two separate businesses. One, Marriott Inter- national Inc., is a healthy company that will manage Marriott’s vast hotel chain; it will get most of the old company’s revenue, a larger share of the cash flow and will be nearly debt-free. The second business, called Host Marriott Corp., is a debt-laden company that will own Marriott hotels along with other real estate and retain essentially all of the old Marriott’s $3 billion of debt. The announcement stunned and infuriated bond- holders, who watched nervously as the value of their Marriott bonds tumbled and as Moody’s Investors Ser- vice Inc. downgraded the bond to the junk-bond cate- gory from investment-grade. Price Plunge In trading, Marriott’s 10% bonds that mature in 2012, which Marriott sold to investors just six months ago, were quoted yesterday at about 80 cents on the dollar, down from 110 Friday. The price decline translates into a stunning loss of $300 for a bond with a $1,000 face amount.
Brealey
Marriott officials concede that the company’s spinoff plan penalizes bondholders. However, the company notes that, like all public corporations, its fiduciary duty is to stockholders, not bondholders. Indeed, Marriott’s stock jumped 12% Monday. (It fell a bit yesterday.) Bond investors and analysts worry that if the Marriott spinoff goes through, other companies will soon follow suit by separating debt-laden units from the rest of the company. “ Any company that fears it has underper- forming divisions that are dragging down its stock price is a possible candidate” for such a restructuring, says Dorothy K. Lee, an assistant vice president at Moody’s. If the trend heats up, investors said, the Marriott re- structuring could be the worst news for corporate Inc.’s managers bondholders since RJR Nabisco shocked investors in 1987 by announcing they were taking the company private in a record $25 billion lever- aged buy-out. The move, which loaded RJR with debt and tanked the value of RJR bonds, triggered a deep slump in prices of many investment-grade corporate bonds as investors backed away from the market. Strong Covenants May Re-Emerge Some analysts say the move by Marriott may trigger the re-emergence of strong covenants, or written protec- tions, in future corporate bond issues to protect bond- holders against such restructurings as the one being engineered by Marriott. In the wake of the RJR buy-out, many investors demanded stronger covenants in new corporate bond issues. Some investors blame themselves for not demand- ing stronger covenants. “ It’s our own fault,” said Robert Hickey, a bond fund manager at Van Kampen Merritt. In their rush to buy bonds in an effort to lock in yields, many investors have allowed companies to sell bonds with covenants that have been “ slim to none,” Mr. Hickey said. Source: Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal, © 1992 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide. Asset-Backed Bonds. The rock star David Bowie earns royalties from a number of successful albums such as The Rise and Fall of Ziggy Stardust and Diamond Dogs. But instead of waiting to receive these royalties, Bowie decided that he would prefer the money upfront. The solution was to issue $55 million of 10-year bonds and to set aside the future royalty payments from the singer’s albums to make the payments on these bonds. Such bonds are known as asset-backed securities; the borrower sets aside a group of assets and the income from these assets is then used to service the debt. The Bowie bonds are an unusual example of an asset-backed security, but billions of dollars 506 An Overview of Corporate Financing 507 of house mortgages and credit card loans are packaged each year and resold as asset- backed bonds. Reverse floaters. Floating-rate bonds that pay a higher rate of interest when other in- terest rates fall and a lower rate when other rates rise are called reverse floaters. They are riskier than normal bonds. When interest rates rise, the prices of all bonds fall, but the prices of reverse floaters suffer a double whammy because the coupon payments on the bonds fall as the discount rate rises. In 1994 Orange County, California, learned this the hard way, when it invested heavily in reverse floaters. Robert Citron, the treasurer, was betting that interest rates would fall. He was wrong; interest rates rose sharply and partly as a result of its investment in reverse floaters, the county lost $1.7 billion. These three examples illustrate the great variety of potential security designs. As long as you can convince investors of its attractions, you can issue a callable, subordi- nated, floating-rate bond denominated in euros. Rather than combining features of ex- isting securities, you may be able to create an entirely new one. We can imagine a cop- per mining company issuing preferred shares on which the dividend fluctuates with the world copper price. We know of no such security, but it is perfectly legal to issue it
Brealey
and—who knows?—it might generate considerable interest among investors. Variety is intrinsically good. People have different tastes, levels of wealth, rates of tax, and so on. Why not offer them a choice? Of course the problem is the expense of designing and marketing new securities. But if you can think of a new security that will appeal to investors, you may be able to issue it on especially favorable terms and thus increase the value of your company. Convertible Securities WARRANT Right to buy shares from a company at a stipulated price before a set date. We have seen that companies sometimes have the option to repay an issue of bonds be- fore maturity. There are also cases in which investors have an option. The most dramatic case is provided by a warrant, which is nothing but an option. Companies often issue warrants and bonds in a package. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 2 Warrants Macaw Bill wishes to make a bond issue, which could include some warrants as a “sweetener.” Each warrant might allow you to purchase one share of Macaw stock at a price of $50 any time during the next 5 years. If Macaw’s stock performs well, that op- tion could turn out to be very valuable. For instance, if the stock price at the end of the 5 years is $80, then you pay the company $50 and receive in exchange a share worth $80. Of course, an investment in warrants also has its perils. If the price of Macaw stock fails to rise above $50, then the warrants expire worthless. CONVERTIBLE BOND Bond that the holder may exchange for a specified amount of another security. A convertible bond gives its owner the option to exchange the bond for a predeter- mined number of common shares. The convertible bondholder hopes that the company’s share price will zoom up so that the bond can be converted at a big profit. But if the shares zoom down, there is no obligation to convert; the bondholder remains just that. Not surprisingly, investors value this option to keep the bond or exchange it for shares, 508 SECTION FIVE INTERNALLY GENERATED FUNDS Cash reinvested in the firm: depreciation plus earnings not paid out as dividends. and therefore a convertible bond sells at a higher price than a comparable bond that is not convertible. The convertible is rather like a package of a bond and a warrant. But there is an im- portant difference: when the owners of a convertible wish to exercise their options to buy shares, they do not pay cash—they just exchange the bond for shares of the stock. Companies may also issue convertible preferred stock. In this case the investor re- ceives preferred stock with fixed dividend payments but has the option to exchange this preferred stock for the company’s common stock. The preferred stock issued by Heinz is convertible into common stock. These examples do not exhaust the options encountered by the financial manager. Patterns of Corporate Financing We have now completed our tour of corporate securities. You may feel like the tourist who has just gone through 12 cathedrals in 5 days. But there will be plenty of time in later material for reflection and analysis. For now, let’s look at how firms use these sources of finance. Firms have two broad sources of cash. They can raise money from external sources by an issue of debt or equity. Or they can plow back part of their profits. When the firm retains cash rather than paying the money out as dividends, it is increasing shareholders’ investment in the firm. Figure 5.4 summarizes the sources of capital for United States corporations. The most striking aspect of this figure is the dominance of internally generated funds, de- fined as depreciation plus earnings that are not paid out as dividends.6 During the 1980s internally generated cash covered approximately three-quarters of firms’ capital re- quirements. DO FIRMS RELY TOO HEAVILY ON INTERNAL FUNDS? Gordon Donaldson, in a survey of corporate debt policies, encountered several firms which acknowledged “that it was their long-term object to hold to a rate of growth
Brealey
which was consistent with their capacity to generate funds internally.” A number of other firms appeared to think less hard about expenditure proposals that could be fi- nanced internally.7 At first glance, this behavior doesn’t make sense. As we have already noted, retained profits are additional capital invested by shareholders and represent, in effect, a com- pulsory issue of shares. A firm that retains $1 million could have paid out the cash as dividends and then sold new common shares to raise the same amount of additional capital. The opportunity cost of capital ought not to depend on whether the project is fi- nanced by retained profits or a new stock issue. 6 Remember that depreciation is a noncash expense. 7 See G. Donaldson, Corporate Debt Capacity, Division of Research, Graduate School of Business Adminis- tration, Harvard University, Boston, 1961, Chapter 3, especially pp. 51–56. FIGURE 5.4 Sources of funds, nonfinancial corporate sector. ) s r a l l o d f o s n o i l l i b ( s d n u f f o e c r u o S 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 (cid:2)100 (cid:2)200 (cid:2)300 An Overview of Corporate Financing 509 Internal funds Net equity issues Debt instruments 0 8 9 1 1 8 9 1 2 8 9 1 3 8 9 1 4 8 9 1 5 8 9 1 6 8 9 1 7 8 9 1 8 8 9 1 9 8 9 1 0 9 9 1 1 9 9 1 2 9 9 1 3 9 9 1 4 9 9 1 5 9 9 1 6 9 9 1 7 9 9 1 8 9 9 1 9 9 9 1 Year Source: Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1999. Values for 1999 are for first two quarters, expressed at annual rates. Why then do managers have an apparent preference for financing by retained earn- ings? Perhaps managers are simply taking the line of least resistance, dodging the dis- cipline of the securities markets. Think back, where we pointed out that a firm is a team, consisting of managers, shareholders, debtholders, and so on. The shareholders and debtholders would like to monitor management to make sure that it is pulling its weight and truly maximizing market value. It is costly for individual investors to keep checks on management. How- ever, large financial institutions are specialists in monitoring, so when the firm goes to the bank for a large loan or makes a public issue of stocks or bonds, managers know that they had better have all the answers. If they want a quiet life, they will avoid going to the capital market to raise money and they will retain sufficient earnings to be able to meet unanticipated demands for cash. We do not mean to paint managers as loafers. There are also rational reasons for re- lying on internally generated funds. The costs of new securities are avoided, for exam- ple. Moreover, the announcement of a new equity issue is usually bad news for in- vestors, who worry that the decision signals lower profits.8 Raising equity capital from internal sources avoids the costs and the bad omens associated with equity issues. (cid:1) Self-Test 7 “Since internal funds provide the bulk of industry’s needs for capital, the securities mar- kets serve little function.” Does the speaker have a point? 8 Managers do have insiders’ insights and naturally are tempted to issue stock when the stock price looks good to them, that is, when they are less optimistic than outside investors. The outside investors realize all this and will buy a new issue only at a discount from the preannouncement price. 510 SECTION FIVE EXTERNAL SOURCES OF CAPITAL Of course firms don’t rely exclusively on internal funds. They also issue securities and retire them, sometimes in big volume. For example, in the early 1990s Heinz dramati- cally increased its reliance on new debt by issuing considerable amounts of bonds. Be- tween 1991 and 1993, its outstanding long-term debt more than doubled. After 1994, however, Heinz reduced its reliance on new debt financing, and its level of outstanding long-term debt stabilized. Despite this, the ratio of debt to the book value of equity con- tinued to rise. The ratio continued to rise because Heinz was buying back shares from the public. So over this period, Heinz had negative net stock issues. Figure 5.5 shows the ratio of the book value of Heinz’s long-term debt to both the
Brealey
book value and market value of its equity. The ratio based on book values rose through- out the 1990s. However, the ratio of debt to the market value of equity was far more sta- ble. This reflects the great rise in stock market values in the 1990s, which allowed the market value of Heinz’s equity to keep up with its issues of long-term debt. If you look back at Figure 5.4, you will see that Heinz was not alone in its use of share repurchases in the latter part of the 1990s. The figure shows that for most of this period corporate America was making large issues of debt and using part of the money to buy back common stock. Despite this policy, debt-to-equity ratios did not rise. The high profit levels during this period resulted in record-setting levels of internally gen- erated funds. As a result, despite the share repurchases, common equity rose in line with long-term debt. The net effect of these financing policies is shown in Figure 5.6, which confirms that debt-to-equity ratios for United States firms in the 1990s were relatively stable in book- value terms but declined considerably in market-value terms. Again, this reflects the run-up of stock prices during this period. United States corporations are carrying more debt than they did 30 years ago. Should we be worried? It is true that higher debt ratios mean that more companies are likely to fall into financial distress when a serious recession hits the economy. But all companies live with this risk to some degree, and it does not follow that less risk is better. Finding the optimal debt ratio is like finding the optimal speed limit: we can agree that accidents at 30 miles per hour are less dangerous, other things being equal, FIGURE 5.5 Debt-to-equity ratios for H. J. Heinz Company. D/E book D/E market o i t a r y t i u q e - o t - t b e D 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 1980 1985 1990 Year 1995 2000 An Overview of Corporate Financing 511 FIGURE 5.6 Debt-to-equity ratio, nonfinancial corporate sector. o i t a r y t i u q e - o t - t b e D 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 D/E book D/E market 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 Year than accidents at 60 miles per hour, but we do not therefore set the national speed limit at 30. Speed has benefits as well as risks. So does debt. Summary What are the major classes of securities issued by firms to raise capital? Companies may raise money from shareholders by issuing more shares. They also raise money indirectly by plowing back cash that could otherwise have been paid out as dividends. Preferred stock offers a fixed dividend but the company has the discretion not to pay it. It can’t, however, then pay a dividend on the common stock. Despite its name, preferred stock is not a popular source of finance, but it is useful in special situations. When companies issue debt, they promise to make a series of interest payments and to repay the principal. However, this liability is limited. Stockholders have the right to default on their obligation and to hand over the assets to the debtholders. Unlike dividends on common stock and preferred stock, the interest payments on debt are regarded as a cost and therefore they are paid out of before-tax income. Here are some forms of debt: • Fixed-rate and floating-rate debt • Funded (long-term) and unfunded (short-term) debt • Callable and sinking-fund debt • Senior and subordinated debt • Secured and unsecured debt • Investment grade and junk debt • Domestic and international debt • Publicly traded debt and private placements The fourth source of finance consists of options and optionlike securities. The simplest option is a warrant, which gives its holder the right to buy a share from the firm at a set price by a set date. Warrants are often sold in combination with other securities. 512 SECTION FIVE Convertible bonds give their holder the right to convert the bond to shares. They therefore resemble a package of straight debt and a warrant. What are recent trends in firms’ use of different sources of finance? Internally generated cash is the principal source of company funds. Some people worry
Brealey
