title
stringlengths 8
841
| date
timestamp[s] | eurovoc_concepts
sequencelengths 1
10
| url
stringclasses 79
values | lang
stringclasses 24
values | formats
sequencelengths 1
5
| text
stringclasses 55
values |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Komisijas Regula (EK) Nr. 164/97 (1997. gada 30. janvāris), ar ko apstiprina ārkārtas atbalsta pasākumus liellopu gaļas tirgum Francijā, piemērojot Lēmumu 97/18/EK | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | lav | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 240
LV
Eiropas Savienības Oficiālais Vēstnesis
03/20. sēj.
31997R0164
31.1.1997.
EIROPAS KOPIENU OFICIĀLAIS VĒSTNESIS
L 29/1
KOMISIJAS REGULA (EK) Nr. 164/97
(1997. gada 30. janvāris),
ar ko apstiprina ārkārtas atbalsta pasākumus liellopu gaļas tirgum Francijā, piemērojot Lēmumu
97/18/EK
EIROPAS KOPIENU KOMISIJA,
IR PIEŅĒMUSI ŠO REGULU:
ņemot vērā Eiropas Kopienas dibināšanas līgumu,
1. pants
jūnija Regulu (EEK)
ņemot vērā Padomes 1968. gada 27.
Nr. 805/68 par liellopu gaļas un teļa gaļas tirgus kopīgo orga-
nizāciju (1), kurā jaunākie grozījumi
izdarīti ar Regulu (EEK)
Nr. 2222/96 (2), un jo īpaši tās 23. pantu,
1.
Francijai ir tiesības maksāt kompensāciju par liellopiem,
kas turēti kādā saimniecībā Francijas teritorijā un nokauti
saskaņā ar Francijas plānu slimības izskaušanai, kas apstiprināts
ar Lēmumu 97/18/EK.
tā kā Komisija ar Lēmumu 97/18/EK (3) apstiprināja pasā-
kumus, ko Francija ierosināja, lai šajā dalībvalstī apkarotu un
izskaustu BSE; tā kā saskaņā ar minēto lēmumu finansiālā palī-
dzība par attiecīgo dzīvnieku nokaušanu Francijai būtu jāpiešķir
saskaņā ar principiem, kas izklāstīti Komisijas 1996. gada
19. aprīļa Regulā (EK) Nr. 716/96, ar ko apstiprina ārkārtas
atbalsta pasākumus liellopu gaļas tirgum Apvienotajā Kara-
listē (4), kurā jaunākie grozījumi
izdarīti ar Regulu (EK)
Nr. 2423/96 (5); tā kā tāpēc būtu jānosaka, ka Kopiena sedz
70 % no nokauto dzīvnieku tirgus vērtības; tā kā, lai noteiktu
tirgus vērtību, Francijai jāizveido sistēma, kas nodrošina godīgu
un objektīvu katra dzīvnieka novērtējumu;
tā kā jānodrošina, ka attiecīgos dzīvniekus nokauj un iznīcina
tā, lai nekādā gadījumā neapdraudētu cilvēku vai citu dzīvnieku
veselību; tā kā tādēļ
jāprecizē nosacījumi, saskaņā ar kuriem
iznīcina šos dzīvniekus, kā arī nosacījumi, saskaņā ar kuriem
Francijas iestādes veic pārbaudes;
tā kā būtu jānosaka, ka Komisijas eksperti pārbauda, kā tiek
ievēroti minētie nosacījumi;
Dzīvniekus, kas minēti 1. punktā, nokauj vai nu saimnie-
2.
cībā, vai arī
iznīcināšanas uzņēmumā. Nevienu no iepriekš-
minēto dzīvnieku daļām nedrīkst iekļaut cilvēku uztura ķēdēs
vai dzīvnieku barības ķēdēs, nedz arī izmantot kosmētikas vai
farmācijas līdzekļos.
Neierobežojot šā punkta pirmo daļu, dzīvniekus, kas vajadzī-
gajā kontrolē ir nokauti saimniecībā, pēc nokaušanas nekavējo-
ties transportē uz iznīcināšanas uzņēmumu, kur tos pārstrādā
un iznīcina.
3.
Atbildīgā Francijas iestāde:
— neierobežojot 1. punktu, ir pilnvarota pirms pārstrādes un
skaita
pārbaudīt
noteikta
iznīcināšanas
nokauto dzīvnieku smadzenes,
laboratoriski
— ir pilnvarota pirms pārstrādes un iznīcināšanas ierobežotu
skaitu dzīvnieku izmantot zinātnes un izglītības mērķiem,
— veic vajadzīgās 2. punktā minēto darbību administratīvās
pārbaudes un efektīvu uzraudzību uz vietas, kā arī
— kontrolē šīs darbības, veicot regulāras pārbaudes, par kurām
iepriekš nebrīdina, jo īpaši lai pārliecinātos, ka visu iegūto
materiālu efektīvi iznīcina.
tā kā šajā regulā paredzētie pasākumi saskan ar Liellopu un teļa
gaļas pārvaldības komitejas atzinumu,
Šo pārbaužu, kontroļu un apskašu rezultātus dara zināmus
Komisijai pēc tās lūguma.
(1) OV L 148, 28.6.1968., 24.
(2) OV L 296, 21.11.1996., 50.
(3) OV L 6, 10.1.1997., 43.
lpp.
(4) OV L 99, 20.4.1996., 14.
(5) OV L 329, 19.12.1996., 43.
lpp.
lpp.
lpp.
lpp.
4.
To dzīvnieku ādas, kuri minēti 1. punktā, nav jāiznīcina
ar noteikumu, ka tās apstrādā tā, lai tās varētu izmantot tikai
ādas apstrādes rūpniecībā.
03/20. sēj.
LV
Eiropas Savienības Oficiālais Vēstnesis
241
2. pants
1.
Kompensācijas apjomu, ko Francija saskaņā ar 1. panta
1. punktu izmaksā ražotājiem vai viņu aģentiem, atbilst katra
attiecīgā dzīvnieka objektīvajai tirgus vērtība, ko nosaka saskaņā
ar objektīvās novērtēšanas sistēmu, kuru apstiprina atbildīgā
Francijas iestāde.
Kopiena sedz 70 % no izdevumiem, kas rodas saistībā ar
2.
1. punktā minēto kompensāciju par dzīvniekiem, kuri nokauti
saskaņā ar 1. pantu.