about that; they think that if management does not go to the trouble of raising money, it may be profligate in spending it. In the late 1990s, net equity issues were negative; that is, companies repurchased more equity than they issued. At the same time companies issued large quantities of debt. However, large levels of internally generated funds in this period allowed book equity to increase despite the share repurchases, with the result that the ratio of long-term debt to book value of equity was fairly stable. Moreover, the stock market boom of the 1990s meant that the ratio of debt to the market value of equity actually fell considerably during this period. Related Web Links www.AshtonAnalytics.com/ Information about the debt markets www.finpipe.com/ See “Types of Debt” for descriptions of many debt instruments www.fcnbd.com/corporate/capital/mezzanine/index.html A menu of choices for corporations Key Terms issuing different kinds of debt www.corpfinet.com/ The corporate finance network www.hoovers.com/ Information about corporations and corporate financing treasury stock issued shares outstanding shares authorized share capital par value additional paid-in capital retained earnings majority voting cumulative voting proxy contest preferred stock net worth floating-rate preferred prime rate funded debt sinking fund callable bond subordinated debt secured debt eurodollars eurobond private placement protective covenant lease warrant convertible bond internally generated funds Quiz 1. Equity Accounts. The authorized share capital of the Alfred Cake Company is 100,000 shares. The equity is currently shown in the company’s books as follows: Common stock ($1.00 par value) Additional paid-in capital Retained earnings Common equity Treasury stock (2,000 shares) Net common equity $ 60,000 10,000 30,000 100,000 5,000 95,000 a. How many shares are issued? b. How many are outstanding? c. How many more shares can be issued without the approval of shareholders? An Overview of Corporate Financing 513 2. Equity Accounts. a. Look back at problem 1. Suppose that the company issues 10,000 shares at $5 a share. Which of the above figures would change? b. What would happen to the company’s books if instead it bought back 1,000 shares at $5 per share? 3. Financing Terms. Fill in the blanks by choosing the appropriate term from the following list: lease, funded, floating-rate, eurobond, convertible, subordinated, call, sinking fund, prime rate, private placement, public issue, senior, unfunded, eurodollar rate, warrant, debentures, term loan. a. Debt maturing in more than 1 year is often called _________ debt. b. An issue of bonds that is sold simultaneously in several countries is traditionally called a(n) _________. c. If a lender ranks behind the firm’s general creditors in the event of default, the loan is said to be _________. d. In many cases a firm is obliged to make regular contributions to a(n) _________, which is then used to repurchase bonds. e. Most bonds give the firm the right to repurchase or _________ the bonds at specified prices. f. The benchmark interest rate that banks charge to their customers with good to excellent credit is generally termed the _________. g. The interest rate on bank loans is often tied to short-term interest rates. These loans are usually called _________ loans. h. Where there is a(n) _________, securities are sold directly to a small group of institu- tional investors. These securities cannot be resold to individual investors. In the case of a(n) _________, debt can be freely bought and sold by individual investors. i. A long-term rental agreement is called a(n) _________. j. A(n) _________ bond can be exchanged for shares of the issuing corporation. k. A(n) _________ gives its owner the right to buy shares in the issuing company at a pre- determined price. 4. Financing Trends. True or false? Explain. a. In several recent years, nonfinancial corporations in the United States have repurchased more stock than they have issued. b. A corporation pays tax on only 30 percent of the common or preferred dividends it re-
Brealey
ceives from other corporations. c. Because of the tax advantage, a large fraction of preferred shares is held by corporations. 5. Preferred Stock. In what ways is preferred stock like long-term debt? In what ways is it like common stock? Practice Problems 6. Voting for Directors. If there are 10 directors to be elected and a shareholder owns 90 shares, indicate the maximum number of votes that he or she can cast for a favorite candi- date under a. majority voting b. cumulative voting 514 SECTION FIVE Solutions to Self-Test Questions 7. Voting for Directors. The shareholders of the Pickwick Paper Company need to elect five directors. There are 400,000 shares outstanding. How many shares do you need to own to ensure that you can elect at least one director if the company has a. majority voting b. cumulative voting Hint: How many votes in total will be cast? How many votes are required to ensure that at least one-fifth of votes are cast for your choice? 8. Equity Accounts. Look back at Table 5.8. a. Suppose that Heinz issues 10 million shares at $55 a share. Rework Table 5.8 to show the company’s equity after the issue. b. Suppose that Heinz subsequently repurchased 500,000 shares at $60 a share. Rework part (a) to show the effect of the further change. 9. Equity Accounts. Common Products has just made its first issue of stock. It raised $2 mil- lion by selling 200,000 shares of stock to the public. These are the only shares outstanding. The par value of each share was $1.50. Fill in the following table: Common shares (par value) Additional paid-in capital Retained earnings Net common equity ________ ________ ________ $2,500,000 10. Protective Covenants. Why might a bond agreement limit the amount of assets that the firm can lease? 11. Bond Yields. Other things equal, will the following provisions increase or decrease the yield to maturity at which a firm can issue a bond? a. A call provision b. A restriction on further borrowing c. A provision of specific collateral for the bond d. An option to convert the bonds into shares 12. Income Bonds. Income bonds are unusual. Interest payments on such bonds may be skipped or deferred if the firm’s income is insufficient to make the payment. In what way are these bonds like preferred stock? Why might a firm choose to issue an income bond instead of preferred stock? 13. Preferred Stock. Preferred stock of financially strong firms sometimes sells at lower yields than the bonds of those firms. For weaker firms, the preferred stock has a higher yield. What might explain this pattern? 1 Par value of common shares must be $1 × 100,000 shares = $100,000. Additional paid-in capital is ($15 – $1) × 100,000 = $1,400,000. Since book value is $4,500,000, retained earnings must be $3,000,000. Therefore, the accounts look like this: Common shares ($1.00 par value per share) Additional paid-in capital Retained earnings Net common equity 100,000 1,400,000 3,000,000 $4,500,000 An Overview of Corporate Financing 515 2 Book value is $10 million. At a discount rate of 10 percent, the market value of the firm ought to be $2 million × 20-year annuity factor at 10% = $17 million, which exceeds book value. At a discount rate of 20 percent, market value falls to $9.7 million, which is below book value. 3 The corporation’s after-tax yield on the bonds is 10% – (.35 × 10%) = 6.5%. The after-tax yield on the preferred is 8% – [.35 × (.30 × 8%)] = 7.16%. The preferred stock provides the higher after-tax rate despite its lower before-tax rate. For the individual, the tax rate on both the preferred and the bond is equal to 35 percent, so the investment with the higher before- tax rate also provides the higher after-tax rate. 4 Because the coupon on floating-rate debt adjusts periodically to current market conditions, the bondholder is less vulnerable to changes in market yields. The coupon rate paid by the bond is not locked in for as long a period of time. Therefore, prices of floaters should be less sensitive to changes in market interest rates. 5 The callable bond will sell at a lower price. Investors will not pay as much for the callable
Brealey
bond since they know that the firm may call it away from them if interest rates fall. Thus they know that their capital gains potential is limited, which makes the bond less valuable. If both bonds are to sell at par value, the callable bond must pay a higher coupon rate as compensation to the investor for the firm’s right to call the bond. 6 The extra debt makes it more likely that the firm will not be able to make good on its prom- ised payments to its creditors. If the new debt is not junior to the already-issued debt, then the original bondholders suffer a loss when their bonds become more susceptible to default risk. A protective covenant limiting the amount of new debt that the firm can issue would have prevented this problem. Investors, having witnessed the problems of the RJR bond- holders, generally demanded the covenant on future debt issues. 7 Capital markets provide liquidity for investors. Because individual stockholders can always lay their hands on cash by selling shares, they are prepared to invest in companies that re- tain earnings rather than pay them out as dividends. Well-functioning capital markets allow the firm to serve all its stockholders simply by maximizing value. Capital markets also pro- vide managers with information. Without this information, it would be very difficult to de- termine opportunity costs of capital or to assess financial performance. HOW CORPORATIONS ISSUE SECURITIES Venture Capital The Initial Public Offering Arranging a Public Issue The Underwriters Who Are the Underwriters? General Cash Offers by Public Companies General Cash Offers and Shelf Registration Costs of the General Cash Offer Market Reaction to Stock Issues The Private Placement Summary Appendix: Hotch Pot’s New Issue Prospectus Planet Hollywood shares are offered to investors. IPOs often provide stellar first-day returns, but their long-term performance tends to be weak. Reuters/Ethan Miller/Archive Photos 517 B ill Gates and Paul Allen founded Microsoft in 1975, when both were around 20 years old. Eleven years later Microsoft shares were sold to the public for $21 a share and immediately zoomed to $35. The largest shareholder was Bill Gates, whose shares in Microsoft then were worth $350 million. In 1976 two college dropouts, Steve Jobs and Steve Wozniak, sold their most valu- able possessions, a van and a couple of calculators, and used the cash to start manufac- turing computers in a garage. In 1980, when Apple Computer went public, the shares were offered to investors at $22 and jumped to $36. At that point, the shares owned by the company’s two founders were worth $414 million. In 1994 Marc Andreesen, a 24-year-old from the University of Illinois, joined with an investor, James Clark, to found Netscape Communications. Just over a year later Netscape stock was offered to the public at $28 a share and immediately leapt to $71. At this price James Clark’s shares were worth $566 million, while Marc Andreesen’s shares were worth $245 million. Such stories illustrate that the most important asset of a new firm may be a good idea. But that is not all you need. To take an idea from the drawing board to a prototype and through to large-scale production requires ever greater amounts of capital. To get a new company off the ground, entrepreneurs may rely on their own savings and personal bank loans. But this is unlikely to be sufficient to build a successful en- terprise. Venture capital firms specialize in providing new equity capital to help firms over the awkward adolescent period before they are large enough to “go public.” In the first part of this material we will explain how venture capital firms do this. If the firm continues to be successful, there is likely to come a time when it needs to tap a wider source of capital. At this point it will make its first public issue of common stock. This is known as an initial public offering, or IPO. In the second section of the material we will describe what is involved in an IPO. A company’s initial public offering is seldom its last. Earlier we saw that internally
Brealey
generated cash is not usually sufficient to satisfy the firm’s needs. Established compa- nies make up the deficit by issuing more equity or debt. The remainder of this material looks at this process. After studying this material you should be able to (cid:1) Understand how venture capital firms design successful deals. (cid:1) Understand how firms make initial public offerings and the costs of such offerings. (cid:1) Know what is involved when established firms make a general cash offer or a pri- vate placement of securities. (cid:1) Explain the role of the underwriter in an issue of securities. 518 VENTURE CAPITAL Money invested to finance a new firm. How Corporations Issue Securities 519 Venture Capital You have taken a big step. With a couple of friends, you have formed a corporation to open a number of fast-food outlets, offering innovative combinations of national dishes such as sushi with sauerkraut, curry Bolognese, and chow mein with Yorkshire pudding. Breaking into the fast-food business costs money, but, after pooling your savings and borrowing to the hilt from the bank, you have raised $100,000 and purchased 1 million shares in the new company. At this zero-stage investment, your company’s assets are $100,000 plus the idea for your new product. That $100,000 is enough to get the business off the ground, but if the idea takes off, you will need more capital to pay for new restaurants. You therefore decide to look for an investor who is prepared to back an untried company in return for part of the prof- its. Equity capital in young businesses is known as venture capital and it is provided by specialist venture capital firms, wealthy individuals, and investment institutions such as pension funds. Most entrepreneurs are able to spin a plausible yarn about their company. But it is as hard to convince a venture capitalist to invest in your business as it is to get a first novel published. Your first step is to prepare a business plan. This describes your product, the potential market, the production method, and the resources—time, money, employees, plant, and equipment—needed for success. It helps if you can point to the fact that you are prepared to put your money where your mouth is. By staking all your savings in the company, you signal your faith in the business. The venture capital company knows that the success of a new business depends on the effort its managers put in. Therefore, it will try to structure any deal so that you have a strong incentive to work hard. For example, if you agree to accept a modest salary (and look forward instead to increasing the value of your investment in the company’s stock), the venture capital company knows you will be committed to working hard. However, if you insist on a watertight employment contract and a fat salary, you won’t find it easy to raise venture capital. You are unlikely to persuade a venture capitalist to give you as much money as you need all at once. Rather, the firm will probably give you enough to reach the next major checkpoint. Suppose you can convince the venture capital company to buy 1 million new shares for $.50 each. This will give it one-half ownership of the firm: it owns 1 mil- lion shares and you and your friends also own 1 million shares. Because the venture capitalist is paying $500,000 for a claim to half your firm, it is placing a $1 million value on the business. After this first-stage financing, your company’s balance sheet looks like this: FIRST-STAGE MARKET-VALUE BALANCE SHEET (figures in millions) Assets Cash from new equity Other assets Value $ .5 .5 $1.0 Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity New equity from venture capital Your original equity Value $ .5 .5 $1.0 (cid:1) Self-Test 1 Why might the venture capital company prefer to put up only part of the funds up- front? Would this affect the amount of effort put in by you, the entrepreneur? Is your 520 SECTION FIVE willingness to accept only part of the venture capital that will eventually be needed a good signal of the likely success of the venture?
Brealey
Suppose that 2 years later your business has grown to the point at which it needs a further injection of equity. This second-stage financing might involve the issue of a fur- ther 1 million shares at $1 each. Some of these shares might be bought by the original backers and some by other venture capital firms. The balance sheet after the new fi- nancing would then be as follows: SECOND-STAGE MARKET-VALUE BALANCE SHEET (figures in millions) Assets Cash from new equity Other assets Value Liabilities and Shareholders’ Equity $1.0 2.0 $3.0 New equity from second-stage financing Equity from first stage Your original equity Value $1.0 1.0 1.0 $3.0 Notice that the value of the initial 1 million shares owned by you and your friends has now been marked up to $1 million. Does this begin to sound like a money machine? It was so only because you have made a success of the business and new investors are prepared to pay $1 to buy a share in the business. When you started out, it wasn’t clear that sushi and sauerkraut would catch on. If it hadn’t caught on, the venture capital firm could have refused to put up more funds. You are not yet in a position to cash in on your investment, but your gain is real. The second-stage investors have paid $1 million for a one-third share in the company. (There are now 3 million shares outstanding, and the second-stage investors hold 1 million shares.) Therefore, at least these impartial observers—who are willing to back up their opinions with a large investment—must have decided that the company was worth at least $3 million. Your one-third share is therefore also worth $1 million. For every 10 first-stage venture capital investments, only two or three may survive as successful, self-sufficient businesses, and only one may pay off big. From these sta- tistics come two rules of success in venture capital investment. First, don’t shy away from uncertainty; accept a low probability of success. But don’t buy into a business un- less you can see the chance of a big, public company in a profitable market. There’s no sense taking a big risk unless the reward is big if you win. Second, cut your losses; iden- tify losers early, and, if you can’t fix the problem—by replacing management, for ex- ample—don’t throw good money after bad. The same advice holds for any backer of a risky startup business—after all, only a fraction of new businesses are funded by card-carrying venture capitalists. Some start- ups are funded directly by managers or by their friends and families. Some grow using bank loans and reinvested earnings. But if your startup combines high risk, sophisti- cated technology, and substantial investment, you will probably try to find venture- capital financing. The Initial Public Offering Very few new businesses make it big, but those that do can be very profitable. For ex- ample, an investor who provided $1,000 of first-stage financing for Intel would by mid- 2000 have reaped $43 million. So venture capitalists keep sane by reminding them- INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERING (IPO) offering of stock to the general public. First How Corporations Issue Securities 521 selves of the success stories1—those who got in on the ground floor of firms like Intel and Federal Express and Lotus Development Corporation.2 If a startup is successful, the firm may need to raise a considerable amount of capital to gear up its production ca- pacity. At this point, it needs more capital than can comfortably be provided by a small number of individuals or venture capitalists. The firm decides to sell shares to the pub- lic to raise the necessary funds. A firm is said to go public when it sells its first issue of shares in a general offering to investors. This first sale of stock is called an initial public offering, or IPO. An IPO is called a primary offering when new shares are sold to raise additional cash for the company. It is a secondary offering when the company’s founders and the ven- ture capitalist cash in on some of their gains by selling shares. A secondary offer there-
Brealey
fore is no more than a sale of shares from the early investors in the firm to new in- vestors, and the cash raised in a secondary offer does not flow to the company. Of course, IPOs can be and commonly are both primary and secondary: the firm raises new cash at the same time that some of the already-existing shares in the firm are sold to the public. Some of the biggest secondary offerings have involved governments selling off stock in nationalized enterprises. For example, the Japanese government raised $12.6 billion by selling its stock in Nippon Telegraph and Telephone and the British govern- ment took in $9 billion from its sale of British Gas. The world’s largest IPO took place in 1999 when the Italian government raised $19.3 billion from the sale of shares in the state-owned electricity company, Enel. ARRANGING A PUBLIC ISSUE Once a firm decides to go public, the first task is to select the underwriters. UNDERWRITER Firm that buys an issue of securities from a company and resells it to the public. Underwriters are investment banking firms that act as financial midwives to a new issue. Usually they play a triple role—first providing the company with procedural and financial advice, then buying the stock, and finally reselling it to the public. SPREAD Difference between public offer price and price paid by underwriter. A small IPO may have only one underwriter, but larger issues usually require a syn- dicate of underwriters who buy the issue and resell it. For example, the initial public of- fering by Microsoft involved a total of 114 underwriters. In the typical underwriting arrangement, called a firm commitment, the underwriters buy the securities from the firm and then resell them to the public. The underwriters re- ceive payment in the form of a spread—that is, they are allowed to sell the shares at a slightly higher price than they paid for them. But the underwriters also accept the risk that they won’t be able to sell the stock at the agreed offering price. If that happens, they will be stuck with unsold shares and must get the best price they can for them. In the more risky cases, the underwriter may not be willing to enter into a firm commitment and handles the issue on a best efforts basis. In this case the underwriter agrees to sell as much of the issue as possible but does not guarantee the sale of the entire issue. 522 SECTION FIVE PROSPECTUS Formal summary that provides information on an issue of securities. UNDERPRICING Issuing securities at an offering price set below the true value of the security. Before any stock can be sold to the public, the company must register the stock with the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). This involves preparation of a detailed and sometimes cumbersome registration statement, which contains information about the proposed financing and the firm’s history, existing business, and plans for the fu- ture. The SEC does not evaluate the wisdom of an investment in the firm but it does check the registration statement for accuracy and completeness. The firm must also comply with the “blue-sky” laws of each state, so named because they seek to protect the public against firms that fraudulently promise the blue sky to investors.3 The first part of the registration statement is distributed to the public in the form of a preliminary prospectus. One function of the prospectus is to warn investors about the risks involved in any investment in the firm. Some investors have joked that if they read prospectuses carefully, they would never dare buy any new issue. The appendix to this material is a possible prospectus for your fast-food business. The company and its underwriters also need to set the issue price. To gauge how much the stock is worth, they may undertake discounted cash-flow calculations like those described earlier. They also look at the price-earnings ratios of the shares of the firm’s principal competitors. Before settling on the issue price, the underwriters may arrange a “roadshow,” which
Brealey
gives the underwriters and the company’s management an opportunity to talk to poten- tial investors. These investors may then offer their reaction to the issue, suggest what they think is a fair price, and indicate how much stock they would be prepared to buy. This allows the underwriters to build up a book of likely orders. Although investors are not bound by their indications, they know that if they want to remain in the underwrit- ers’ good books, they must be careful not to renege on their expressions of interest. The managers of the firm are eager to secure the highest possible price for their stock, but the underwriters are likely to be cautious because they will be left with any unsold stock if they overestimate investor demand. As a result, underwriters typically try to underprice the initial public offering. Underpricing, they argue, is needed to tempt investors to buy stock and to reduce the cost of marketing the issue to customers. Underpricing represents a cost to the existing owners since the new investors are allowed to buy shares in the firm at a favorable price. The cost of underpricing may be very large. It is common to see the stock price increase substantially from the issue price in the days following an issue. Such immediate price jumps indicate the amount by which the shares were underpriced compared to what investors were willing to pay for them. A study by Ibbotson, Sindelar, and Ritter of approximately 9,000 new issues from 1960 to 1987 found average underpricing of 16 percent.4 Sometimes new issues are dramati- cally underpriced. In November 1998, for example, 3.1 million shares in theglobe.com 3 Sometimes states go beyond blue-sky laws in their efforts to protect their residents. In 1980 when Apple Computer Inc. made its first public issue, the Massachusetts state government decided the offering was too risky for its residents and therefore banned the sale of the shares to investors in the state. The state relented later, after the issue was out and the price had risen. Massachusetts investors obviously did not appreciate this “protection.” 4 R. G. Ibbotson, J. L. Sindelar, and J. R. Ritter, “Initial Public Offerings,” Journal of Applied Corporate Fi- nance 1 (Summer 1988), pp. 37–45. Note, however, that initial underpricing does not mean that IPOs are su- perior long-run investments. In fact, IPO returns over the first 3 years of trading have been less than a con- trol sample of matching firms. See J. R. Ritter, “The Long-Run Performance of Initial Public Offerings,” Journal of Finance 46 (March 1991), pp. 3–27. Project Analysis 523 SEE BOX were sold in an IPO at a price of $9 a share. In the first day of trading 15.6 million shares changed hands and the price at one point touched $97. Unfortunately, the bo- nanza did not last. Within a year the stock price had fallen by over two-thirds from its first-day peak. The nearby box reports on the phenomenal performance of Internet IPOs in the late 1990s. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 1 Underpricing of IPOs Suppose an IPO is a secondary issue, and the firm’s founders sell part of their holding to investors. Clearly, if the shares are sold for less than their true worth, the founders will suffer an opportunity loss. But what if the IPO is a primary issue that raises new cash for the company? Do the founders care whether the shares are sold for less than their market value? The follow- ing example illustrates that they do care. Suppose Cosmos.com has 2 million shares outstanding and now offers a further 1 million shares to investors at $50. On the first day of trading the share price jumps to $80, so that the shares that the company sold for $50 million are now worth $80 mil- lion. The total market capitalization of the company is 3 million × $80 = $240 million. The value of the founders’ shares is equal to the total value of the company less the value of the shares that have been sold to the public—in other words, $240 – $80 = $160 million. The founders might justifiably rejoice at their good fortune. However, if the
Brealey
company had issued shares at a higher price, it would have needed to sell fewer shares to raise the $50 million that it needs, and the founders would have retained a larger share of the company. For example, suppose that the outside investors, who put up $50 million, received shares that were worth only $50 million. In that case the value of the founders’ shares would be $240 –$50 = $190 million. The effect of selling shares below their true value is to transfer $30 million of value from the founders to the investors who buy the new shares. Unfortunately, underpricing does not mean that anyone can become wealthy by buy- ing stock in IPOs. If an issue is underpriced, everybody will want to buy it and the un- derwriters will not have enough stock to go around. You are therefore likely to get only a small share of these hot issues. If it is overpriced, other investors are unlikely to want it and the underwriter will be only too delighted to sell it to you. This phenomenon is known as the winner’s curse.5 It implies that, unless you can spot which issues are un- derpriced, you are likely to receive a small proportion of the cheap issues and a large proportion of the expensive ones. Since the dice are loaded against uninformed in- vestors, they will play the game only if there is substantial underpricing on average. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 2 Underpricing of IPOs and Investor Returns Suppose that an investor will earn an immediate 10 percent return on underpriced IPOs and lose 5 percent on overpriced IPOs. But because of high demand, you may get only 5 The highest bidder in an auction is the participant who places the highest value on the auctioned object. Therefore, it is likely that the winning bidder has an overly optimistic assessment of true value. Winning the auction suggests that you have overpaid for the object—this is the winner’s curse. In the case of IPOs, your ability to “win” an allotment of shares may signal that the stock is overpriced. FINANCE IN ACTION Internet Shares: Loopy.com? The tiny images are like demented postage stamps coming jerkily to life; the sound is prone to break up and at times could be coming from a bathroom plughole. Welcome to the Internet live broadcasting experience. However, despite offering audio-visual quality that would have been unacceptable in the pioneering days of television, a small, loss-making company called Broadcast.com broke all previous records when it made its Wall Street debut on July 17th. Shares in the Dallas-based company were offered at $18 and reached as high as $74 before closing at $62.75— a gain of nearly 250% on the day after a feed- ing frenzy in which 6.5m shares changed hands. After the dust had settled, Broadcast.com was established as a $1 billion company, and its two 30-something founders, Mark Cuban and Todd Wagner, were worth nearly $500m between them. In its three years of existence, Broadcast.com, for- merly known as AudioNet, has lost nearly $13m, and its offer document frankly told potential investors that it had absolutely no idea when it might start to make money. So has Wall Street finally taken leave of its senses? The value being placed on Broadcast.com is not ob- viously loopier than a number of other gravity-defying Internet stocks, particularly the currently fashionable “ portals” — gateways to the Web— such as Yahoo! and America Online. Yahoo!, the Internet’s leading content aggregator, has nearly doubled in value since June. On the back of revenue estimates of around $165m, it has a market value of $8.7 billion. Mark Hardie, an analyst with the high-tech con- sultancy Forrester Research, does not believe, in any case, that the enthusiasm for Broadcast.com has been overdone. He says: “ There are no entrenched players in this space. The ‘old’ media are aware that the intelli- gence to exploit the Internet lies outside their organiza- tions and are standing back waiting to see what hap-
Brealey
pens. Broadcast.com is well-positioned to be a service intermediary for those companies and for other content owners.” Persuaded? Source: © 1998 The Economist Newspaper Group, Inc. Reprinted with permission. Further reproduction prohibited. www.economist. com. half the shares you bid for when the issue is underpriced. Suppose you bid for $1,000 of shares in two issues, one overpriced and the other underpriced. You are awarded the full $1,000 of the overpriced issue, but only $500 worth of shares in the underpriced issue. The net gain on your two investments is (.10 × $500) – (.05 × $1,000) = 0. Your net profit is zero, despite the fact that on average, IPOs are underpriced. You have suffered the winner’s curse: you “win” a larger allotment of shares when they are overpriced. (cid:1) Self-Test 2 FLOTATION COSTS The costs incurred when a firm issues new securities to the public. 524 What is the percentage profit earned by an investor who can identify the underpriced issues in Example 2? Who are such investors likely to be? The costs of a new issue are termed flotation costs. Underpricing is not the only flotation cost. In fact, when people talk about the cost of a new issue, they often think only of the direct costs of the issue. For example, preparation of the registration state- ment and prospectus involves management, legal counsel, and accountants, as well as underwriters and their advisers. There is also the underwriting spread. (Remember, un- derwriters make their profit by selling the issue at a higher price than they paid for it.) Table 5.10 summarizes the costs of going public. The table includes the underwrit- ing spread and administrative costs as well as the cost of underpricing, as measured by the initial return on the stock. For a small IPO of no more than $10 million, the under- TABLE 5.10 Average expenses of 1,767 initial public offerings, 1990–1994a How Corporations Issue Securities 525 Value of Issue (millions of dollars) Direct Costs, %b Average First-Day Return, %b Total Costs, %c 2–9.99 10–19.99 20–39.99 40–59.99 60–79.99 80–99.99 100–199.99 200–499.99 500 and up All issues 16.96 11.63 9.70 8.72 8.20 7.91 7.06 6.53 5.72 11.00 16.36 9.65 12.48 13.65 11.31 8.91 7.16 5.70 7.53 12.05 25.16 18.15 18.18 17.95 16.35 14.14 12.78 11.10 10.36 18.69 a The table includes only issues where there was a firm underwriting commitment. b Direct costs (i.e., underwriting spread plus administrative costs) and average initial return are expressed as a percentage of the issue price. c Total costs (i.e., direct costs plus underpricing) are expressed as a percentage of the market price of the share. Source: J. R. Ritter et al., “The Costs of Raising Capital,” Journal of Financial Research 19, No. 1, Spring 1996. Reprinted by permission. writing spread and administrative costs are likely to absorb 15 to 20 percent of the pro- ceeds from the issue. For the very largest IPOs, these direct costs may amount to only 5 percent of the proceeds. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 3 Costs of an IPO When the investment bank Goldman Sachs went public in 1999, the sale was partly a primary issue (the company sold new shares to raise cash) and partly a secondary one (two large existing shareholders cashed in some of their shares). The underwriters ac- quired a total of 69 million Goldman Sachs shares for $50.75 each and sold them to the public at an offering price of $53.6 The underwriters’ spread was therefore $53 – $50.75 = $2.25. The firm and its shareholders also paid a total of $9.2 million in legal fees and other costs. By the end of the first day’s trading Goldman’s stock price had risen to $70. Here are the direct costs of the Goldman Sachs issue: Direct Expenses Underwriting spread Other expenses Total direct expenses 69 million × $2.25 = $155.25 million 9.2 $164.45 million The total amount of money raised by the issue was 69 million × $53 = $3,657 million. Of this sum 4.5 percent was absorbed by direct expenses (that is, 164.45/3,657 = .045). In addition to these direct costs, there was underpricing. The market valued each
Brealey
share of Goldman Sachs at $70, so the cost of underpricing was 69 million × ($70 – 6 No prizes for guessing which investment bank acted as lead underwriter. 526 SECTION FIVE $53) = $1,173 million, resulting in total costs of $164.45 + $1,173 = $1,337.45 million. Therefore, while the total market value of the issued shares was 69 million × $70 = $4,830 million, direct costs and the costs of underpricing absorbed nearly 28 percent of the market value of the shares. (cid:1) Self-Test 3 Suppose that the underwriters acquired Goldman Sachs shares for $60 and sold them to the public at an offering price of $64. If all other features of the offer were unchanged (and investors still valued the stock at $70 a share), what would have been the direct costs of the issue and the costs of underpricing? What would have been the total costs as a proportion of the market value of the shares? The Underwriters We have described underwriters as playing a triple role—providing advice, buying a new issue from the company, and reselling it to investors. Underwriters don’t just help the company to make its initial public offering; they are called in whenever a company wishes to raise cash by selling securities to the public. Most companies raise capital only occasionally, but underwriters are in the business all the time. Established underwriters are careful of their reputation and will not handle a new issue unless they believe the facts have been presented fairly to investors. Thus, in addition to handling the sale of an issue, the underwriters in effect give it their seal of approval. This implied endorsement may be worth quite a bit to a company that is coming to the market for the first time. Underwriting is not always fun. On October 15, 1987, the British government final- ized arrangements to sell its holding of British Petroleum (BP) shares at £3.30 a share. This huge issue involving more than $12 billion was underwritten by an international group of underwriters and simultaneously marketed in a number of countries. Four days after the underwriting arrangement was finalized, the October stock market crash oc- curred and stock prices nose-dived. The underwriters appealed to the British govern- ment to cancel the issue but the government hardened its heart and pointed out that the underwriters knew the risks when they agreed to handle the sale.7 By the closing date of the offer, the price of BP stock had fallen to £2.96 and the underwriters had lost more than $1 billion. WHO ARE THE UNDERWRITERS? Since underwriters play such a crucial role in new issues, we should look at who they are. Several thousand investment banks, security dealers, and brokers are at least spo- 7 The government’s only concession was to put a floor on the underwriters’ losses by giving them the option to resell their stock to the government at £2.80 a share. The BP offering is described and analyzed in C. Mus- carella and M. Vetsuypens, “The British Petroleum Stock Offering: An Application of Option Pricing,” Jour- nal of Applied Corporate Finance 1 (1989), pp. 74–80. How Corporations Issue Securities 527 TABLE 5.11 Top underwriters of U.S. debt and equity, 1998 (figures in billions) Underwriter Value of Issues Merrill Lynch Salomon Smith Barney Morgan Stanley Dean Witter Goldman Sachs Lehman Brothers Credit Suisse First Boston J. P. Morgan Bear Stearns Chase Manhattan Donaldson Lufkin & Jenrette All underwriters Source: Securities Data Co. $ 304 225 203 192 147 127 89 83 71 61 $1,820 radically involved in underwriting. However, the market for the larger issues is domi- nated by the major investment banking firms, which specialize in underwriting new is- sues, dealing in securities, and arranging mergers. These firms enjoy great prestige, ex- perience, and financial muscle. Table 5.11 lists some of the largest firms, ranked by total volume of issues in 1998. Merrill Lynch, the winner, raised a total of $304 billion. Of course, only a small proportion of these issues was for companies that were coming to the market for the first time.