3.
Neierobežojot 1. punktu, atbildīgā Francijas iestāde ir
pilnvarota izmaksāt papildu summas par dzīvniekiem, kas
nokauti saskaņā ar šo shēmu. Kopiena nepiedalās šo izdevumu
līdzfinansēšanā.
3. pants
Francija pieņem visus pasākumus, kas vajadzīgi,
lai nodroši-
nātu, ka šo shēmu piemēro pareizi. Tā pēc iespējas ātrāk
informē Komisiju par pasākumiem, ko tā ir veikusi, kā arī
jebkādām izmaiņām šajos pasākumos.
Atbildīgā Francijas iestāde:
4. pants
— nokauto dzīvnieku vidējo tirgus vērtību, kā arī
— 2. panta 3. punktā minēto papildu summu kopējo
apjomu
saskaņā ar šo shēmu;
b) izveido sīki
izstrādātu ziņojumu par kontrolēm, ko tā
veikusi saskaņā ar 3. punktā minētajiem pasākumiem, un
reizi ceturksnī iesniedz šo ziņojumu Komisijā.
5. pants
Neierobežojot Padomes Regulas (EEK) Nr. 729/70 (1) 9. pantu,
Komisijas eksperti, vajadzības gadījumā kopā ar dalībvalstu
ekspertiem,
iestādi veic
pārbaudes uz vietas, lai pārliecinātos, ka ievēroti visi šīs regulas
noteikumi.
atbildīgo Francijas
sadarbībā
ar
6. pants
Pasākumus, ko veic saskaņā ar šo regulu, uzskata par inter-
vences pasākumiem Regulas
(EEK) Nr. 729/70 3. panta
nozīmē.
7. pants
a) katru reizi, piemērojot pirmajā 1. minēto plānu, nekavējoties
informē Komisiju par:
— to dzīvnieku skaitu, kurus paredzēts nokaut,
— nokauto dzīvnieku skaitu,
Šī regula stājas spēkā dienā, kad to publicē Eiropas Kopienu
Oficiālajā Vēstnesī.
To piemēro, sākot no 1996. gada 1. aprīļa.
Šī regula uzliek saistības kopumā un ir tieši piemērojama visās dalībvalstīs.
Briselē, 1997. gada 30.
janvārī
Komisijas vārdā —
Komisijas loceklis
Franz FISCHLER
(1) OV L 94, 28.4.1970., 13.
lpp.
|
For more information about employment, competitiveness and solidarity : Ireland. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU employment policy",
"European social policy",
"Ireland",
"access to EU information"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/bc3d53ba-b8a3-409c-a563-c3cff4395807 | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
ΓΡΑΠΤΗ ΕΡΩΤΗΣΗ αρ θ. 148/97 του Amedeo AMADEO προς το Συμβούλ ο. Συντελεστής φερεγγυότητας των πιστωτικών ιδρυμάτων | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"approximation of laws",
"credit guarantee",
"credit institution",
"financial solvency",
"ratio",
"share capital"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/762b4ae5-517f-4c96-9c18-1a5624baaa76 | ell | [
"print"
] | null |
Lisätietoja työllisyydestä, kasvusta, kilpailukyvystä ja yhteisvastuullisuudesta : Suomi/Finland. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU employment policy",
"European social policy",
"Finland",
"access to EU information"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/0243102f-1095-424a-8b31-3c4217722100 | fin | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Nařízení Komise (ES) č. 164/97 ze dne 30. ledna 1997, kterým se přijímají mimořádná opatření na podporu trhu s hovězím masem ve Francii podle rozhodnutí 97/18/ES | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | ces | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 240
CS
Úřední věstník Evropské unie
03/sv. 20
31997R0164
31.1.1997
ÚŘEDNÍ VĚSTNÍK EVROPSKÝCH SPOLEČENSTVÍ
L 29/1
NAŘÍZENÍ KOMISE (ES) č. 164/97
ze dne 30. ledna 1997,
kterým se přijímají mimořádná opatření na podporu trhu s hovězím masem ve Francii podle
rozhodnutí 97/18/ES
KOMISE EVROPSKÝCH SPOLEČENSTVÍ,
PŘIJALA TOTO NAŘÍZENÍ:
s ohledem na Smlouvu o založení Evropského společenství,
Článek 1
Rady
nařízení
dne
ze
s ohledem na
trhu s hovězím
27. června 1968 o společné organizaci
a telecím masem (1),
nařízením
naposledy
(ES) č. 222/96 (2), a zejména na článek 23 uvedeného naří-
zení,
pozměněné
č. 805/68
vzhledem k tomu, že Komise přijala rozhodnutím 97/18/ES (3)
opatření navržená Francií za účelem kontroly a eradikace
bovinní spongiformní encefalopatie (BSE) v tomto členském
státě; že v souladu s uvedeným rozhodnutím je nutné poskyt-
finanční pomoc na porážku příslušných zvířat
nout Francii
v souladu s nařízením Komise
č. 716/96 ze dne
(ES)
19. dubna 1996, kterým se přijímají mimořádná opatření na
podporu trhu s hovězím masem ve Spojeném království (4), na-
posledy pozměněným nařízením (ES) č. 2423/96 (5); že je
proto nutné stanovit příspěvek Společenství ve výši 70 % tržní
hodnoty poražených zvířat; že za účelem stanovení
tržní
hodnoty je vhodné, aby Francie zavedla systém, který zaručí
přiměřené a objektivní ohodnocení každého zvířete;
vzhledem k tomu, že je nezbytné zajistit, aby příslušná zvířata
byla poražena
aby
nevzniklo žádné nebezpečí pro zdraví lidí a ostatních zvířat; že
je proto nezbytné, aby francouzské orgány stanovily podmínky
pro likvidaci těchto zvířat a pro kontroly, které mají provést;
takovým způsobem,
a zlikvidována
vzhledem k tomu, že je nutné vytvořit ustanovení, aby odbor-
stanovených
níci Komise mohli kontrolovat dodržování
podmínek;
Francie je oprávněna vyplácet náhradu pro skot chovaný
1.
v zemědělském podniku na území Francie a poražený v sou-
ladu s eradikačním plánem Francie schváleným rozhodnutím
97/18/ES.
2.
Zvířata uvedená v odstavci 1 jsou poražena buď v země-
dělském podniku, nebo v kafilérii. Žádná část uvedených zvířat
se nesmí dostat potravinového a krmivového řetězce nebo být
použita pro výrobu kosmetických nebo farmaceutických
výrobků.