Brealey
Earlier we pointed out that instead of issuing bonds in the United States, many cor- porations issue international bonds in London, which are then sold to investors outside the United States. In addition, new equity issues by large multinational companies are increasingly marketed to investors throughout the world. Since these securities are sold in a number of countries, many of the major international banks are involved in under- writing the issues. For example, look at Table 5.12 which shows the names of the prin- cipal underwriters of international issues in 1998. TABLE 5.12 Top underwriters of international issues of securities, 1998 (figures in billions) Underwriter Value of Issues Warburg Dillon Read Merrill Lynch Morgan Stanley Dean Witter Goldman Sachs ABN AMRO Deutsche Bank Paribas J. P. Morgan Barclays Capital Credit Suisse First Boston All underwriters Source: Securities Data Co. $ 63.6 52.3 43.6 42.5 41.5 39.0 38.7 36.0 31.1 25.7 $665.5 528 SECTION FIVE SEASONED OFFERING Sale of securities by a firm that is already publicly traded. RIGHTS ISSUE Issue of securities offered only to current stockholders. General Cash Offers by Public Companies After the initial public offering a successful firm will continue to grow and from time to time it will need to raise more money by issuing stock or bonds. An issue of addi- tional stock by a company whose stock already is publicly traded is called a seasoned offering. Any issue of securities needs to be formally approved by the firm’s board of directors. If a stock issue requires an increase in the company’s authorized capital, it also needs the consent of the stockholders. Public companies can issue securities either by making a general cash offer to in- vestors at large or by making a rights issue, which is limited to existing shareholders. In the latter case, the company offers the shareholders the opportunity, or right, to buy more shares at an “attractive” price. For example, if the current stock price is $100, the company might offer investors an additional share at $50 for each share they hold. Sup- pose that before the issue an investor has one share worth $100 and $50 in the bank. If the investor takes up the offer of a new share, that $50 of cash is transferred from the investor’s bank account to the company’s. The investor now has two shares that are a claim on the original assets worth $100 and on the $50 cash that the company has raised. So the two shares are worth a total of $150, or $75 each. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 4 Rights Issues Easy Writer Word Processing Company has 1 million shares outstanding, selling at $20 a share. To finance the development of a new software package, it plans a rights issue, allowing one new share to be purchased for each 10 shares currently held. The purchase price will be $10 a share. How many shares will be issued? How much money will be raised? What will be the stock price after the rights issue? The firm will issue one new share for every 10 old ones, or 100,000 shares. So shares outstanding will rise to 1.1 million. The firm will raise $10 × 100,000 = $1 mil- lion. Therefore, the total value of the firm will increase from $20 million to $21 mil- lion, and the stock price will fall to $21 million/1.1 million shares = $19.09 per share. In some countries the rights issue is the most common or only method for issuing stock, but in the United States rights issues are now very rare. We therefore will con- centrate on the mechanics of the general cash offer. GENERAL CASH OFFERS AND SHELF REGISTRATION GENERAL CASH OFFER Sale of securities open to all investors by an already- public company. When a public company makes a general cash offer of debt or equity, it essentially fol- lows the same procedure used when it first went public. This means that it must first register the issue with the SEC and draw up a prospectus.8 Before settling on the issue price, the underwriters will usually contact potential investors and build up a book of 8 The procedure is similar when a company makes an international issue of bonds or equity, but as long as
Brealey
these issues are not sold publicly in the United States, they do not need to be registered with the SEC. SHELF REGISTRATION A procedure that allows firms to file one registration statement for several issues of the same security. How Corporations Issue Securities 529 likely orders. The company will then sell the issue to the underwriters, and they in turn will offer the securities to the public. Companies do not need to prepare a separate registration statement every time they issue new securities. Instead, they are allowed to file a single registration statement cov- ering financing plans for up to 2 years into the future. The actual issues can then be sold to the public with scant additional paperwork, whenever the firm needs cash or thinks it can issue securities at an attractive price. This is called shelf registration—the regis- tration is put “on the shelf,” to be taken down, dusted off, and used as needed. Think of how you might use shelf registration when you are a financial manager. Suppose that your company is likely to need up to $200 million of new long-term debt over the next year or so. It can file a registration statement for that amount. It now has approval to issue up to $200 million of debt, but it isn’t obliged to issue any. Nor is it required to work through any particular underwriters—the registration statement may name the underwriters the firm thinks it may work with, but others can be substituted later. Now you can sit back and issue debt as needed, in bits and pieces if you like. Sup- pose Merrill Lynch comes across an insurance company with $10 million ready to in- vest in corporate bonds, priced to yield, say, 7.3 percent. If you think that’s a good deal, you say “OK” and the deal is done, subject to only a little additional paperwork. Mer- rill Lynch then resells the bonds to the insurance company, hoping for a higher price than it paid for them. Here is another possible deal. Suppose you think you see a window of opportunity in which interest rates are “temporarily low.” You invite bids for $100 million of bonds. Some bids may come from large investment bankers acting alone, others from ad hoc syndicates. But that’s not your problem; if the price is right, you just take the best deal offered. Thus shelf registration gives firms several different things that they did not have pre- viously: 1. Securities can be issued in dribs and drabs without incurring excessive costs. 2. Securities can be issued on short notice. 3. Security issues can be timed to take advantage of “market conditions” (although any financial manager who can reliably identify favorable market conditions could make a lot more money by quitting and becoming a bond or stock trader instead). 4. The issuing firm can make sure that underwriters compete for its business. Not all companies eligible for shelf registration actually use it for all their public is- sues. Sometimes they believe they can get a better deal by making one large issue through traditional channels, especially when the security to be issued has some unusual feature or when the firm believes it needs the investment banker’s counsel or stamp of approval on the issue. Thus shelf registration is less often used for issues of common stock than for garden-variety corporate bonds. COSTS OF THE GENERAL CASH OFFER Whenever a firm makes a cash offer, it incurs substantial administrative costs. Also, the firm needs to compensate the underwriters by selling them securities below the price that they expect to receive from investors. Figure 5.7 shows the average underwriting spread and administrative costs for several types of security issues in the United States.9 9 These figures do not capture all administrative costs. For example, they do not include management time spent on the issue. 530 SECTION FIVE FIGURE 5.7 Total direct costs as a percentage of gross proceeds. The total direct costs for initial public offerings (IPOs), seasoned equity offerings (SEOs), convertible bonds, and straight bonds are composed of underwriter spreads and other direct expenses. ) % ( s t s o c t c e r i d l a t o T 20 15 10 5 0 2– 9.99 10– 19.99 20– 39.99 IPOs SEOs
Brealey
Convertibles Bonds 40– 59.99 60– 79.99 Proceeds ($ millions) 80– 99.99 100– 199.99 200– 499.99 500– up Source: Immoo Lee, Scott Lochhead, Jay Ritter, and Quanshui Zhao, “The Costs of Raising Capital,” Journal of Financial Research 19 (Spring 1996), pp. 59–74. Copyright © 1996. Reprinted by permission. The figure clearly shows the economies of scale in issuing securities. Costs may ab- sorb 15 percent of a $1 million seasoned equity issue but less than 4 percent of a $500 million issue. This occurs because a large part of the issue cost is fixed. Figure 5.7 shows that issue costs are higher for equity than for debt securities—the costs for both types of securities, however, show the same economies of scale. Issue costs are higher for equity than for debt because administrative costs are somewhat higher, and also because underwriting stock is riskier than underwriting bonds. The un- derwriters demand additional compensation for the greater risk they take in buying and reselling equity. (cid:1) Self-Test 4 Use Figure 5.7 to compare the costs of 10 issues of $15 million of stock in a seasoned offering versus one issue of $150 million. MARKET REACTION TO STOCK ISSUES Because stock issues usually throw a sizable number of new shares onto the market, it is widely believed that they must temporarily depress the stock price. If the proposed issue is very large, this price pressure may, it is thought, be so severe as to make it al- most impossible to raise money. This belief in price pressure implies that a new issue depresses the stock price tem- porarily below its true value. However, that view doesn’t appear to fit very well with the notion of market efficiency. If the stock price falls solely because of increased supply, How Corporations Issue Securities 531 then that stock would offer a higher return than comparable stocks and investors would be attracted to it as ants to a picnic. Economists who have studied new issues of common stock have generally found that the announcement of the issue does result in a decline in the stock price. For industrial issues in the United States this decline amounts to about 3 percent.10 While this may not sound overwhelming, such a price drop can be a large fraction of the money raised. Sup- pose that a company with a market value of equity of $5 billion announces its intention to issue $500 million of additional equity and thereby causes the stock price to drop by 3 percent. The loss in value is .03 × $5 billion, or $150 million. That’s 30 percent of the amount of money raised (.30 × $500 million = $150 million). What’s going on here? Is the price of the stock simply depressed by the prospect of the additional supply? Possibly, but here is an alternative explanation. Suppose managers (who have better information about the firm than outside in- vestors) know that their stock is undervalued. If the company sells new stock at this low price, it will give the new shareholders a good deal at the expense of the old share- holders. In these circumstances managers might be prepared to forgo the new invest- ment rather than sell shares at too low a price. If managers know that the stock is overvalued, the position is reversed. If the com- pany sells new shares at the high price, it will help its existing shareholders at the ex- pense of the new ones. Managers might be prepared to issue stock even if the new cash were just put in the bank. Of course investors are not stupid. They can predict that managers are more likely to issue stock when they think it is overvalued and therefore they mark the price of the stock down accordingly. The tendency for stock prices to decline at the time of an issue may have nothing to do with increased supply. Instead, the stock issue may simply be a signal that well-informed managers believe the market has overpriced the stock.11 The Private Placement Whenever a company makes a public offering, it must register the issue with the SEC. It could avoid this costly process by selling the issue privately. There are no hard-
Brealey
and-fast definitions of a private placement, but the SEC has insisted that the security should be sold to no more than a dozen or so knowledgeable investors. 10 See, for example, P. Asquith and D. W. Mullins, “Equity Issues and Offering Dilution,” Journal of Finan- cial Economics 15 (January–February 1986), pp. 61–90; R. W. Masulis and A. N. Korwar, “Seasoned Equity Offerings: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Financial Economics 15 (January–February 1986), pp. 91–118; W. H. Mikkelson and M. M. Partch, “Valuation Effects of Security Offerings and the Issuance Process,” Journal of Financial Economics 15 (January–February 1986), pp. 31–60. There appears to be a smaller price decline for utility issues. Also Marsh observed a smaller decline for rights issues in the United Kingdom; see P. R. Marsh, “Equity Rights Issues and the Efficiency of the UK Stock Market,” Journal of Fi- nance 34 (September 1979), pp. 839–862. 11 This explanation was developed in S. C. Myers and N. S. Majluf, “Corporate Financing and Investment De- cisions When Firms Have Information that Investors Do Not Have,” Journal of Financial Economics 13 (1984), pp. 187–222. PRIVATE PLACEMENT Sale of securities to a limited number of investors without a public offering. 532 SECTION FIVE One disadvantage of a private placement is that the investor cannot easily resell the security. This is less important to institutions such as life insurance companies, which invest huge sums of money in corporate debt for the long haul. However, in 1990 the SEC relaxed its restrictions on who could buy unregistered issues. Under the new rule, Rule 144a, large financial institutions can trade unregistered securities among them- selves. As you would expect, it costs less to arrange a private placement than to make a pub- lic issue. That might not be so important for the very large issues where costs are less significant, but it is a particular advantage for companies making smaller issues. Another advantage of the private placement is that the debt contract can be custom- tailored for firms with special problems or opportunities. Also, if the firm wishes later to change the terms of the debt, it is much simpler to do this with a private placement where only a few investors are involved. Therefore, it is not surprising that private placements occupy a particular niche in the corporate debt market, namely, loans to small and medium-sized firms. These are the firms that face the highest costs in public issues, that require the most detailed investi- gation, and that may require specialized, flexible loan arrangements. We do not mean that large, safe, and conventional firms should rule out private placements. Enormous amounts of capital are sometimes raised by this method. For ex- ample, AT&T once borrowed $500 million in a single private placement. Nevertheless, the advantages of private placement—avoiding registration costs and establishing a di- rect relationship with the lender—are generally more important to smaller firms. Of course these advantages are not free. Lenders in private placements have to be compensated for the risks they face and for the costs of research and negotiation. They also have to be compensated for holding an asset that is not easily resold. All these fac- tors are rolled into the interest rate paid by the firm. It is difficult to generalize about the differences in interest rates between private placements and public issues, but a typ- ical yield differential is on the order of half a percentage point. Summary How do venture capital firms design successful deals? Infant companies raise venture capital to carry them through to the point at which they can make their first public issue of stock. More established publicly traded companies can issue additional securities in a general cash offer. Financing choices should be designed to avoid conflicts of interest. This is especially important in the case of a young company that is raising venture capital. If both managers
Brealey
and investors have an important equity stake in the company, they are likely to pull in the same direction. The willingness to take that stake also signals management’s confidence in the new company’s future. Therefore, most deals require that the entrepreneur maintain large stakes in the firm. In addition, most venture financing is done in stages that keep the firm on a short leash, and force it to prove at several crucial points that it is worthy of additional investment. How do firms make initial public offerings and what are the costs of such offerings? The initial public offering is the first sale of shares in a general offering to investors. The sale of the securities is usually managed by an underwriting firm which buys the shares from the company and resells them to the public. The underwriter helps to prepare a prospectus, which describes the company and its prospects. The costs of an IPO include How Corporations Issue Securities 533 direct costs such as legal and administrative fees, as well as the underwriting spread—the difference between the price the underwriter pays to acquire the shares from the firm and the price the public pays the underwriter for those shares. Another major implicit cost is the underpricing of the issue—that is, shares are typically sold to the public somewhat below the true value of the security. This discount is reflected in abnormally high average returns to new issues on the first day of trading. What are some of the significant issues that arise when established firms make a general cash offer or a private placement of securities? There are always economies of scale in issuing securities. It is cheaper to go to the market once for $100 million than to make two trips for $50 million each. Consequently, firms “bunch” security issues. This may mean relying on short-term financing until a large issue is justified. Or it may mean issuing more than is needed at the moment to avoid another issue later. A seasoned offering may depress the stock price. The extent of this price decline varies, but for issues of common stocks by industrial firms the fall in the value of the existing stock may amount to a significant proportion of the money raised. The likely explanation for this pressure is the information the market reads into the company’s decision to issue stock. Shelf registration often makes sense for debt issues by blue-chip firms. Shelf registration reduces the time taken to arrange a new issue, it increases flexibility, and it may cut underwriting costs. It seems best suited for debt issues by large firms that are happy to switch between investment banks. It seems least suited for issues of unusually risky securities or for issues by small companies that most need a close relationship with an investment bank. Private placements are well-suited for small, risky, or unusual firms. The special advantages of private placement stem from avoiding registration expenses and a more direct relationship with the lender. These are not worth as much to blue-chip borrowers. What is the role of the underwriter in an issue of securities? The underwriter manages the sale of the securities for the issuing company. The underwriting firms have expertise in such sales because they are in the business all the time, whereas the company raises capital only occasionally. Moreover, the underwriters may give an implicit seal of approval to the offering. Because the underwriters will not want to squander their reputation by misrepresenting facts to the public, the implied endorsement may be quite important to a firm coming to the market for the first time. Related Web Links www.FreeEDGAR.com/default.htm Information on registration of new securities offerings http://cbs.marketwatch.com/news/current/ipo_rep.htx?source=htx/http2_mw List of new IPOs www.cob.ohio-state.edu/~fin/resources_education/credit.htm The changing mix of corporate financing www.investorama.com/features/proxystatements.html The role of the proxy statement in in- vestor relations www.vnpartners.com/primer.htm Venture capital as a source of project financing Key Terms
Brealey
venture capital initial public offering (IPO) underwriter spread prospectus underpricing flotation costs seasoned offering rights issue general cash offer shelf registration private placement 534 SECTION FIVE Quiz 1. Underwriting. a. Is a rights issue more likely to be used for an initial public offering or for subsequent is- sues of stock? b. Is a private placement more likely to be used for issues of seasoned stock or seasoned bonds by an industrial company? c. Is shelf registration more likely to be used for issues of unseasoned stocks or bonds by a large industrial company? 2. Underwriting. Each of the following terms is associated with one of the events beneath. Can you match them up? a. Shelf registration b. Firm commitment c. Rights issue A. The underwriter agrees to buy the issue from the company at a fixed price. B. The company offers to sell stock to existing stockholders. C. Several issues of the same security may be sold under the same registration. 3. Underwriting Costs. State for each of the following pairs of issues which you would expect to involve the lower proportionate underwriting and administrative costs, other things equal: a. A large issue/a small issue b. A bond issue/a common stock issue c. A small private placement of bonds/a small general cash offer of bonds 4. IPO Costs. Why are the issue costs for debt issues generally less than those for equity is- sues? 5. Venture Capital. Why do venture capital companies prefer to advance money in stages? 6. IPOs. Your broker calls and says that you can get 500 shares of an imminent IPO at the of- fering price. Should you buy? Are you worried about the fact that your broker called you? Practice Problems 7. IPO Underpricing. Having heard about IPO underpricing, I put in an order to my broker for 1,000 shares of every IPO he can get for me. After 3 months, my investment record is as follows: IPO Shares Allocated to Me Price per Share Initial Return A B C D 500 200 1,000 0 $10 20 8 12 7% 12 –2 23 a. What is the average underpricing of this sample of IPOs? b. What is the average initial return on my “portfolio” of shares purchased from the four IPOs I bid on? Calculate the average initial return, weighting by the amount of money in- vested in each issue. c. Why have I performed so poorly relative to the average initial return on the full sample of IPOs? What lessons do you draw from my experience? 8. IPO Costs. Moonscape has just completed an initial public offering. The firm sold 3 mil- lion shares at an offer price of $8 per share. The underwriting spread was $.50 a share. The How Corporations Issue Securities 535 price of the stock closed at $11 per share at the end of the first day of trading. The firm in- curred $100,000 in legal, administrative, and other costs. What were flotation costs as a frac- tion of funds raised? Were flotation costs for Moonscape higher or lower than is typical for IPOs of this size (see Table 5.10)? 9. IPO Costs. Look at the illustrative new issue prospectus in the appendix. a. Is this issue a primary offering, a secondary offering, or both? b. What are the direct costs of the issue as a percentage of the total proceeds? Are these more than the average for an issue of this size? c. Suppose that on the first day of trading the price of Hotch Pot stock is $15 a share. What are the total costs of the issue as a percentage of the market price? d. After paying her share of the expenses, how much will the firm’s president, Emma Lu- cullus, receive from the sale? What will be the value of the shares that she retains in the company? 10. Flotation Costs. “For small issues of common stock, the costs of flotation amount to about 15 percent of the proceeds. This means that the opportunity cost of external equity capital is about 15 percentage points higher than that of retained earnings.” Does this follow? 11. Flotation Costs. When Microsoft went public, the company sold 2 million new shares (the primary issue). In addition, existing shareholders sold .8 million shares (the secondary issue) and kept 21.1 million shares. The new shares were offered to the public at $21 and the un-
Brealey
derwriters received a spread of $1.31 a share. At the end of the first day’s trading the mar- ket price was $35 a share. a. How much money did the company receive before paying its portion of the direct costs? b. How much did the existing shareholders receive from the sale before paying their portion of the direct costs? c. If the issue had been sold to the underwriters for $30 a share, how many shares would the company have needed to sell to raise the same amount of cash? d. How much better off would the existing shareholders have been? 12. Flotation Costs. The market value of the marketing research firm Fax Facts is $600 million. The firm issues an additional $100 million of stock, but as a result the stock price falls by 2 percent. What is the cost of the price drop to existing shareholders as a fraction of the funds raised? 13. Flotation Costs. Young Corporation stock currently sells for $30 per share. There are 1 mil- lion shares currently outstanding. The company announces plans to raise $3 million by of- fering shares to the public at a price of $30 per share. a. If the underwriting spread is 8 percent, how many shares will the company need to issue in order to be left with net proceeds of $3 million? b. If other administrative costs are $60,000 what is the dollar value of the total direct costs of the issue? c. If the share price falls by 3 percent at the announcement of the plans to proceed with a seasoned offering, what is the dollar cost of the announcement effect? 14. Private Placements. You need to choose between the following types of issues: A public issue of $10 million face value of 10-year debt. The interest rate on the debt would be 8.5 percent and the debt would be issued at face value. The underwriting spread would be 1.5 percent and other expenses would be $80,000. A private placement of $10 million face value of 10-year debt. The interest rate on the private placement would be 9 percent but the total issuing expenses would be only $30,000. 536 SECTION FIVE Challenge Problem a. What is the difference in the proceeds to the company net of expenses? b. Other things equal, which is the better deal? c. What other factors beyond the interest rate and issue costs would you wish to consider before deciding between the two offers? 15. Rights. In 2001 Pandora, Inc., makes a rights issue at a subscription price of $5 a share. One new share can be purchased for every four shares held. Before the issue there were 10 mil- lion shares outstanding and the share price was $6. a. What is the total amount of new money raised? b. What is the expected stock price after the rights are issued? 16. Rights. Problem 15 contains details of a rights offering by Pandora. Suppose that the com- pany had decided to issue the new stock at $4 instead of $5 a share. How many new shares would it have needed to raise the same sum of money? Recalculate the answers to problem 15. Show that Pandora’s shareholders are just as well off if it issues the shares at $4 a share rather than the $5 assumed in problem 15. 17. Rights. Consolidated Jewels needs to raise $2 million to pay for its Diamonds in the Rough campaign. It will raise the funds by offering 200,000 rights, each of which entitles the owner to buy one new share. The company currently has outstanding 1 million shares priced at $20 each. a. What must be the subscription price on the rights the company plans to offer? b. What will be the share price after the rights issue? c. What is the value of a right to buy one share? d. How many rights would be issued to an investor who currently owns 1,000 shares? e. Show that the investor who currently holds 1,000 shares is unaffected by the rights issue. Specifically, show that the value of the rights plus the value of the 1,000 shares after the rights issue equals the value of the 1,000 shares before the rights issue. 18. Rights. Associated Breweries is planning to market unleaded beer. To finance the venture it proposes to make a rights issue with a subscription price of $10. One new share can be pur-
Brealey
chased for each two shares held. The company currently has outstanding 100,000 shares priced at $40 a share. Assuming that the new money is invested to earn a fair return, give values for the a. number of new shares b. amount of new investment c. total value of company after issue d. total number of shares after issue e. share price after the issue 19. Venture Capital. Here is a difficult question. Pickwick Electronics is a new high-tech com- pany financed entirely by 1 million ordinary shares, all of which are owned by George Pick- wick. The firm needs to raise $1 million now for stage 1 and, assuming all goes well, a fur- ther $1 million at the end of 5 years for stage 2. First Cookham Venture Partners is considering two possible financing schemes: Buying 2 million shares now at their current valuation of $1. Buying 1 million shares at the current valuation and investing a further $1 million at the end of 5 years at whatever the shares are worth. The outlook for Pickwick is uncertain, but as long as the company can secure the additional finance for stage 2, it will be worth either $2 million or $12 million after completing stage Solutions to Self-Test Questions How Corporations Issue Securities 537 2. (The company will be valueless if it cannot raise the funds for stage 2.) Show the possi- ble payoffs for Mr. Pickwick and First Cookham and explain why one scheme might be pre- ferred. Assume an interest rate of zero. 1 Unless the firm can secure second-stage financing, it is unlikely to succeed. If the entre- preneur is going to reap any reward on his own investment, he needs to put in enough ef- fort to get further financing. By accepting only part of the necessary venture capital, man- agement increases its own risk and reduces that of the venture capitalist. This decision would be costly and foolish if management lacked confidence that the project would be successful enough to get past the first stage. A credible signal by management is one that only managers who are truly confident can afford to provide. However, words are cheap and there is little to be lost by saying that you are confident (although if you are proved wrong, you may find it difficult to raise money a second time). 2 If an investor can distinguish between overpriced and underpriced issues, she will bid only on the underpriced ones. In this case she will purchase only issues that provide a 10 percent gain. However, the ability to distinguish these issues requires considerable insight and re- search. The return to the informed IPO participant may be viewed as a return on the re- sources expended to become informed. 3 Direct expenses: Underwriting spread = 69 million × $4 Other expenses Total direct expenses Underpricing = 69 million × ($70 – $64) Total expenses Market value of issue = 69 million × $70 $ 276.0 million 9.2 $ 285.2 million $ 414.0 million $ 699.2 million $4,830.0 million Expenses as proportion of market value = 699.2/4,830 = .145 = 14.5%. 4 Ten issues of $15 million each will cost about 9 percent of proceeds, or .09 × $150 million = $13.5 million. One issue of $150 million will cost only 4 percent of $150 million, or $6 million. MINICASE Pet.Com was founded in 1997 by two graduates of the University of Wisconsin with help from Georgina Sloberg, who had built up an enviable reputation for backing new start-up businesses. Pet.Com’s user-friendly system was designed to find buyers for unwanted pets. Within 3 years the company was generating rev- enues of $3.4 million a year, and, despite racking up sizable losses, was regarded by investors as one of the hottest new e-commerce businesses. The news that the company was preparing to go pub- lic therefore generated considerable excitement. The company’s entire equity capital of 1.5 million shares was owned by the two founders and Ms. Sloberg. The initial public of- fering involved the sale of 500,000 shares by the three existing shareholders, together with the sale of a further 750,000 shares by the company in order to provide funds for expansion.