Po porážce v zemědělském podniku jsou zvířata neprodleně
přepravena do spaloven nebo kafilérií, kde jsou po zpracování
zlikvidována.
3.
Příslušný francouzský orgán
— je odchylně od odstavce 1 oprávněn před zpracováním
a likvidací podrobit laboratornímu vyšetření vzorky mozku
poražených zvířat,
— je oprávněn použít před zpracováním a likvidací omezený
počet zvířat pro výzkumné a vzdělávací účely,
— provede nezbytné administrativní kontroly a zkontroluje
na místě činnosti uvedené v odstavci 2 a
— zkontroluje tyto činnosti na základě častých a neohláše-
ných inspekcí, které mají zejména prověřit, že byl všechen
natřený materiál účinně zničen.
vzhledem k tomu, že opatření tohoto nařízení jsou v souladu
se stanoviskem Řídícího výboru pro hovězí a telecí maso,
Výsledky těchto prověření, kontrol a vyšetření jsou poskytnuty
Komisi na její žádost.
(1) Úř. věst. L 148, 28.6.1968, s. 24.
(2) Úř. věst. L 296, 21.11.1996, s. 50.
(3) Úř. věst. L 6, 10.1.1997, s. 43.
(4) Úř. věst. L 99, 20.4.1996, s. 14.
(5) Úř. věst. L 329, 19.12.1996, s. 43.
4.
Kůže zvířat uvedených v odstavci 1 nejsou zlikvidovány,
pokud byly ošetřeny tak, že je lze použít pouze pro výrobu
kůže.
03/sv. 20
CS
Úřední věstník Evropské unie
241
Článek 2
1.
Částka náhrady, kterou je příslušný francouzský orgán
oprávněn vyplácet producentům nebo jejich zástupcům podle
čl. 1 odst. 1, odpovídá objektivní tržní hodnotě pro každé
zvíře ve Francii, která se stanoví na základě systému individuál-
ního
schváleného
ohodnocení
příslušným francouzským orgánem.
a objektivního
zvířete
Společenství
2.
částku
náhrady uvedenou v odstavci 1, která se vyplácí pro zvířata
poražená podle článku 1.
spolufinancuje 70 % výdajů na
Odchylně od odstavce 1 jsou příslušné francouzské
3.
orgány oprávněny vyplácet příplatky pro skot poražený
v rámci tohoto režimu. Společenství se na financování těchto
výdajů nepodílí.
Článek 3
Francie přijme všechna opatření nezbytná k použití
tohoto
režimu. Co nejdříve informuje Komisi o přijatých opatřeních
a o všech jejich změnách.
Příslušný francouzský orgán
Článek 4
— o průměrné tržní ceně poraženého zvířete a
— o celkové částce příplatků uvedených v čl. 2 odst. 3
na základě stávajícího režimu v průběhu předchozího
týdne
b) každé čtvrtletí vypracuje podrobnou zprávu o kontrolách,
které provedl na základě opatření uvedených v článku 3,
a každé čtvrtletí ji předá Komisi.
Článek 5
Aniž je dotčen článek 9 nařízení Rady (EHS) č. 729/70 (1),
odborníci Komise, které v případě potřeby doprovázejí odbor-
níci z ostatních členských států, provádějí ve spolupráci
s příslušnými francouzskými orgány kontroly na místě, aby
prověřili dodržování všech ustanovení tohoto nařízení.
Článek 6
Opatření přijatá podle tohoto nařízení se považují za inter-
venční opatření ve smyslu článku 3 nařízení (EHS) č. 729/70.
Článek 7
ihned po každém použití plánu uvede-
a) informuje Komisi
ného v článku 1:
— o počtu zvířat na porážku,
— o počtu poražených zvířat,
Toto nařízení vstupuje v platnost dnem vyhlášení v Úředním
věstníku Evropských společenství.
Použije se ode dne 1. dubna 1996.
Toto nařízení je závazné v celém rozsahu a přímo použitelné ve všech členských státech.
V Bruselu dne 30.
ledna 1997.
Za Komisi
Franz FISCHLER
člen Komise
(1) Úř. věst. L 94, 28.4.1970, s. 13.
|
Parecer do Comité Económico e Social sobre «As relações entre a União Europeia e a ASEAN» | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"ASEAN",
"EU relations",
"cooperation policy",
"economic relations",
"trade relations"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/b5d765a2-9473-4767-b3f2-a69686fc3d10 | por | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Decizia nr. 1/97 a Comitetului mixt al SEE din 30 ianuarie 1997 de modificare a anexei II (Reglementări tehnice, standarde, încercări și certificare) la Acordul SEE | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | ron | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print",
"xhtml"
] | (cid:18)(cid:18)(cid:16)(cid:87)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:15) (cid:22)(cid:22)
(cid:51)(cid:48)
(cid:43)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:79)(cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:48)(cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:77) (cid:66)(cid:77) (cid:54)(cid:79)(cid:74)(cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:74)(cid:74) (cid:38)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:70)
(cid:19)(cid:25)(cid:22)
(cid:19)(cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:24)(cid:37)(cid:17)(cid:20)(cid:19)(cid:24)(cid:9)(cid:17)(cid:19)(cid:10)
(cid:45) (cid:25)(cid:22)(cid:16)(cid:23)(cid:23)
(cid:43)(cid:54)(cid:51)(cid:47)(cid:34)(cid:45)(cid:54)(cid:45) (cid:48)(cid:39)(cid:42)(cid:36)(cid:42)(cid:34)(cid:45) (cid:34)(cid:45) (cid:36)(cid:48)(cid:46)(cid:54)(cid:47)(cid:42)(cid:53)(cid:227)(cid:323)(cid:42)(cid:45)(cid:48)(cid:51) (cid:38)(cid:54)(cid:51)(cid:48)(cid:49)(cid:38)(cid:47)(cid:38)
(cid:19)(cid:24)(cid:15)(cid:20)(cid:15)(cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:24)
(cid:37)(cid:38)(cid:36)(cid:42)(cid:59)(cid:42)(cid:34) (cid:47)(cid:51)(cid:15) (cid:18)(cid:16)(cid:26)(cid:24) (cid:34) (cid:36)(cid:48)(cid:46)(cid:42)(cid:53)(cid:38)(cid:53)(cid:54)(cid:45)(cid:54)(cid:42) (cid:46)(cid:42)(cid:57)(cid:53) (cid:34)(cid:45) (cid:52)(cid:38)(cid:38)
(cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:79) (cid:20)(cid:17) (cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:86)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:24)
(cid:69)(cid:70) (cid:78)(cid:80)(cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:70) (cid:66) (cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:70)(cid:89)(cid:70)(cid:74) (cid:42)(cid:42) (cid:9)(cid:51)(cid:70)(cid:72)(cid:77)(cid:70)(cid:78)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:228)(cid:83)(cid:74) (cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:73)(cid:79)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:70)(cid:13) (cid:84)(cid:85)(cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:69)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:69)(cid:70)(cid:13) (cid:207)(cid:79)(cid:68)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:68)(cid:228)(cid:83)(cid:74) (cid:84)(cid:13)(cid:74) (cid:68)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:10) (cid:77)(cid:66) (cid:34)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:69)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:52)(cid:38)(cid:38)
(cid:36)(cid:48)(cid:46)(cid:42)(cid:53)(cid:38)(cid:53)(cid:54)(cid:45) (cid:46)(cid:42)(cid:57)(cid:53) (cid:34)(cid:45) (cid:52)(cid:38)(cid:38)(cid:13)