Brealey
The company estimated that the issue would involve legal fees, auditing, printing, and other expenses of $1.3 million, which would be shared proportionately between the selling shareholders and the company. In addition, the company agreed to pay the un- derwriters a spread of $1.25 per share. The roadshow had confirmed the high level of interest in the issue, and indications from investors suggested that the entire issue could be sold at a price of $24 a share. The underwriters, however, cautioned about being too greedy on price. They pointed out that indications from investors were not the same as firm orders. Also, they argued, it was much more important to have a successful issue than to have a group of disgruntled share- holders. They therefore suggested an issue price of $18 a share. That evening Pet.Com’s financial manager decided to run 538 SECTION FIVE through some calculations. First she worked out the net receipts to the company and the existing shareholders assuming that the stock was sold for $18 a share. Next she looked at the various costs of the IPO and tried to judge how they stacked up against the typical costs for similar IPOs. That brought her up against the question of underpricing. When she had raised the matter with the underwriters that morning, they had dismissed the notion that the initial day’s return on an IPO should be considered part of the issue costs. One of the members of the underwriting team had asked: “The underwriters want to see a high return and a high stock price. Would Pet.Com prefer a low stock price? Would that make the issue less costly?” Pet.Com’s financial manager was not convinced but felt that she should have a good answer. She won- dered whether underpricing was only a problem because the ex- isting shareholders were selling part of their holdings. Perhaps the issue price would not matter if they had not planned to sell. Appendix: Hotch Pot’s New Issue Prospectus12 How Corporations Issue Securities 539 PROSPECTUS 800,000 Shares Hotch Pot, Inc. Common Stock ($.01 par value) Of the 800,000 shares of Common Stock offered hereby, 500,000 shares are being sold by the Company and 300,000 shares are being sold by the Selling Stockholders. See “Principal and Selling Stockholders.” The Company will not receive any of the pro- ceeds from the sale of shares by the Selling Stockholders. Before this offering there has been no public market for the Common Stock. These se- curities involve a high degree of risk. See “Certain Factors.” THESE SECURITIES HAVE NOT BEEN APPROVED OR DISAPPROVED BY THE SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION NOR HAS THE COMMISSION PASSED ON THE ACCURACY OR ADEQUACY OF THIS PROSPECTUS. ANY REPRESENTATION TO THE CONTRARY IS A CRIMI- NAL OFFENSE. Price to Public Underwriting Discount Proceeds to Company1 Proceeds to Selling Shareholders Per share Total $12.00 $9,600,000 $1.30 $1,040,000 $10.70 $5,350,000 $10.70 $3,210,000 1 Before deducting expenses payable by the Company estimated at $400,000, of which $250,000 will be paid by the Company and $150,000 by the Selling Stockholders. The Common Stock is offered, subject to prior sale, when, as, and if delivered to and accepted by the Underwriters and subject to approval of certain legal matters by their counsel and by counsel for the Company and the Selling Shareholders. The Underwrit- ers reserve the right to withdraw, cancel, or modify such offer and reject orders in whole or in part. Silverman Pinch Inc. April 1, 2000 No person has been authorized to give any information or to make any representations, other than as contained therein, in connection with the offer contained in this Prospec- tus, and, if given or made, such information or representations must not be relied upon. This Prospectus does not constitute an offer of any securities other than the registered securities to which it relates or an offer to any person in any jurisdiction where such an offer would be unlawful. The delivery of this Prospectus at any time does not imply that
Brealey
information herein is correct as of any time subsequent to its date. IN CONNECTION WITH THIS OFFERING, THE UNDERWRITER MAY OVERALLOT OR EFFECT TRANSACTIONS WHICH STABILIZE OR 12 Most prospectuses have content similar to that of the Hotch Pot prospectus but go into considerably more detail. Also, we have omitted from the Hotch Pot prospectus the company’s financial statements. 540 SECTION FIVE How Corporations Issue Securities 540 MAINTAIN THE MARKET PRICE OF THE COMMON STOCK OF THE COMPANY AT A LEVEL ABOVE THAT WHICH MIGHT OTHERWISE PREVAIL IN THE OPEN MARKET. SUCH STABILIZING, IF COMMENCED, MAY BE DISCONTINUED AT ANY TIME. Prospectus Summary The following summary information is qualified in its entirety by the detailed informa- tion and financial statements appearing elsewhere in this Prospectus. The Company: Hotch Pot, Inc. operates a chain of 140 fast-food outlets in the United States offering unusual combinations of dishes. The Offering: Common Stock offered by the Company 500,000 shares; Common Stock offered by the Selling Stockholders 300,000 shares; Common Stock to be outstanding after this offering 3,500,000 shares. Use of Proceeds: For the construction of new restaurants and to provide working capital. THE COMPANY Hotch Pot, Inc. operates a chain of 140 fast-food outlets in Illinois, Pennsylvania, and Ohio. These restaurants specialize in offering an unusual combination of foreign dishes. The Company was organized in Delaware in 1990. USE OF PROCEEDS The Company intends to use the net proceeds from the sale of 500,000 shares of Com- mon Stock offered hereby, estimated at approximately $5 million, to open new outlets in midwest states and to provide additional working capital. It has no immediate plans to use any of the net proceeds of the offering for any other specific investment. DIVIDEND POLICY The company has not paid cash dividends on its Common Stock and does not anticipate that dividends will be paid on the Common Stock in the foreseeable future. CERTAIN FACTORS Investment in the Common Stock involves a high degree of risk. The following factors should be carefully considered in evaluating the Company: Substantial Capital Needs. The Company will require additional financing to continue its expansion policy. The Company believes that its relations with its lenders are good, but there can be no assurance that additional financing will be available in the future. How Corporations Issue Securities 541 The Company is in competition with a number of restaurant chains Competition. supplying fast food. Many of these companies are substantially larger and better capi- talized than the Company. CAPITALIZATION The following table sets forth the capitalization of the Company as of December 31, 1999, and as adjusted to reflect the sale of 500,000 shares of Common Stock by the Company. Long-term debt Stockholders’ equity Common stock –$.01 par value, 3,000,000 shares outstanding, 3,500,000 shares outstanding, as adjusted Paid-in capital Retained earnings Total stockholders’ equity Total capitalization Actual As Adjusted (in thousands) $ — 30 $ — 35 1,970 3,200 5,200 $5,200 7,315 3,200 10,550 $10,550 SELECTED FINANCIAL DATA [The Prospectus typically includes a summary income statement and balance sheet.] MANAGEMENT’S ANALYSIS OF RESULTS OF OPERATIONS AND FINANCIAL CONDITION Revenue growth for the year ended December 31, 1999, resulted from the opening of ten new restaurants in the Company’s existing geographic area and from sales of a new range of desserts, notably crepe suzette with custard. Sales per customer increased by 20% and this contributed to the improvement in margins. During the year the Company borrowed $600,000 from its banks at an interest rate of 2% above the prime rate. BUSINESS Hotch Pot, Inc. operates a chain of 140 fast-food outlets in Illinois, Pennsylvania, and Ohio. These restaurants specialize in offering an unusual combination of foreign dishes. 50% of company’s revenues derived from sales of two dishes, sushi and sauerkraut and
Brealey
curry bolognese. All dishes are prepared in three regional centers and then frozen and distributed to the individual restaurants. MANAGEMENT The following table sets forth information regarding the Company’s directors, executive officers, and key employees: 542 SECTION FIVE Name Age Position Emma Lucullus Ed Lucullus 28 33 President, Chief Executive Officer, & Director Treasurer & Director Emma Lucullus Emma Lucullus established the Company in 1990 and has been its Chief Executive Officer since that date. Ed Lucullus Ed Lucullus has been employed by the Company since 1990. EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION The following table sets forth the cash compensation paid for services rendered for the year 1999 by the executive officers: Name Capacity Cash Compensation Emma Lucullus Ed Lucullus President and Chief Executive Officer Treasurer $130,000 $ 95,000 CERTAIN TRANSACTIONS At various times between 1990 and 1999 First Cookham Venture Partners invested a total of $1.5 million in the Company. In connection with this investment, First Cookham Venture Partners was granted certain rights to registration under the Securities Act of 1933, including the right to have their shares of Common Stock registered at the Com- pany’s expense with the Securities and Exchange Commission. PRINCIPAL AND SELLING STOCKHOLDERS The following table sets forth certain information regarding the beneficial ownership of the Company’s voting Common Stock as of the date of this prospectus by (i) each per- son known by the Company to be the beneficial owner of more than 5% of its voting Common Stock, and (ii) each director of the Company who beneficially owns voting Common Stock. Unless otherwise indicated, each owner has sole voting and dispositive power over his shares. Name of Beneficial Owner Emma Lucullus Ed Lucullus First Cookham Venture Partners Hermione Kraft Shares Beneficially Owned prior to Offering Number Percent 400,000 400,000 1,700,000 200,000 13.3 13.3 66.7 6.7 Shares to Be Sold 25,000 25,000 250,000 — Shares Beneficially Owned after Offering Number Percent 375,000 375,000 1,450,000 200,000 12.9 12.9 50.0 6.9 DESCRIPTION OF CAPITAL STOCK The Company’s authorized capital stock consists of 10,000,000 shares of voting Com- mon Stock. How Corporations Issue Securities 543 As of the date of this Prospectus, there are 4 holders of record of the Common Stock. Under the terms of one of the Company’s loan agreements, the Company may not pay cash dividends on Common Stock except from net profits without the written consent of the lender. UNDERWRITING Subject to the terms and conditions set forth in the Underwriting Agreement, the Un- derwriter, Silverman Pinch Inc., has agreed to purchase from the Company and the Sell- ing Stockholders 800,000 shares of Common Stock. There is no public market for the Common Stock. The price to the public for the Com- mon Stock was determined by negotiation between the Company and the Underwriter and was based on, among other things, the Company’s financial and operating history and condition, its prospects, and the prospects for its industry in general, the manage- ment of the Company, and the market prices of securities for companies in businesses similar to that of the Company. LEGAL MATTERS The validity of the shares of Common Stock offered by the Prospectus is being passed on for the Company by Blair, Kohl, and Chirac and for the Underwriter by Chretien Howard. LEGAL PROCEEDINGS Hotch Pot was served in January 2000 with a summons and complaint in an action commenced by a customer who alleges that consumption of the Company’s products caused severe nausea and loss of feeling in both feet. The Company believes that the complaint is without foundation. EXPERTS The consolidated financial statements of the Company have been so included in re- liance on the reports of Hooper Firebrand, independent accountants, given on the au- thority of that firm as experts in auditing and accounting. FINANCIAL STATEMENTS [Text and tables omitted.] Appendix B Leasing Leverage and Capital Structure LEASING 547 548 APPENDIX B
Brealey
OPERATING LEASE Usually a shorter-term lease under which the lessor is responsible for insurance, taxes, and upkeep. May be cancelable by the lessee on short notice. LEASING VERSUS BUYING As far as the lessee is concerned, it is the use of the asset that is important, not neces- sarily who has title to it. One way to obtain the use of an asset is to lease it. Another way is to obtain outside financing and buy it. Thus, the decision to lease or buy amounts to a comparison of alternative financing arrangements for the use of an asset. Figure B.1 compares leasing and buying. The lessee, Sass Company, might be a hos- pital, a law firm, or any other firm that uses computers. The lessor is an independent leasing company that purchased the computer from a manufacturer such as Hewlett- Packard (HP). Leases of this type, in which the leasing company purchases the asset from the manufacturer, are called direct leases. Of course, HP might choose to lease its own computers, and many companies, including HP and some of the other companies mentioned previously, have set up wholly owned subsidiaries called captive finance companies to lease out their products.1 As shown in Figure B.1, whether it leases or buys, Sass Company ends up using the asset. The key difference is that in one case (buy), Sass arranges the financing, purchases the asset, and holds title to the asset. In the other case (lease), the leasing company arranges the financing, purchases the asset, and holds title to the asset. OPERATING LEASES Years ago, a lease in which the lessee received an equipment operator along with the equipment was called an operating lease. Today, an operating lease (or service lease) is difficult to define precisely, but this form of leasing has several important character- istics. First of all, with an operating lease, the payments received by the lessor are usually not enough to allow the lessor to fully recover the cost of the asset. A primary reason is that operating leases are often relatively short-term. Therefore, the life of the lease may be much shorter than the economic life of the asset. For example, if you lease a car for two years, the car will have a substantial residual value at the end of the lease, and the lease payments you make will pay off only a fraction of the original cost of the car. The lessor in an operating lease expects to either lease the asset again or sell it when the lease terminates. A second characteristic of an operating lease is that it frequently requires that the les- sor maintain the asset. The lessor may also be responsible for any taxes or insurance. Of course, these costs will be passed on, at least in part, to the lessee in the form of higher lease payments. The third, and perhaps most interesting, feature of an operating lease is the cancela- tion option. This option can give the lessee the right to cancel the lease before the ex- piration date. If the option to cancel is exercised, the lessee returns the equipment to the lessor and ceases to make payments. The value of a cancelation clause depends on whether technological and/or economic conditions are likely to make the value of the asset to the lessee less than the present value of the future lease payments under the lease. To leasing practitioners, these three characteristics define an operating lease. How- ever, as we will see shortly, accountants use the term in a somewhat different way. 1 In addition to arranging financing for asset users, captive finance companies (or subsidiaries) may purchase their parent company’s accounts receivable. General Motors Acceptance Corporation (GMAC) and General Electric (GE) Capital are examples of captive finance companies. Leasing 549 FIGURE B.1 Leasing vs. Buying Buy Lease Sass Co. buys asset and uses asset; financing raised by debt Sass Co. leases asset from lessor; lessor owns asset Manufacturer of asset Manufacturer of asset Sass Co. arranges financing and buys asset from manufacturer Lessor arranges financing and buys asset Sass Co.