(cid:66)(cid:87)(cid:195)(cid:79)(cid:69) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:87)(cid:70)(cid:69)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:70) (cid:34)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:69)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:69) (cid:52)(cid:81)(cid:66)(cid:324)(cid:74)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:38)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:79)(cid:80)(cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:68) (cid:38)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:13) (cid:66)(cid:84)(cid:85)(cid:71)(cid:70)(cid:77) (cid:68)(cid:86)(cid:78) (cid:66) (cid:71)(cid:80)(cid:84)(cid:85) (cid:78)(cid:80)(cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:66)(cid:85) (cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:79) (cid:49)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:85)(cid:80)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:69)(cid:70)
(cid:66)(cid:69)(cid:66)(cid:81)(cid:85)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:70) (cid:66) (cid:34)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:69)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74) (cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:69) (cid:52)(cid:81)(cid:66)(cid:324)(cid:74)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:38)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:79)(cid:80)(cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:68) (cid:38)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:13) (cid:69)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:86)(cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:85) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:86)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:70) (cid:1353)(cid:66)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:69)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:1352)(cid:13) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:84)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:77) (cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:26)(cid:25)(cid:13)
(cid:207)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:83)(cid:86)(cid:68)(cid:195)(cid:85) (cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:70)(cid:89)(cid:66) (cid:42)(cid:42) (cid:77)(cid:66) (cid:66)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:69) (cid:66) (cid:71)(cid:80)(cid:84)(cid:85) (cid:78)(cid:80)(cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:228) (cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:79) (cid:37)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:74)(cid:91)(cid:74)(cid:66) (cid:79)(cid:83)(cid:15) (cid:24)(cid:23)(cid:16)(cid:26)(cid:23) (cid:66) (cid:36)(cid:80)(cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74) (cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:89)(cid:85) (cid:66)(cid:77) (cid:52)(cid:38)(cid:38) (cid:9)(cid:18)(cid:10)(cid:28)
(cid:207)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:83)(cid:86)(cid:68)(cid:195)(cid:85) (cid:37)(cid:74)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:66) (cid:26)(cid:22)(cid:16)(cid:19)(cid:25)(cid:16)(cid:36)(cid:38) (cid:66) (cid:49)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:77)(cid:66)(cid:78)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74) (cid:38)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:79) (cid:84)(cid:13)(cid:74) (cid:66) (cid:36)(cid:80)(cid:79)(cid:84)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74) (cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:79) (cid:19)(cid:21) (cid:80)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:80)(cid:78)(cid:67)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:22) (cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:69) (cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:68)(cid:324)(cid:74)(cid:66) (cid:77)(cid:66)
(cid:71)(cid:80)(cid:68) (cid:66) (cid:78)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:70)(cid:77)(cid:80)(cid:83) (cid:86)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:91)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:70) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:66)(cid:78)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:66)(cid:75)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:66) (cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:80)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:228) (cid:66) (cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:80)(cid:83) (cid:68)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:72)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:74) (cid:69)(cid:70) (cid:66)(cid:86)(cid:85)(cid:80)(cid:87)(cid:70)(cid:73)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:70) (cid:9)(cid:19)(cid:10) (cid:85)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:67)(cid:86)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:84)(cid:228) (cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:207)(cid:79)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:81)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:228)
(cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:66)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:69)(cid:13)
(cid:37)(cid:38)(cid:36)(cid:42)(cid:37)(cid:38)(cid:27)
(cid:34)(cid:83)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:18)
(cid:45)(cid:66) (cid:68)(cid:66)(cid:81)(cid:74)(cid:85)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:42) (cid:69)(cid:86)(cid:81)(cid:228) (cid:81)(cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:21)(cid:22)(cid:84) (cid:9)(cid:37)(cid:74)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:66) (cid:26)(cid:22)(cid:16)(cid:18)(cid:16)(cid:36)(cid:38) (cid:66) (cid:49)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:77)(cid:66)(cid:78)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74) (cid:38)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:79) (cid:84)(cid:13)(cid:74) (cid:66) (cid:36)(cid:80)(cid:79)(cid:84)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74)(cid:10) (cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:79) (cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:70)(cid:89)(cid:66) (cid:42)(cid:42) (cid:77)(cid:66) (cid:66)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:69)