Brealey
1. Uses asset 2. Owns asset Lessor 1. Owns asset 2. Does not use asset Lessee (Sass Co.) 1. Uses asset 2. Does not own asset Sass Co. leases asset from lessor If Sass Co. buys the asset, then it will own the asset and use it. If Sass Co. leases the asset, the lessor will own the asset, but Sass Co. will still use it as the lessee. If Sass Co. buys the asset, then it will own the asset and use it. If Sass Co. leases the asset, the lessor will own the asset, but Sass Co. will still use it as the lessee. FINANCIAL LEASE Typically a longer-term, fully amortized lease under which the lessee is responsible for main-tenance, taxes, and insurance. Usually not cancelable by the lessee without penalty. TAX-ORIENTED LEASE A financial lease in which the lessor is the owner for tax purposes. Also called a true lease or a tax lease. FINANCIAL LEASES A financial lease is the other major type of lease. In contrast to the situation with an operating lease, the payments made under a financial lease (plus the anticipated resid- ual, or salvage, value) are usually sufficient to fully cover the lessor’s cost of purchas- ing the asset and pay the lessor a return on the investment. For this reason, a financial lease is sometimes said to be a fully amortized or full-payout lease, whereas an operat- ing lease is said to be partially amortized. Financial leases are often called capital leases by the accountants. With a financial lease, the lessee (not the lessor) is usually responsible for insurance, maintenance, and taxes. It is also important to note that a financial lease generally can- not be canceled, at least not without a significant penalty. In other words, the lessee must make the lease payments or face possible legal action. The characteristics of a financial lease, particularly the fact that it is fully amortized, make it very similar to debt financing, so the name is a sensible one. There are three types of financial leases that are of particular interest: tax-oriented leases, leveraged leases, and sale and leaseback agreements. We consider these next. Tax-Oriented Leases A lease in which the lessor is the owner of the leased asset for tax purposes is called a tax-oriented lease. Such leases are also called tax leases or true leases. In contrast, a conditional sales agreement lease is not a true lease. Here, the “lessee” is the owner for tax purposes. Conditional sales agreement leases are really just secured loans. The fi- nancial leases we discuss in this material are all tax leases. Tax-oriented leases make the most sense when the lessee is not in a position to use tax credits or depreciation deductions that come with owning the asset. By arranging for someone else to hold title, a tax lease passes these benefits on. The lessee can ben- 550 APPENDIX B LEVERAGED LEASE A financial lease in which the lessor borrows a substantial fraction of the cost of the leased asset on a nonrecourse basis. SALE AND LEASEBACK A financial lease in which the lessee sells an asset to the lessor and then leases it back. efit because the lessor may return a portion of the tax benefits to the lessee in the form of lower lease costs. Leveraged Leases A leveraged lease is a tax-oriented lease in which the lessor borrows a substantial por- tion of the purchase price of the leased asset on a nonrecourse basis, meaning that if the lessee stops making the lease payments, the lessor does not have to keep making the loan payments. Instead, the lender must proceed against the lessee to recover its invest- ment. In contrast, with a single-investor lease, if the lessor borrows to purchase the asset, the lessor remains responsible for the loan payments regardless of whether or not the lessee makes the lease payments. Sale and Leaseback Agreements A sale and leaseback occurs when a company sells an asset it owns to another party and immediately leases it back. In a sale and leaseback, two things happen: 1. The lessee receives cash from the sale of the asset. 2. The lessee continues to use the asset.
Brealey
Often, with a sale and leaseback, the lessee may have the option to repurchase the leased asset at the end of the lease. An example of a sale and leaseback occurred in July 1985 when the city of Oakland, California, used the proceeds from the sale of its city hall and 23 other buildings to help meet the liabilities of its $150 million Police and Retirement System, which was un- derfunded by about $60 million. As part of the same transaction, Oakland leased back the buildings to provide for their continued use. A little more recently, in March 1998, cash-strapped Korean Airlines announced plans to sell 14 of its aircraft and then lease them back from the purchaser. Although the purchaser was not revealed, it was widely understood that KAL was working with General Electric Capital Aviation Services, one of the largest lessors specializing in air- craft. Under terms of the deal, KAL would raise about $386 million in badly needed cash without giving up control of its planes. CONCEPT QUESTIONS • What are the differences between an operating lease and a financial lease? • What is a tax-oriented lease? • What is a sale and leaseback agreement? Accounting and Leasing Before November 1976, leasing was frequently called off–balance sheet financing. As the name implies, a firm could arrange to use an asset through a lease and not neces- sarily disclose the existence of the lease contract on the balance sheet. Lessees had to report information on leasing activity only in the footnotes to their financial statements. In November 1976, the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) issued its Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 13 (FASB 13), “Accounting for Leases.” The basic idea of FASB 13 is that certain financial leases must be “capital- Leasing 551 ized.” Essentially, this requirement means that the present value of the lease payments must be calculated and reported along with debt and other liabilities on the right-hand side of the lessee’s balance sheet. The same amount must be shown as the capitalized value of leased assets on the left-hand side of the balance sheet. Operating leases are not disclosed on the balance sheet. Exactly what constitutes a financial or operating lease for accounting purposes will be discussed in just a moment. The accounting implications of FASB 13 are illustrated in Table B.1. Imagine a firm that has $100,000 in assets and no debt, which implies that the equity is also $100,000. The firm needs a truck costing $100,000 (it’s a big truck) that it can lease or buy. The top of the table shows the balance sheet assuming that the firm borrows the money and buys the truck. If the firm leases the truck, then one of two things will happen. If the lease is an op- erating lease, then the balance sheet will look like the one in Part B of the table. In this case, neither the asset (the truck) nor the liability (the present value of the lease pay- ments) appears. If the lease is a capital lease, then the balance sheet will look more like the one in Part C of the table, where the truck is shown as an asset and the present value of the lease payments is shown as a liability.2 As we discussed earlier, it is difficult, if not impossible, to give a precise definition of what constitutes a financial lease or an operating lease. For accounting purposes, a lease is declared to be a capital lease, and must therefore be disclosed on the balance sheet, if at least one of the following criteria is met: 1. The lease transfers ownership of the property to the lessee by the end of the term of the lease. TABLE B.1 Leasing and the balance sheet A. Balance Sheet with Purchase (the company finances a $100,000 truck with debt) $100,000 Truck $100,000 Other assets $200,000 Debt Equity Total assets Total debt plus equity B. Balance Sheet with Operating Lease (the company finances the truck with an operating lease) Truck Other assets $000,000 $100,000 Debt Equity Total assets $100,000 Total debt plus equity C. Balance Sheet with Capital Lease (the company finances the truck with a capital lease) $100,000 $100,000 $200,000 $000,000 $100,000 $100,000
Brealey
Assets under capital lease Other assets Total assets $100,000 $100,000 $200,000 Obligations under capital lease Equity Total debt plus $100,000 $100,000 $200,000 In the first case, a $100,000 truck is purchased with debt. In the second case, an operating lease is used; no balance sheet entries are created. In the third case, a capital (financial) lease is used; the lease payments are capitalized as a liability, and the leased truck appears as an asset. 2 We have made the simplifying assumption that the present value of the lease payments under the capital lease is equal to the cost of the truck. In general, it is the present value of the payments that must be reported, not the cost of the asset. 552 APPENDIX B 2. The lessee can purchase the asset at a price below fair market value (bargain pur- chase price option) when the lease expires. 3. The lease term is 75 percent or more of the estimated economic life of the asset. 4. The present value of the lease payments is at least 90 percent of the fair market value of the asset at the start of the lease. If one or more of the four criteria are met, the lease is a capital lease; otherwise, it is an operating lease for accounting purposes. A firm might be tempted to try and “cook the books” by taking advantage of the somewhat arbitrary distinction between operating leases and capital leases. Suppose a trucking firm wants to lease a $100,000 truck. The truck is expected to last for 15 years. A (perhaps unethical) financial manager could try to negotiate a lease contract for 10 years with lease payments having a present value of $89,000. These terms would get around Criteria 3 and 4. If Criteria 1 and 2 were similarly circumvented, the arrange- ment would be an operating lease and would not show up on the balance sheet. There are several alleged benefits from “hiding” financial leases. One of the advan- tages of keeping leases off the balance sheet has to do with fooling financial analysts, creditors, and investors. The idea is that if leases are not on the balance sheet, they will not be noticed. Financial managers who devote substantial effort to keeping leases off the balance sheet are probably wasting time. Of course, if leases are not on the balance sheet, tra- ditional measures of financial leverage, such as the ratio of total debt to total assets, will understate the true degree of financial leverage. As a consequence, the balance sheet will appear “stronger” than it really is. But it seems unlikely that this type of manipu- lation would mislead many people. CONCEPT QUESTIONS • For accounting purposes, what constitutes a capital lease? • How are capital leases reported? Taxes, the IRS and Leases The lessee can deduct lease payments for income tax purposes if the lease is deemed to be a true lease by the Internal Revenue Service. The tax shields associated with lease payments are critical to the economic viability of a lease, so IRS guidelines are an im- portant consideration. Essentially, the IRS requires that a lease be primarily for business purposes and not merely for purposes of tax avoidance. In broad terms, a lease that is valid from the IRS’s perspective will meet the follow- ing standards: 1. The term of the lease must be less than 80 percent of the economic life of the asset. If the term is greater than this, the transaction will be regarded as a conditional sale. 2. The lease should not include an option to acquire the asset at the end of the lease term at a price below the asset’s then–fair market value. This type of bargain option would give the lessee the asset’s residual scrap value, implying an equity interest. 3. The lease should not have a schedule of payments that are very high at the start of Leasing 553 the lease term and thereafter very low. If the lease requires early “balloon” pay- ments, this will be considered evidence that the lease is being used to avoid taxes and not for a legitimate business purpose. The IRS may require an adjustment in the payments for tax purposes in such cases. 4. The lease payments must provide the lessor with a fair market rate of return. The
Brealey
profit potential of the lease to the lessor should be apart from the deal’s tax benefits. 5. Renewal options must be reasonable and reflect the fair market value of the asset at the time of renewal. This requirement can be met by, for example, granting the les- see the first option to meet a competing outside offer. The IRS is concerned about lease contracts because leases sometimes appear to be set up solely to defer taxes. To see how this could happen, suppose that a firm plans to purchase a $1 million bus that has a five-year life for depreciation purposes. Assume that straight-line depreciation to a zero salvage value is used. The depreciation expense would be $200,000 per year. Now suppose the firm can lease the bus for $500,000 per year for two years and buy the bus for $1 at the end of the two-year term. The present value of the tax benefits is clearly less if the bus is bought than if the bus is leased. The speedup of lease payments greatly benefits the firm and basically gives it a form of ac- celerated depreciation. In this case, the IRS might decide that the primary purpose of the lease was to defer taxes. CONCEPT QUESTIONS • Why is the IRS concerned about leasing? • What are some of the standards the IRS uses in evaluating a lease? The Cash Flows from Leasing To begin our analysis of the leasing decision, we need to identify the relevant cash flows. The first part of this section illustrates how this is done. A key point, and one to watch for, is that taxes are a very important consideration in a lease analysis. THE INCREMENTAL CASH FLOWS Consider the decision confronting the Tasha Corporation, which manufactures pipe. Business has been expanding, and Tasha currently has a five-year backlog of pipe or- ders for the Trans-Missouri Pipeline. The International Boring Machine Corporation (IBMC) makes a pipe-boring ma- chine that can be purchased for $10,000. Tasha has determined that it needs a new ma- chine, and the IBMC model will save Tasha $6,000 per year in reduced electricity bills for the next five years. Tasha has a corporate tax rate of 34 percent. For simplicity, we assume that five-year straight-line depreciation will be used for the pipe-boring machine, and, after five years, the machine will be worthless. Johnson Leasing Corporation has offered to lease the same pipe-boring machine to Tasha for lease payments of $2,500 paid at the end of each of the next five years. With the lease, Tasha would remain responsible for maintenance, insurance, and operating expenses.3 3 We have assumed that all lease payments are made in arrears, that is, at the end of the year. Actually, many leases require payments to be made at the beginning of the year. 554 APPENDIX B TABLE B.2 Incremental cash flows for Tasha Corp. from leasing instead of buying Susan Smart has been asked to compare the direct incremental cash flows from leas- ing the IBMC machine to the cash flows associated with buying it. The first thing she realizes is that, because Tasha will get the machine either way, the $6,000 savings will be realized whether the machine is leased or purchased. Thus, this cost savings, and any other operating costs or revenues, can be ignored in the analysis. Upon reflection, Ms. Smart concludes that there are only three important cash flow differences between leasing and buying:4 1. If the machine is leased, Tasha must make a lease payment of $2,500 each year. However, lease payments are fully tax deductible, so the aftertax lease payment would be $2,500 (cid:3) (1 (cid:2) .34) (cid:4) $1,650. This is a cost of leasing instead of buying. 2. If the machine is leased, Tasha does not own it and cannot depreciate it for tax pur- poses. The depreciation would be $10,000/5 (cid:4) $2,000 per year. A $2,000 deprecia- tion deduction generates a tax shield of $2,000 (cid:3) .34 (cid:4) $680 per year. Tasha loses this valuable tax shield if it leases, so this is a cost of leasing. 3. If the machine is leased, Tasha does not have to spend $10,000 today to buy it. This
Brealey
is a benefit from leasing. The cash flows from leasing instead of buying are summarized in Table B.2. Notice that the cost of the machine shows up with a positive sign in Year 0. This is a reflection of the fact that Tasha saves the initial $10,000 equipment cost by leasing instead of buying. A NOTE ON TAXES Susan Smart has assumed that Tasha can use the tax benefits of the depreciation al- lowances and the lease payments. This may not always be the case. If Tasha were los- ing money, it would not pay taxes and the tax shelters would be worthless (unless they could be shifted to someone else). As we mentioned before, this is one circumstance under which leasing may make a great deal of sense. If this were the case, the relevant lines in Table B.2 would have to be changed to reflect a zero tax rate. CONCEPT QUESTIONS • What are the cash flow consequences of leasing instead of buying? • Explain why the $10,000 in Table B.2 has a positive sign. Lease versus Buy Aftertax lease payment Lost depreciation tax shield Cost of machine Total cash flow Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 (cid:2)$1,650 (cid:2)$1,650 (cid:2)$1,650 (cid:2)$1,650 (cid:2)$1,650 (cid:2)$0,680 (cid:2)$0,680 (cid:2)$0,680 (cid:2)$0,680 (cid:2)$0,680 (cid:1)$10,000 (cid:1)$10,000 (cid:2)$2,330 (cid:2)$2,330 (cid:2)$2,330 (cid:2)$2,330 (cid:2)$2,330 4 There is a fourth consequence of leasing that we do not discuss here. If the machine has a nontrivial resid- ual value, then, if we lease, we give up that residual value. This is another cost of leasing instead of buying. Leasing 555 Lease or Buy? Based on our discussion thus far, Ms. Smart’s analysis comes down to this: if Tasha Corp. leases instead of buying, it saves $10,000 today because it avoids having to pay for the machine, but it must give up $2,330 per year for the next five years in exchange. We now must decide whether getting $10,000 today and then paying back $2,330 per year is a good idea. A PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS Suppose Tasha were to borrow $10,000 today and promise to make aftertax payments of $2,330 per year for the next five years. This is essentially what Tasha will be doing if it leases instead of buying. What interest rate would Tasha be paying on this “loan”? Note that we need to find the unknown rate for a five-year annuity with payments of $2,330 per year and a present value of $10,000. It is easy to verify that the rate is 5.317 percent. Suppose Tasha were to borrow $10,000 today and promise to make aftertax pay- ments of $2,330 per year for the next five years. This is essentially what Tasha will be doing if it leases instead of buying. What interest rate would Tasha be paying on this “loan”? Note that we need to find the unknown rate for a five-year annuity with pay- ments of $2,330 per year and a present value of $10,000. It is easy to verify that the rate is 5.317 percent. The cash flows for our hypothetical loan are identical to the cash flows from leasing instead of buying, and what we have illustrated is that when Tasha leases the machine, it effectively arranges financing at an aftertax rate of 5.317 percent. Whether this is a good deal or not depends on what rate Tasha would pay if it simply borrowed the money. For example, suppose Tasha can arrange a five-year loan with its bank at a rate of 7.57575 percent. Should Tasha sign the lease or should it go with the bank? Because Tasha is in a 34 percent tax bracket, the aftertax interest rate would be 7.57575 (cid:4) (1 (cid:2) .34) = 5 percent. This is less than the 5.317 percent implicit aftertax rate on the lease. In this particular case, Tasha would be better off borrowing the money because it would get a better rate. We have seen that Tasha should buy rather than lease. The steps in our analysis can be summarized as follows: 1. Calculate the incremental aftertax cash flows from leasing instead of buying. 2. Use these cash flows to calculate the implicit aftertax interest rate on the lease. 3. Compare this rate to the company’s aftertax borrowing cost and choose the cheaper