(cid:84)(cid:70) (cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:84)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:91)(cid:228) (cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:78)(cid:228)(cid:85)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:81)(cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:27)
(cid:1353)(cid:21)(cid:22)(cid:85)(cid:15) (cid:20)(cid:26)(cid:22) (cid:45) (cid:17)(cid:17)(cid:19)(cid:25)(cid:27) (cid:37)(cid:74)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:66) (cid:26)(cid:22)(cid:16)(cid:19)(cid:25)(cid:16)(cid:36)(cid:38) (cid:66) (cid:49)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:77)(cid:66)(cid:78)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74) (cid:38)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:79) (cid:84)(cid:13)(cid:74) (cid:66) (cid:36)(cid:80)(cid:79)(cid:84)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74) (cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:79) (cid:19)(cid:21) (cid:80)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:80)(cid:78)(cid:67)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:22)
(cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:69) (cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:68)(cid:324)(cid:74)(cid:66) (cid:77)(cid:66) (cid:71)(cid:80)(cid:68) (cid:66) (cid:78)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:70)(cid:77)(cid:80)(cid:83) (cid:86)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:91)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:70) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:66)(cid:78)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:66)(cid:75)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:66) (cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:80)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:228) (cid:66) (cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:80)(cid:83) (cid:68)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:72)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:74) (cid:69)(cid:70) (cid:66)(cid:86)(cid:85)(cid:80)(cid:87)(cid:70)(cid:73)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:70)
(cid:9)(cid:43)(cid:48) (cid:45) (cid:19)(cid:25)(cid:18)(cid:13) (cid:19)(cid:20)(cid:15)(cid:18)(cid:18)(cid:15)(cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:22)(cid:13) (cid:81)(cid:15) (cid:18)(cid:10)(cid:15)(cid:1352)
(cid:53)(cid:70)(cid:89)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:77)(cid:70) (cid:37)(cid:74)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:70)(cid:74) (cid:26)(cid:22)(cid:16)(cid:19)(cid:25)(cid:16)(cid:36)(cid:38) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:78)(cid:67)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:70) (cid:74)(cid:84)(cid:77)(cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:69)(cid:70)(cid:91)(cid:228) (cid:84)(cid:13)(cid:74) (cid:79)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:87)(cid:70)(cid:72)(cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:228)(cid:13) (cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:70)(cid:89)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:70) (cid:77)(cid:66) (cid:87)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:84)(cid:74)(cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:70) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:78)(cid:67)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:70) (cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:84)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:87)(cid:70) (cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:70)
(cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:91)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:74) (cid:69)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:74)(cid:91)(cid:74)(cid:74)(cid:13) (cid:84)(cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:85) (cid:66)(cid:86)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:70)(cid:15)
(cid:34)(cid:83)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:19)
(cid:49)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:91)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:66) (cid:69)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:74)(cid:91)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:83)(cid:228) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:87)(cid:74)(cid:72)(cid:80)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:70) (cid:77)(cid:66) (cid:18) (cid:71)(cid:70)(cid:67)(cid:83)(cid:86)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:24) (cid:68)(cid:86) (cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:79)(cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:324)(cid:74)(cid:66) (cid:85)(cid:83)(cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:84)(cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:74) (cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:66)(cid:67)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:70) (cid:68)(cid:228)(cid:85)(cid:83)(cid:70) (cid:36)(cid:80)(cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:89)(cid:85) (cid:66)(cid:77) (cid:52)(cid:38)(cid:38)
(cid:66) (cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:83) (cid:79)(cid:80)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:228)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:80)(cid:83) (cid:81)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:87)(cid:228)(cid:91)(cid:86)(cid:85)(cid:70) (cid:77)(cid:66) (cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:18)(cid:17)(cid:20) (cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:70)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:9)(cid:18)(cid:10) (cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:79) (cid:66)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:83)(cid:69)(cid:15)
(cid:34)(cid:83)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:20)
(cid:49)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:91)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:66) (cid:69)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:74)(cid:91)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:84)(cid:70) (cid:81)(cid:86)(cid:67)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:228) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:52)(cid:70)(cid:68)(cid:324)(cid:74)(cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:70)(cid:66) (cid:52)(cid:38)(cid:38) (cid:84)(cid:13)(cid:74) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:52)(cid:86)(cid:81)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:78)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:52)(cid:38)(cid:38) (cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:70) (cid:43)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:79)(cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:74) (cid:48)(cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:77) (cid:66)(cid:77) (cid:36)(cid:80)(cid:78)(cid:86)(cid:79)(cid:74)(cid:85)(cid:228)(cid:324)(cid:74)(cid:77)(cid:80)(cid:83) (cid:38)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:80)(cid:81)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:70)(cid:15)