Brealey
source of financing. The most important thing to note from our discussion thus far is that in evaluating a lease, the relevant rate for the comparison is the company’s aftertax borrowing rate. The fundamental reason is that the alternative to leasing is long-term borrowing, so the af- tertax interest rate on such borrowing is the relevant benchmark. THREE POTENTIAL PITFALLS There are three potential problems with the implicit rate that we calculated on the lease. First of all, we can interpret this rate as the internal rate of return, or IRR, on the deci- sion to lease rather than buy, but doing so can be confusing. To see why, notice that the 556 APPENDIX B NET ADVANTAGE TO LEASING (NAL) The NPV that is calculated when deciding whether to lease an asset or to buy it. IRR from leasing is 5.317 percent, which is greater than Tasha’s aftertax borrowing cost of 5 percent. Normally, the higher the IRR, the better, but we decided that leasing was a bad idea here. The reason is that the cash flows are not conventional; the first cash flow is positive and the rest are negative, which is just the opposite of the conventional case. With this cash flow pattern, the IRR represents the rate we pay, not the rate we get, so the lower the IRR, the better. A second, and related, potential pitfall has to do with the fact that we calculated the advantage of leasing instead of buying. We could have done just the opposite and come up with the advantage of buying instead of leasing. If we did this, the cash flows would be the same, but the signs would be reversed. The IRR would be the same. Now, how- ever, the cash flows would be conventional, so we could interpret the 5.317 percent IRR as saying that borrowing and buying is better. The third potential problem is that our implicit rate is based on the net cash flows of leasing instead of buying. There is another rate that is sometimes calculated, which is based solely on the lease payments. If we wanted to, we could note that the lease pro- vides $10,000 in financing and requires five payments of $2,500 each. It would be tempting to then determine an implicit rate based on these numbers, but the resulting rate would not be meaningful for making lease versus buy decisions, and it should not be confused with the implicit return on leasing instead of borrowing and buying. Perhaps because of these potential sources of confusion, the IRR approach we have outlined thus far is not as widely used as the NPV-based approach that we describe next. NPV ANALYSIS Now that we know that the relevant rate for evaluating a lease versus buy decision is the firm’s aftertax borrowing cost, an NPV analysis is straightforward. We simply discount the cash flows back to the present at Tasha’s aftertax borrowing rate of 5 percent as fol- lows: NPV (cid:4) $10,000 (cid:2) 2,330 (cid:3) (1 (cid:2) 1/1.055)/.05 (cid:4) (cid:2)$87.68 The NPV from leasing instead of buying is 2$87.68, verifying our earlier conclusion that leasing is a bad idea. Once again, notice the signs of the cash flows; the first is pos- itive, the rest are negative. The NPV we have computed here is often called the net ad- vantage to leasing (NAL). Surveys indicate that the NAL approach is the most popu- lar means of lease analysis in the real world. A MISCONCEPTION In our lease versus buy analysis, it looks as though we ignored the fact that if Tasha bor- rows the $10,000 to buy the machine, it will have to repay the money with interest. In fact, we reasoned that if Tasha leased the machine, it would be better off by $10,000 today because it wouldn’t have to pay for the machine. It is tempting to argue that if Tasha borrowed the money, it wouldn’t have to come up with the $10,000. Instead, Tasha would make a series of principal and interest payments over the next five years. This observation is true, but not particularly relevant. The reason is that if Tasha bor- rows $10,000 at an aftertax cost of 5 percent, the present value of the aftertax loan pay- ments is simply $10,000, no matter what the repayment schedule is (assuming that the
Brealey
Leasing 557 loan is fully amortized). Thus, we could write down the aftertax loan repayments and work with these, but it would just be extra work for no gain. LEASE EVALUATION In our Tasha Corp. example, suppose Tasha is able to negotiate a lease payment of $2,000 per year. What would be the NPV of the lease in this case? With this new lease payment, the aftertax lease payment would be $2,000 (cid:3) (1 (cid:2) .34) (cid:4) $1,320, which is $1,650 (cid:2) 1,320 (cid:4) $330 less than before. Referring back to Table B.2, note that the aftertax cash flows would be (cid:2)$2,000 instead of (cid:2)$2,330. At 5 percent, the NPV would be: NPV (cid:4) $10,000 (cid:2) 2,000 (cid:3) (1 (cid:2) 1/1.055)/.05 (cid:4) (cid:2)$1341.05 Thus, the lease is very attractive. CONCEPT QUESTIONS • What is the relevant discount rate for evaluating whether or not to lease an asset? Why? • Explain how to go about a lease versus buy analysis. LEVERAGE AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE 559 560 APPENDIX B The Capital Structure Question How should a firm go about choosing its debt-equity ratio? Here, as always, we assume that the guiding principle is to choose the course of action that maximizes the value of a share of stock. However, when it comes to capital structure decisions, this is essen- tially the same thing as maximizing the value of the whole firm, and, for convenience, we will tend to frame our discussion in terms of firm value. The WACC (Weighted Average Cost of Capital) tells us that the firm’s overall cost of capital is a weighted average of the costs of the various components of the firm’s cap- ital structure. When we described the WACC, we took the firm’s capital structure as given. Thus, one important issue that we will want to explore is what happens to the cost of capital when we vary the amount of debt financing, or the debt-equity ratio. A primary reason for studying the WACC is that the value of the firm is maximized when the WACC is minimized. The WACC is the discount rate appropriate for the firm’s overall cash flows. Since values and discount rates move in opposite directions, mini- mizing the WACC will maximize the value of the firm’s cash flows. Thus, we will want to choose the firm’s capital structure so that the WACC is mini- mized. For this reason, we will say that one capital structure is better than another if it results in a lower weighted average cost of capital. Further, we say that a particular debt- equity ratio represents the optimal capital structure if it results in the lowest possible WACC. This optimal capital structure is sometimes called the firm’s target capital structure as well. CONCEPT QUESTIONS • What is the relationship between the WACC and the value of the firm? • What is an optimal capital structure? The Effect of Financial Leverage In this section, we examine the impact of financial leverage on the payoffs to stock- holders. As you may recall, financial leverage refers to the extent to which a firm relies on debt. The more debt financing a firm uses in its capital structure, the more financial leverage it employs. As we describe, financial leverage can dramatically alter the payoffs to shareholders in the firm. Remarkably, however, financial leverage may not affect the overall cost of capital. If this is true, then a firm’s capital structure is irrelevant because changes in cap- ital structure won’t affect the value of the firm. THE IMPACT OF FINANCIAL LEVERAGE We start by illustrating how financial leverage works. For now, we ignore the impact of taxes. Also, for ease of presentation, we describe the impact of leverage in terms of its effects on earnings per share, EPS, and return on equity, ROE. These are, of course, ac- counting numbers and, as such, are not our primary concern. Using cash flows instead of these accounting numbers would lead to precisely the same conclusions, but a little more work would be needed. Leverage and Capital Structure 561 TABLE B.3 Current and proposed capital structures for the Trans Am Corporation Assets Debt Equity
Brealey
Debt-equity ratio Share price Current Proposed $8,000,000 $0 $8,000,000 0 $20 $8,000,000 $4,000,000 $4,000,000 1 $20 Shares outstanding 400,000 200,000 Interest rate 10 % 10 % Financial Leverage, EPS, and ROE: An Example The Trans Am Corporation currently has no debt in its capital structure. The CFO, Ms. Morris, is considering a restructuring that would involve issuing debt and using the pro- ceeds to buy back some of the outstanding equity. Table B.3 presents both the current and proposed capital structures. As shown, the firm’s assets have a market value of $8 million, and there are 400,000 shares outstanding. Because Trans Am is an all-equity firm, the price per share is $20. The proposed debt issue would raise $4 million; the interest rate would be 10 per- cent. Since the stock sells for $20 per share, the $4 million in new debt would be used to purchase $4 million/20 (cid:4) 200,000 shares, leaving 200,000 outstanding. After the re- structuring, Trans Am would have a capital structure that was 50 percent debt, so the debt-equity ratio would be 1. Notice that, for now, we assume that the stock price will remain at $20. To investigate the impact of the proposed restructuring, Ms. Morris has prepared Table B.4, which compares the firm’s current capital structure to the proposed capital structure under three scenarios. The scenarios reflect different assumptions about the firm’s EBIT. Under the expected scenario, the EBIT is $1 million. In the recession sce- nario, EBIT falls to $500,000. In the expansion scenario, it rises to $1.5 million. To illustrate some of the calculations in Table B.4, consider the expansion case. EBIT is $1.5 million. With no debt (the current capital structure) and no taxes, net in- come is also $1.5 million. In this case, there are 400,000 shares worth $8 million total. EPS is therefore $1.5 million/400,000 (cid:4) $3.75 per share. Also, since accounting return on equity, ROE, is net income divided by total equity, ROE is $1.5 million/8 million (cid:4) 18.75%. With $4 million in debt (the proposed capital structure), things are somewhat differ- ent. Since the interest rate is 10 percent, the interest bill is $400,000. With EBIT of $1.5 million, interest of $400,000, and no taxes, net income is $1.1 million. Now there are only 200,000 shares worth $4 million total. EPS is therefore $1.1 million/200,000 (cid:4) $5.5 per share versus the $3.75 per share that we calculated above. Furthermore, ROE is $1.1 million/4 million (cid:4) 27.5%. This is well above the 18.75 percent we calculated for the current capital structure. EPS versus EBIT The impact of leverage is evident in Table B.4 when the effect of the restructuring on EPS and ROE is examined. In particular, the variability in both EPS and ROE is much larger under the proposed capital structure. This illustrates how financial leverage acts to magnify gains and losses to shareholders. In Figure B.3, we take a closer look at the effect of the proposed restructuring. This figure plots earnings per share, EPS, against earnings before interest and taxes, EBIT, 562 APPENDIX B TABLE B.4 Capital structure scenarios for the Trans Am Corporation Current Capital Structure: No Debt Recession $500,000 0 $500,000 6.25 % $1.25 Expected $1,000,000 0 $1,000,000 12.50 % $2.50 Proposed Capital Structure: Debt (cid:4) $4 million Recession $500,000 400,000 $100,000 2.50 % $.50 Expected $1,000,000 400,000 $ 600,000 15.00 % $3.00 Expansion $1,500,000 0 $1,500,000 18.75% $3.75 Expansion $1,500,000 400,000 $1,100,000 27.50 % $5.50 EBIT Interest Net income ROE EPS EBIT Interest Net income ROE EPS for the current and proposed capital structures. The first line, labeled “No debt,” repre- sents the case of no leverage. This line begins at the origin, indicating that EPS would be zero if EBIT were zero. From there, every $400,000 increase in EBIT increases EPS by $1 (because there are 400,000 shares outstanding). The second line represents the proposed capital structure. Here, EPS is negative if EBIT is zero. This follows because $400,000 of interest must be paid regardless of the
Brealey
firm’s profits. Since there are 200,000 shares in this case, the EPS is –$2 per share as shown. Similarly, if EBIT were $400,000, EPS would be exactly zero. The important thing to notice in Figure B.2 is that the slope of the line in this sec- ond case is steeper. In fact, for every $400,000 increase in EBIT, EPS rises by $2, so the line is twice as steep. This tells us that EPS is twice as sensitive to changes in EBIT because of the financial leverage employed. Another observation to make in Figure B.2 is that the lines intersect. At that point, EPS is exactly the same for both capital structures. To find this point, note that EPS is equal to EBIT/400,000 in the no-debt case. In the with-debt case, EPS is (EBIT – $400,000)/200,000. If we set these equal to each other, EBIT is: EBIT/400,000 (cid:4) (EBIT – $400,000)/200,000 EBIT (cid:4) 2 (cid:3) (EBIT – $400,000) EBIT (cid:4) $800,000 When EBIT is $800,000, EPS is $2 per share under either capital structure. This is labeled as the break-even point in Figure B.2; we could also call it the indifference point. If EBIT is above this level, leverage is beneficial; if it is below this point, it is not. There is another, more intuitive, way of seeing why the break-even point is $800,000. Notice that, if the firm has no debt and its EBIT is $800,000, its net income is also $800,000. In this case, the ROE is $800,000/8,000,000 (cid:4) 10%. This is precisely the same as the interest rate on the debt, so the firm earns a return that is just sufficient to pay the interest. EXAMPLE: BREAK-EVEN EBIT The MPD Corporation has decided in favor of a capital restructuring. Currently, MPD uses no debt financing. Following the restructuring, however, debt will be $1 million. Leverage and Capital Structure 563 FIGURE B.2 Financial leverage: EPS and EBIT for the Trans Am Corporation Earnings per share ($) With debt No debt Advantage to debt Break-even point Disadvantage to debt 400,000 800,000 1,200,000 Earnings before interest and taxes ($) 4 3 2 1 0 –1 –2 The interest rate on the debt will be 9 percent. MPD currently has 200,000 shares out- standing, and the price per share is $20. If the restructuring is expected to increase EPS, what is the minimum level for EBIT that MPD’s management must be expecting? Ig- nore taxes in answering. To answer, we calculate the break-even EBIT. At any EBIT above this the increased fi- nancial leverage will increase EPS, so this will tell us the minimum level for EBIT. Under the old capital structure, EPS is simply EBIT/200,000. Under the new capital structure, the interest expense will be $1 million (cid:3) .09 (cid:4) $90,000. Furthermore, with the $1 million proceeds, MPD will repurchase $1 million/20 (cid:4) 50,000 shares of stock, leaving 150,000 outstanding. EPS is thus (EBIT – $90,000)/150,000. Now that we know how to calculate EPS under both scenarios, we set them equal to each other and solve for the break-even EBIT: EBIT/200,000 (cid:4) (EBIT – $90,000)/150,000 EBIT (cid:4) (4/3) (cid:3) (EBIT – $90,000) EBIT (cid:4) $360,000 Verify that, in either case, EPS is $1.80 when EBIT is $360,000. Management at MPD is apparently of the opinion that EPS will exceed $1.80. Section 6 Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control International Financial Management MERGERS, ACQUISITIONS, AND CORPORATE CONTROL The Market for Corporate Control Method 1: Proxy Contests Method 2: Mergers and Acquisitions Method 3: Leveraged Buyouts Method 4: Divestitures and Spin-offs Sensible Motives for Mergers Economies of Scale Economies of Vertical Integration Combining Complementary Resources Mergers as a Use for Surplus Funds Dubious Reasons for Mergers Diversification The Bootstrap Game Evaluating Mergers Mergers Financed by Cash Mergers Financed by Stock A Warning Another Warning Merger Tactics Who Gets the Gains? Leveraged Buyouts Barbarians at the Gate? Mergers and the Economy Merger Waves Do Mergers Generate Net Benefits? Summary A merger is consummated. These two managers are clearly delighted, but why do companies decide to merge?
Brealey
Reuters/Peter Morgan/Archive Photos 567 I n recent years the scale and pace of merger activity have been remark- able. For example, Table 6.1 lists just a few of the important mergers of 1998 and 1999. Notice that the United States does not have a monopoly on merger activity. In recent years many of the largest mergers have involved European firms. The mergers listed in Table 6.1 involved big money. During periods of intense merger activity financial managers spend considerable time either searching for firms to acquire or worrying whether some other firm is about to take over their company. When one company buys another, it is making an investment, and the basic princi- ples of capital investment decisions apply. You should go ahead with the purchase if it makes a net contribution to shareholders’ wealth. But mergers are often awkward trans- actions to evaluate, and you have to be careful to define benefits and costs properly. Many mergers are arranged amicably, but in other cases one firm will make a hos- tile takeover bid for the other. We describe the principal techniques of modern merger warfare, and since the threat of hostile takeovers has stimulated corporate restructurings and leveraged buyouts (LBOs), we describe them too, and attempt to explain why these deals have generated rewards for investors. We close with a look at who gains and loses from mergers and we discuss whether mergers are beneficial on balance. After studying this material you should be able to (cid:1) Describe ways that companies change their ownership or management. (cid:1) Explain why it may make sense for companies to merge. (cid:1) Estimate the gains and costs of mergers to the acquiring firm. (cid:1) Describe takeover defenses. (cid:1) Summarize the evidence on whether mergers increase efficiency and on how the gains from mergers are distributed between shareholders of the acquired and acquiring firms. (cid:1) Explain some of the motivations for leveraged and management buyouts of the firm. Year 1999 1999 1999 1999 1999 1999 1999 1999 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 1998 Buying Company Selling Company Payment, Billions of Dollars MCI WorldCom Viacom AT&T Travelers Group Exxon TotalFina (France) Olivetti (Italy) Vodafone (UK) British Petroleum (UK) Daimler-Benz (Germany) Zeneca (UK) Nationsbank Corp. WorldCom Inc. Norwest Corp. Sprint CBS MediaOne Group Citicorp Mobil Corp. Elf Aquitaine (France) Telecom Italia (Italy) Air Touch Communications Amoco Corp. Chrysler Astra (Sweden) BankAmerica Corp. MCI Communications Wells Fargo & Co. 115 35 54 83 80 55 58 61 48 38 35 62 42 34 TABLE 22.1 Some important recent mergers 568 Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 569 The Market for Corporate Control The shareholders are the owners of the firm. But most shareholders do not feel like the boss, and with good reason. Try buying a share of General Motors stock and marching into the boardroom for a chat with your employee, the chief executive officer. The ownership and management of large corporations are almost always separated. Shareholders do not directly appoint or supervise the firm’s managers. They elect the board of directors, who act as their agents in choosing and monitoring the managers of the firm. Shareholders have a direct say in very few matters. Control of the firm is in the hands of the managers, subject to the general oversight of the board of directors. The separation of ownership and management or control creates potential agency costs. Agency costs occur when managers or directors take actions adverse to share- holders’ interests. The temptation to take such actions may be ever-present, but there are many forces and constraints working to keep managers’ and shareholders’ interests in line. As we pointed out earlier, managers’ paychecks in large corporations are almost always tied to the profitability of the firm and the performance of its shares. Boards of directors take their responsibilities seriously—they may face lawsuits if they don’t—and therefore are reluctant to rubber-stamp obviously bad financial decisions. But what ensures that the board has engaged the most talented managers? What hap-
Brealey
pens if managers are inadequate? What if the board of directors is derelict in monitor- ing the performance of managers? Or what if the firm’s managers are fine, but re- sources of the firm could be used more efficiently by merging with another firm? Can we count on managers to pursue arrangements that would put them out of jobs? These are all questions about the market for corporate control, the mechanisms by which firms are matched up with management teams and owners who can make the most of the firm’s resources. You should not take a firm’s current ownership and man- agement for granted. If it is possible for the value of the firm to be enhanced by chang- ing management or by reorganizing under new owners, there will be incentives for someone to make a change. There are four ways to change the management of a firm. These are (1) a successful proxy contest in which a group of stockholders votes in a new group of directors, who then pick a new management team; (2) the purchase of one firm by another in a merger or acquisition; (3) a leveraged buyout of the firm by a private group of investors; and (4) a divestiture, in which a firm either sells part of its operations to another company or spins it off as an independent firm. We will review briefly each of these methods. METHOD 1: PROXY CONTESTS Shareholders elect the board of directors to keep watch on management and replace un- satisfactory managers. If the board is lax, shareholders are free to elect a different board. In theory this ensures that the corporation is run in the best interests of share- holders. In practice things are not so clear-cut. Ownership in large corporations is widely dis- persed. Usually even the largest single shareholder holds only a small fraction of the 570 SECTION SIX PROXY CONTEST Takeover attempt in which outsiders compete with management for shareholders’ votes. Also called proxy fight. MERGER Combination of two firms into one, with the acquirer assuming assets and liabilities of the target firm. shares. Most shareholders have little notion who is on the board or what the members stand for. Management, on the other hand, deals directly with the board and has a per- sonal relationship with its members. In many corporations, management sits on the committee that nominates candidates for the board. It is not surprising that some boards seem less than aggressive in forcing managers to run a lean, efficient operation and to act primarily in the interests of shareholders. When a group of investors believes that the board and its management team should be replaced, they can launch a proxy contest. A proxy is the right to vote another share- holder’s shares. In a proxy contest, the dissident shareholders attempt to obtain enough proxies to elect their own slate to the board of directors. Once the new board is in con- trol, management can be replaced. A proxy fight is therefore a direct contest for control of the corporation. But most proxy contests fail. Dissidents who engage in such fights must use their own money, while management can use the corporation’s funds and lines of communi- cation with shareholders to defend itself. Such fights can cost millions of dollars.1 Institutional shareholders such as large pension funds have become more aggressive in pressing for managerial accountability. These funds have been able to gain conces- sions from firms without initiating proxy contests. For example, firms have agreed to split the jobs of chief executive officer and chairman of the board of directors. This en- sures that an outsider is responsible for keeping watch over the company. Also, more firms now bar corporate insiders from serving on the committee that nominates candi- dates to the board. Perhaps as a result of shareholder pressure, boards also seem to be getting more aggressive. For example, outside directors were widely credited for has- tening the recent replacement of top management at Coke and British Airwaves. METHOD 2: MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS
Brealey
Proxy contests are rare, and successful ones are rarer still. Poorly performing managers face a greater risk from acquisition. If the management of one firm observes another firm underperforming, it can try to acquire the business and replace the poor managers with its own team. In practice, corporate takeovers are the arenas where contests for cor- porate control are usually fought. There are three ways for one firm to acquire another. One possibility is to merge the two companies into one, in which case the acquiring company assumes all the assets and all the liabilities of the other. Such a merger must have the approval of at least 50 percent of the stockholders of each firm.2 The acquired firm ceases to exist, and its for- mer shareholders receive cash and/or securities in the acquiring firm. In many mergers there is a clear acquiring company, whose management then runs the enlarged firm. However, a merger is often a combination of two equals with both managements hav- ing a major say in the running of the new company. For example, the $330 billion pro- posed merger between Time Warner and AOL is a merger of equals. A second alternative is for the acquiring firm to buy the target firm’s stock in ex- change for cash, shares, or other securities. The acquired firm may continue to exist as a separate entity, but it is now owned by the acquirer. The approval and cooperation of the target firm’s managers are generally sought, but even if they resist, the acquirer can 1 J. H. Mulherin and A. B. Poulsen provide an analysis of proxy fights in “Proxy Contests and Corporate Change: Implications for Shareholder Wealth,” Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998), pp. 279–313. 2 Corporate charters and state laws sometimes specify a higher percentage. TENDER OFFER Takeover attempt in which outsiders directly offer to buy the stock of the firm’s shareholders. ACQUISITION Takeover of a firm by purchase of that firm’s common stock or assets. LEVERAGED BUYOUT (LBO) Acquisition of the firm by a private group using substantial borrowed funds. MANAGEMENT BUYOUT (MBO) Acquisition of the firm by its own management in a leveraged buyout. Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 571 attempt to purchase a majority of the outstanding shares. By offering to buy shares directly from shareholders, the acquiring firm can bypass the target firm’s management altogether. The offer to purchase stock is called a tender offer. If the tender offer is successful, the buyer obtains control and can, if it chooses, toss out incumbent man- agement. The third approach is to buy the target firm’s assets. In this case ownership of the assets needs to be transferred, and payment is made to the selling firm rather than di- rectly to its stockholders. Usually, the target firm sells only some of its assets, but oc- casionally it sells all of them. In this case, the selling firm continues to exist as an in- dependent entity, but it becomes an empty shell—a corporation engaged in no business activity. The terminology of mergers and acquisitions (M&A) can be confusing. These phrases are used loosely to refer to any kind of corporate combination or takeover. But strictly speaking, merger means the combination of all the assets and liabilities of two firms. The purchase of the stock or assets of another firm is an acquisition. METHOD 3: LEVERAGED BUYOUTS Sometimes a group of investors takes over a firm by means of a leveraged buyout, or LBO. The LBO group takes the firm private and its shares no longer trade in the secu- rities markets. Usually a considerable proportion of LBO financing is borrowed, hence the term leveraged buyout. If the investor group is led by the management of the firm, the takeover is called a management buyout, or MBO. In this case, the firm’s managers actually buy the firm from the shareholders and continue to run it. They become owner-managers. We will discuss LBOs and MBOs later. METHOD 4: DIVESTITURES AND SPIN-OFFS Firms not only acquire businesses; they also sell them. Divestitures are part of the mar-
Brealey
ket for corporate control. In recent years the number of divestitures has been about half the number of mergers. Instead of selling a business to another firm, companies may spin off the business by separating it from the parent firm and distributing stock in the newly independent com- pany to the shareholders of the parent company. For example, in 1996, AT&T was split into four separate firms: AT&T continued to operate telecommunication services, Lu- cent took responsibility for telecommunication equipment manufacturing, NCR took on the computer business, and AT&T Capital, which handled leasing, was spun off and sold to another firm. Instead of holding shares in one megafirm, AT&T’s shareholders were given shares in Lucent and NCR as well as AT&T. Investors clearly welcomed this move: when the announcement of the split was made in 1995, AT&T’s shares jumped 11 percent. Probably the most frequent motive for spin-offs is improved efficiency. Companies sometimes refer to a business as being a “poor fit.” By spinning off a poor fit, the man- agement of the parent company can concentrate on its main activity. If each business must stand on its own feet, there is no risk that funds will be siphoned off from one in order to support unprofitable investments in the other. Moreover, if the two parts of the business are independent, it is easy to see the value of each and to reward managers ac- cordingly. 572 SECTION SIX Sensible Motives for Mergers We now look more closely at mergers and acquisitions and consider when they do and do not make sense. Mergers are often categorized as horizontal, vertical, or conglom- erate. A horizontal merger is one that takes place between two firms in the same line of business; the merged firms are former competitors. Most of the mergers around the turn of the twentieth century were of this type. Recent examples of horizontal mergers have occurred in banking, such as the merger between Deutsche Bank and Bankers Trust, and in oil, such as the merger between Exxon and Mobil. A horizontal merger can be blocked if it would be anticompetitive or create too much market power. The Mobil and Exxon merger was challenged, but it was finally con- summated after the two companies agreed to sell a number of service stations to other retailers. During the 1920s, vertical mergers were predominant. A vertical merger is one in which the buyer expands backward toward the source of raw material or forward in the direction of the ultimate consumer. Thus a soft drink manufacturer might buy a sugar producer (expanding backward) or a fast-food chain as an outlet for its product (ex- panding forward). Pepsi owns BurgerKing, for example. A conglomerate merger involves companies in unrelated lines of business. For ex- ample, before it went belly up in 1999, the Korean conglomerate, Daewoo, had nearly 400 different subsidiaries and 150,000 employees. It built ships in Korea, manufactured microwaves in France, TVs in Mexico, cars in Poland, fertilizers in Vietnam, and man- aged hotels in China and a bank in Hungary. No U.S. company is as diversified as Dae- woo, but in the 1960s and 1970s it was common in the United States for unrelated busi- nesses to merge. However, the number of conglomerate mergers declined in the 1980s. In fact much of the action in the 1980s came from breaking up the conglomerates that had been formed 10 to 20 years earlier. (cid:1) Self-Test 1 Are the following hypothetical mergers horizontal, vertical, or conglomerate? a. IBM acquires Apple Computer. b. Apple Computer acquires Stop & Shop (a supermarket chain). c. Stop & Shop acquires Campbell Soup. d. Campbell Soup acquires IBM. We have already seen that one motive for a merger is to replace the existing man- agement team. If this motive is important, one would expect that poorly performing firms would tend to be targets for acquisition; this seems to be the case.3 However, firms also acquire other firms for reasons that have nothing to do with inadequate man-
Brealey
agement. Many mergers and acquisitions are motivated by possible gains in efficiency from combining operations. These mergers create synergies. By this we mean that the two firms are worth more together than apart. 3 For example, Palepu found that investors in firms that were subsequently acquired earned relatively low rates of return for several years before the merger. See K. Palepu, “Predicting Takeover Targets: A Methodological and Empirical Analysis,” Journal of Accounting and Economics 8 (March 1986), pp. 3–36. Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 573 A merger adds value only if synergies, better management, or other changes make the two firms worth more together than apart. It would be convenient if we could say that certain types of mergers are usually suc- cessful and other types fail. Unfortunately, there are no such simple generalizations. Many mergers that appear to make sense nevertheless fail because managers cannot handle the complex task of integrating two firms with different production processes, accounting methods, and corporate cultures. Moreover, the value of most businesses de- pends on human assets—managers, skilled workers, scientists, and engineers. If these people are not happy in their new roles in the acquiring firm, the best of them will leave. Beware of paying too much for assets that go down in the elevator and out to the park- ing lot at the close of each business day. With this caveat in mind, we will now consider possible sources of synergy. ECONOMIES OF SCALE Just as most of us believe that we would be happier if only we were a little richer, so managers always seem to believe their firm would be more competitive if only it were just a little bigger. They hope for economies of scale, that is, the opportunity to spread fixed costs across a larger volume of output. The banking industry provides many ex- amples. By the 1970s, it was clear that the United States had too many small, local banks. Some (now very large) banks grew by systematically buying up smaller banks and streamlining their operations. Most of the cost savings came from consolidating “backoffice” operations, such as computer systems for processing checks and credit- card transactions and payments. These economies of scale are the natural goal of horizontal mergers. But they have been claimed in conglomerate mergers, too. The architects of these mergers have pointed to the economies that come from sharing central services such as accounting, financial control, and top-level management. ECONOMIES OF VERTICAL INTEGRATION Large industrial companies commonly like to gain as much control and coordination as possible over the production process by expanding back toward the output of the raw material and forward to the ultimate consumer. One way to achieve this is to merge with a supplier or a customer. Consider Du Pont’s purchase of an oil company, Conoco. This was vertical integration because petroleum is the ultimate raw material for much of Du Pont’s chemical production. Do not assume that more vertical integration is necessarily better than less. Carried to extremes, it is absurdly inefficient. For example, before the Polish economy was re- structured, LOT, the Polish state airline, found itself raising pigs to make sure that its employees had fresh meat on their tables. (Of course, in a centrally managed economy it may prove necessary to grow your own meat, since you can’t be sure you’ll be able to buy it.) Vertical integration is less popular recently. Many companies are finding it more ef- ficient to outsource the provision of many activities. For example, Du Pont seems to have become less convinced of the benefits of vertical integration, for in 1999 it sold off Conoco. 574 SECTION SIX COMBINING COMPLEMENTARY RESOURCES Many small firms are acquired by large firms that can provide the missing ingredients necessary for the firm’s success. The small firm may have a unique product but lack the engineering and sales organization necessary to produce and market it on a large scale.
Brealey
The firm could develop engineering and sales talent from scratch, but it may be quicker and cheaper to merge with a firm that already has ample talent. The two firms have complementary resources—each has what the other needs—so it may make sense for them to merge. Also the merger may open up opportunities that neither firm would pur- sue otherwise. Federal Express’s purchase of Caliber System, a trucking company, is an example. Federal Express specializes in shipping packages by air, mostly for overnight delivery. Caliber’s RMS subsidiary moves nonexpress packages by truck. RMS greatly increases Federal Express’s capability to move packages on the ground. At the same time, RMS-originated business can move easily on the Federal Express system when rapid or distant delivery is essential. (cid:1) EXAMPLE 1 Complementary Resources Of course two large firms may also merge because they have complementary resources. Consider the 1989 merger between two electric utilities, Utah Power & Light and PacifiCorp, which serves customers in California. Utah Power’s peak demand comes in the summer, for air conditioning. PacifiCorp’s peak comes in the winter, for heating. The savings from combining the two firms’ generating systems were estimated at $45 million annually. MERGERS AS A USE FOR SURPLUS FUNDS Suppose that your firm is in a mature industry. It is generating a substantial amount of cash, but it has few profitable investment opportunities. Ideally such a firm should dis- tribute the surplus cash to shareholders by increasing its dividend payment or by repur- chasing its shares. Unfortunately, energetic managers are often reluctant to shrink their firm in this way. If the firm is not willing to purchase its own shares, it can instead purchase some- one else’s. Thus firms with a surplus of cash and a shortage of good investment oppor- tunities often turn to mergers financed by cash as a way of deploying their capital. Firms that have excess cash and do not pay it out or redeploy it by acquisition often find themselves targets for takeover by other firms that propose to redeploy the cash for them. During the oil price slump of the early 1980s, many cash-rich oil companies found themselves threatened by takeover. This was not because their cash was a unique asset. The acquirers wanted to capture the companies’ cash flow to make sure it was not frittered away on negative-NPV oil exploration projects. We return to this free-cash- flow motive for takeovers later. We have discussed how mergers may make economic sense, but things can still go wrong when managers don’t do their homework. That was the case for Converse Inc., which produces athletic shoes. In May 1995 Converse announced that it was acquiring Apex One, a leading maker of sportswear. Apex brought with it a number of valuable licenses for professional and college teams. As one enthusiast observed, “By letting them outfit athletes from head to toe, the Apex deal potentially puts them on an even Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 575 keel with Nike and Reebok.” However, 85 days later Converse closed down Apex One after incurring a $46 million loss on its investment. What went wrong? The problem appears to have begun when Apex was several months late in introducing its fall product lines. Converse’s management complained that, in light of these delays, Apex’s $100 million revenue projection at the time of the purchase had been unrealistic and over the next 3 months projections were progres- sively scaled back to $40 million. Inevitably, the closure of Apex was followed by a vol- ley of legal suits.4 Dubious Reasons for Mergers The benefits that we have described so far all make economic sense. Other arguments sometimes given for mergers are more dubious. Here are two. DIVERSIFICATION We have suggested that the managers of a cash-rich company may prefer to see that cash used for acquisitions. That is why we often see cash-rich firms in stagnant indus-
Brealey