(cid:34)(cid:83)(cid:85)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:80)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:21)
(cid:34)(cid:69)(cid:80)(cid:81)(cid:85)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:228) (cid:77)(cid:66) (cid:35)(cid:83)(cid:86)(cid:89)(cid:70)(cid:77)(cid:77)(cid:70)(cid:84)(cid:13) (cid:20)(cid:17) (cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:79)(cid:86)(cid:66)(cid:83)(cid:74)(cid:70) (cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:24)(cid:15)
(cid:49)(cid:70)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:83)(cid:86) (cid:36)(cid:80)(cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:85)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:78)(cid:74)(cid:89)(cid:85) (cid:66)(cid:77) (cid:52)(cid:38)(cid:38)
(cid:49)(cid:83)(cid:70)(cid:84)(cid:13)(cid:70)(cid:69)(cid:74)(cid:79)(cid:85)(cid:70)(cid:77)(cid:70)
(cid:36)(cid:15) (cid:37)(cid:34)(cid:58)
(cid:9)(cid:18)(cid:10) (cid:47)(cid:70)(cid:81)(cid:86)(cid:67)(cid:77)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:66)(cid:85)(cid:228) (cid:207)(cid:79)(cid:68)(cid:228) (cid:207)(cid:79) (cid:43)(cid:86)(cid:83)(cid:79)(cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:86)(cid:77) (cid:48)(cid:71)(cid:74)(cid:68)(cid:74)(cid:66)(cid:77)(cid:15)
(cid:9)(cid:19)(cid:10)
(cid:43)(cid:48) (cid:45) (cid:19)(cid:25)(cid:18)(cid:13) (cid:19)(cid:20)(cid:15)(cid:18)(cid:18)(cid:15)(cid:18)(cid:26)(cid:26)(cid:22)(cid:13) (cid:81)(cid:15) (cid:18)(cid:15)
|
Beschluß des Gemeinsamen EWR-Ausschusses Nr. 1/97 vom 30. Januar 1997 über die Änderung des Anhangs II (Technische Vorschriften, Normen, Prüfung und Zertifizierung) des EWR-Abkommens | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | deu | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Ir-Regolament tal-Kummissjoni (KEE) Nru 164/97 tat-30 ta’ Jannar 1997 li jadotta miżuri eċċezzjonali ta’ appoġġ għas-suq tal-laħam taċ-ċanga fi Franza billi tiġi applikata d-Deċiżjoni 97/18/KE | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | mlt | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 240
MT
Il-Ġurnal Uffiċjali ta' l-Unjoni Ewropea
03/Vol. 20
31997R0164
31.1.1997
IL-ĠURNAL UFFIĊJALI TAL-KOMUNITAJIET EWROPEJ
L 29/1
IR-REGOLAMENT TAL-KUMMISSJONI (KEE) Nru 164/97
tat-30 ta’ Jannar 1997
li jadotta miżuri eċċezzjonali ta’ appoġġ għas-suq tal-laħam taċ-ċanga fi Franza billi tiġi applikata d-
Deċiżjoni 97/18/KE
IL-KUMMISSJONI TAL-KOMUNITAJIET EWROPEJ,
ADOTTAT DAN IR-REGOLAMENT:
li kkunsidrat
Wara
Ewropea,
it-Trattat
li
jistabbilixxi
l-Komunità
Artikolu 1
Wara li kkunsidrat ir-Regolament tal-Kunsill (KEE) Nru 805/68
tas-27 ta Ġunju 1968 dwar l-organizzazzjoni komuni tas-suq
tal-laħam taċ-ċanga u tal-vitella (1), kif
l-aħħar emendat bir-
Regolament
l-
Artikolu 23 li hemm fih,
(KE) Nru 2222/96 (2), u, b’mod partikolari,
Billi bid-Deċiżjoni tal-Kummissjoni 97/18/KE (3) il-Kummissjoni
approvat miżuri proposti minn Franza sabiex jikkontrollaw u
jeradikaw il-BSE f’dan l-Istat Membru; billi bi qbil mad-
tiġi provvduta
Deċiżjoni msemmija hawn fuq għandha
għajnuna finanzjarja lil Franza sabiex twettaq il-qatla tal-
bhejjem konċernati skond il-linji preskritti fir-Regolament tal-
Kummissjoni (KEE) Nru 716/96 tad-19 ta’ April 1996 li jadotta
miżuri eċċezzjonali ta’ appoġġ għas-suq tal-laħam taċ-ċanga fir-
Renju Unit (4), kif l-aħħar emendat bir-Regolament (KE) Nru
tiġi
2423/96 (5); billi, konsegwentement huwa xieraq li
provvduta kontribuzzjoni Komunitarja ta’ 70 % tal-valur fis-suq
tal-bhejjem imneħħija; billi, sabiex jiġi stabbilit il-valur fis-suq
Franza għandha twaqqaf sistema sabiex tiġi żgurata stima ġusta
u oġġettiva għal kull bhima;
jiġu
jiġi żgurat li
Billi, huwa meħtieġ illi
maqtula u meqruda f’manjiera li ma’ toħloq l-ebda theddida
għas-saħħa tal-bniedem jew għas-saħħa ta’ bhejjem oħra; billi
huwa għalhekk meħtieġ illi
l-kondizzjonijiet
dwar il-qerda ta’ dawn il-bhejjem u dwar il-kontrolli li
jridu
jitwettqu mill-awtoritajiet Franċiżi;
jiġu speċifikati
l-bhejjem involuti
Billi għandhom isiru disposizzjonijiet mill-esperti tal-Kummiss-
sabiex jiċċekkjaw konformità mal-kondizzjonijiet kif
joni
speċifikati;
Franza għandha tiġi awtorizzata li
jkunu preżenti
1.
rigward annimali bovini
territorji ta’ Franza u li
eradikazzjoni kif approvat bid-Deċiżjoni 97/18/KE.
tħallas kumpens
fond fit-
li
fuq xi
jinqatlu bi qbil mal-pjan Franċiż ta’
Il-bhejjem riferiti fil-paragrafu 1 għandhom jinqatlu jew
2.
fuq ir-razzett jew f’impjant ta’ rendiment. L-ebda parti mill-
bhejjem imsemmija hawn fuq ma tista’ tidħol fil-food chain tal-
jew tiġi wżata għall-
bniedem jew ta’
prodotti kosmetiċi jew farmaċewtiċi.
l-għalf ta’
l-annimali
Minkejja l-ewwel
subparagafu u b’konformità mal-kontroll
il-bhejjem għandhom
meħtieġ, wara li jinqatlu fuq ir-razzett,
jinġarru fil-pront lejn impjant tar-rendiment għall-proċessar u l-
qerda.
3.
L-awtorità kompetenti Franċiża għandha:
— minkejja l-paragrafu 1, qabel
il-proċessar u l-qerda,
awtorizzata li tipproċedi għal eżami
imħuħ minn kampjun tal-bhejjem imneħħija,
fil-laboratorju ta’
tiġi
l-
— tiġi awrtorizzata, qabel il-proċessar u l-qerda, li tuża numru
limitat mill-bhejjem għall-għanijiet ta’riċerka jew tagħlim,
— twettaq il-kontrolli amministrattivi u s-sorveljanza fuq il-
post meħtieġa fil-ħidma riferita fil-paragrafi 2, u
— tikkontrolla din il-ħidma fuq il-bażi ta’ spezzjonijiet spissi u
mingħajr avviż, partikolarment sabiex jiġi verifikat illi
l-
materjal kollu miksub ikun ġie effettivament meqrud.
Billi l-miżuri provvduti f’dan ir-Regolament huma bi qbil ma’ l-
opinjoni tal-Kumitat ta’ Ġestjoni tal-Laħam taċ-Ċanga u tal-
Vitella,
Ir-riżultati ta’ dawn it-testijiet, kontrolli u eżamijiet għandhom
ikunu disponibbli għall-Kummissjoni meta mitluba.
(1) ĠU Nru L 148, tat-28.6.1968, p. 24.
(2) ĠU Nru L 296, tal-21.11.1996, p. 50.
(3) ĠU Nru L 6, tal-10.1.1997, p. 43.
(4) ĠU Nru L 99, tal-20.4.1996, p. 14.
(5) ĠU Nru L 329, tad-19.12.1996, p. 43.
Il-ġlud tal-bhejjem riferiti fil-paragrafu 1 ma għandhomx
jistgħu
4.
jiġu meqruda basta jkunu ġew trattati b’tali mod illi
jintużaw biss għall-produzzjoni tal-ġilda.
03/Vol. 20
MT
Il-Ġurnal Uffiċjali ta' l-Unjoni Ewropea
241
Artikolu 2
jew lill-aġenti
L-ammont tal-kumpens għal kull bhima li jrid jitħallas lill-
1.
tagħhom minn Franza skond l-
produtturi
Artikolu 1(1) għandu jkun daqs il-valur oġġettiv tas-suq fi
Franza ta’ kull bhima kkonċernata stabbilit
ta’
sistema ta’ valutazzjoni oġġettiva miftiehma mill-awtorità
kompetenti Franċiża.
fuq il-bażi
Il-Komunità għandha tikkofinanzja bir-rata ta’ 70 % in-
2.
nefqa li għandha x’taqsam ma’ l-ammont tal-kumpens riferit fil-
paragrafu 1 għall-annimali maqtula bi qbil ma’ l-Artikolu 1.
l-awtorità kompetenti Franċiża
3. Minkejja l-paragrafu 1,
hija awtorizzata li tħallas l-ammonti supplimentari rigward l-
ifrat maqtula skond din l-iskema. Il-Komunità ma għandhiex
tikkofinanzja din in-nefqa.
Artikolu 3
Franza għandha tadotta l-miżuri kollha meħtieġa sabiex tiġi
żgurata l-applikazzjoni xierqa ta’ din l-iskema. Għandha
tgħarraf
jkun dwar il-
miżuri li tkun ħadet u dwar kull emenda għalihom.
lill-Kummissjoni malajr kemm jista’
Artikolu 4
L-awtorità kompetenti Franċiża:
(a) għandha tgħarraf lill-Kummissjoni fil-pront, kull darba li l-
pjan riferit fl-Artikolu 1 jiġi applikat, dwar:
— in-numru tal-bhejjem magħżula għat-tneħħija,
— in-numru ta’ bhejjem imneħħija,
— il-valur medju fis-suq tal-bhejjem imneħħija, u
— l-ammonti totali supplimentari riferiti fl-Artikolu 2(3)
skond din l-iskema;
(b) għandha tagħmel rapport dettaljat dwar il-kontrolli li jkunu
fl-Artikolu 3 u għandha
ttieħdu skond il-miżuri riferiti
tikkomunika dan lill-Komunità kull tlett xhur.
Artikolu 5
Mingħajr preġudizzju għall-Artikolu 9 tar-Regolament
tal-
Kunsill (KEE) Nru 729/70 (1), l-esperti tal-Kummissjoni, akkum-
panjati fejn xieraq minn esperti mill-Istati Membri, għandhom
iwettqu, b’kollaborazzjoni ma’ l-awtorità kompetenti Franċiża,
kontrolli
fuq il-post sabiex jivverifikaw il-konformità mad-
disposizzjonijiet kollha ta’ dan ir-Regolament.
Artikolu 6
Il-miżuri meħuda skond dan ir-Regolament għandhom jiġu
kunsidrati bħala miżuri ta’ intervent fit-tifsira ta’ l-Artikolu 3
tar-Regolament (KEE) Nru 729/70.
Artikolu 7
Dan ir-Regolament għandu jidħol fis-seħħ fil-jum tal-pubblikaz-
zjoni tiegħu fil-Ġurnal Uffiċjali tal-Komunitajiet Ewropej.
Għandu jibda japplika mill-1 ta’ April 1996.
Dan ir-Regolament għandu jorbot fl-intier tiegħu u japplika direttament fl-Istati Membri
kollha.
Magħmul fi Brussel, fit-30 ta’ Jannar 1997.
Għall-Kummissjoni
Franz FISCHLER
Membru tal-Kummissjoni
(1) ĠU Nru L 94, tat-28.4.1970, p. 13.
|
VERORDNUNG (EG) Nr. 171/97 DER KOMMISSION vom 30. Januar 1997 zur Festsetzung der Produktionserstattungen für Getreide und Reis | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereals",
"production refund",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/d196500f-e7d3-4057-a252-876f0dc521b1 | deu | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Kommissionens beslut av den 30 januari 1997 om avslutande av antidumpningsförfarandet beträffande import till Spanien av viss Portlandcement med ursprung i Rumänien, Tunisien och Turkiet | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Spain",
"anti-dumping legislation",
"cement",
"import",
"originating product",
"third country"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/1fe01c43-1450-4f67-a3cd-bc9c0c2d9d82 | swe | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Avis du Comité économique et social sur le thème «Pour une nouvelle dynamique dans les relations entre l'Union européenne et l'ASEAN» | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"ASEAN",
"EU relations",
"cooperation policy",
"economic relations",
"trade relations"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/b5d765a2-9473-4767-b3f2-a69686fc3d10 | fra | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGULAMENTO (CE) Nº 172/97 DA COMISSÃO de 30 de Janeiro de 1997 que estabelece os valores forfetários de importação para a determinação do preço de entrada de certos frutos e produtos hortícolas | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"citrus fruit",
"fruit vegetable",
"import price",
"perennial vegetable"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/6c824bec-9666-42d6-a7e0-91d65c0ba87c | por | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Γνωμοδότηση της Οικονομικής και Κοινωνικής Επιτροπής με θέμα «Για μια νέα δυναμική στις σχέσεις μεταξύ της Ευρωπαϊκής Ένωσης και του ASEAN» | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"ASEAN",
"EU relations",
"cooperation policy",
"economic relations",
"trade relations"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/b5d765a2-9473-4767-b3f2-a69686fc3d10 | ell | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
97/169/ΕΚ: Απόφαση της Επιτροπής της 30ής Ιανουαρίου 1997 για την περάτωση της διαδικασίας αντιντάμπινγκ σχετικά με τις εισαγωγές στην Ισπανία ορισμένων τσιμέντων Portland καταγωγής Ρουμανίας, Τυνησίας και Τουρκίας | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Spain",
"anti-dumping legislation",
"cement",
"import",
"originating product",
"third country"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/1fe01c43-1450-4f67-a3cd-bc9c0c2d9d82 | ell | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGOLAMENTO (CE) N. 168/97 DELLA COMMISSIONE del 30 gennaio 1997 che modifica il regolamento (CE) n. 2993/94 che fissa gli aiuti per l'approvvigionamento delle Canarie in prodotti del settore lattiero-caseario nel quadro del regime previsto dagli articoli da 2 a 4 del regolamento (CEE) n. 1601/92 del Consiglio | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Canary Islands",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply",
"supply balance sheet"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/f4114a94-a4b1-44e3-b5aa-e675eb5bcea7 | ita | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Kommissionens förordning (EG) nr 164/97 av den 30 januari 1997 om undantagsåtgärder till stöd för nöttköttsmarknaden i Frankrike genom tillämpning av kommissionens beslut 97/18/EG | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | swe | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Talous- ja sosiaalikomitean lausunto aiheesta "Euroopan unionin ja ASEANin suhteiden uusi dynamiikka" | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"ASEAN",
"EU relations",
"cooperation policy",
"economic relations",
"trade relations"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/b5d765a2-9473-4767-b3f2-a69686fc3d10 | fin | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGOLAMENTO (CE) N. 166/97 DELLA COMMISSIONE del 30 gennaio 1997 che fissa le restituzioni all'esportazione nel settore del latte e dei prodotti lattiero-caseari | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"export refund",
"milk",
"milk product"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/16f0e789-75e8-4867-bc90-7233569d9860 | ita | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Κανονισμός (ΕΚ) αριθ. 164/97 της Επιτροπής της 30ής Ιανουαρίου 1997 για τη θέσπιση έκτακτων μέτρων στήριξης της αγοράς βοείου κρέατος στη Γαλλία με την εφαρμογή της απόφασης 97/18/ΕΚ | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | ell | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Direttiva 97/6/CE della Commissione del 30 gennaio 1997 che modifica la direttiva 70/524/CEE del Consiglio relativa agli additivi nell'alimentazione degli animali (Testo rilevante ai fini del SEE) | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"animal nutrition",
"antibiotic",
"food additive",
"food chemistry",
"foodstuffs legislation",
"veterinary drug"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/bb896151-d74b-4918-acdc-cb20345cf86c | ita | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Decisão do Comité Misto do EEE nº 1/97 de 30 de Janeiro de 1997 que altera o anexo II (regulamentação técnica, normas, ensaios e certificação) do Acordo EEE | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | por | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Décision du Comité mixte de l'EEE nº 1/97 du 30 janvier 1997 modifiant l'annexe II (réglementations techniques, normes, essais et certification) de l'accord EEE | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | fra | [
"fmx4",
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print",
"xhtml"
] | null |
COMMISSION REGULATION (EC) No 168/97 of 30 January 1997 amending Regulation (EC) No 2993/94 fixing the aid for the supply of milk products to the Canary Islands under the arrangements provided for in Articles 2 to 4 of Council Regulation (EEC) No 1601/92 | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Canary Islands",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply",
"supply balance sheet"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/f4114a94-a4b1-44e3-b5aa-e675eb5bcea7 | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
QUESTION ECRITE no 137/97 des députes Claudio AZZOLINI , Antonio TAJANI au Conseil. Suppression des bateaux de pêche à l'espadon en Italie | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EC Decision",
"EU financing",
"FIFG",
"Italy",
"fishing net",
"fishing vessel",
"redevelopment aid",
"sea fish",
"summary procedure",
"vocational retraining"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/39620153-c815-4170-a277-f29c8cabbfb5 | fra | [
"html",
"print"
] | null |
Décision de la Commission du 30 janvier 1997 portant clôture de la procédure antidumping concernant les importations en Espagne de certains ciments Portland originaires de Roumanie, de Tunisie et de Turquie | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Spain",
"anti-dumping legislation",
"cement",
"import",
"originating product",
"third country"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/1fe01c43-1450-4f67-a3cd-bc9c0c2d9d82 | fra | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
VERORDENING (EG) Nr. 173/97 VAN DE COMMISSIE van 30 januari 1997 houdende wijziging van de restituties die worden toegepast voor bepaalde producten van de sector granen en de sector rijst, uitgevoerd in de vorm van niet in bijlage II van het Verdrag vermelde goederen | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal flour",
"cereals",
"export refund",
"groat",
"meal",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/c59d856e-0ced-4bee-8347-9375a372f4a3 | nld | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Rozhodnutí Smíšeného výboru EHP č. 1/97 ze dne 30. ledna 1997, kterým se mění příloha II (Technické předpisy, normy, zkoušení a certifikace) Dohody o EHP | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | ces | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 224
CS
Úřední věstník Evropské unie
11/sv. 2
21997D0327(02)
L 85/66
ÚŘEDNÍ VĚSTNÍK EVROPSKÝCH SPOLEČENSTVÍ
27.3.1997
ROZHODNUTÍ SMÍŠENÉHO VÝBORU EHP
č. 1/97
ze dne 30. ledna 1997,
kterým se mění příloha II (Technické předpisy, normy, zkoušení a certifikace) Dohody o EHP
SMÍŠENÝ VÝBOR EHP,
s ohledem na Dohodu o Evropském hospodářském prostoru ve znění Protokolu o úpravě Dohody
o Evropském hospodářském prostoru (dále jen „Dohoda“), a zejména s ohledem na článek 98 této dohody,
vzhledem k tomu, že příloha II Dohody byla změněna rozhodnutím Smíšeného výboru EHP č. 76/96 (1);
vzhledem k tomu, že směrnice Evropského parlamentu a Rady 95/28/ES ze dne 24. října 1995
o hořlavosti materiálů vnitřní výbavy určitých kategorií motorových vozidel (2) by měla být začleněna do
Dohody,
ROZHODL TAKTO:
Článek 1
V kapitole I přílohy II Dohody se za bod 45s (směrnice Evropského parlamentu a Rady 95/1/ES) vkládá
nový bod, který zní:
„45t. 395 L 0028: Směrnice Evropského parlamentu a Rady 95/28/ES ze dne 24. října 1995
o hořlavosti materiálů vnitřní výbavy určitých kategorií motorových vozidel (Úř. věst. L 281,
23.11.1995, s. 1).“
Znění směrnice 95/28/ES v islandském a norském jazyce, která tvoří přílohu odpovídajících jazykových
verzí tohoto rozhodnutí, jsou platná.
Článek 2
Článek 3
Toto rozhodnutí vstupuje v platnost dnem 1. února 1997 za předpokladu, že Smíšenému výboru EHP jsou
učiněna veškerá oznámení podle čl. 103 odst. 1 Dohody.
Toto rozhodnutí bude zveřejněno v oddíle EHP a v dodatku EHP Úředního věstníku Evropských společenství.
Článek 4
V Bruselu dne 30. ledna 1997.
Za Smíšený výbor EHP
předsedkyně
C. DAY
(1) Dosud nezveřejněné v Úředním věstníku.
(2) Úř. věst. L 281, 23.11.1995, s. 1.
|
WRITTEN QUESTION No. 148/97 by Amedeo AMADEO to the Council. Solvency ratio for credit institutions | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"approximation of laws",
"credit guarantee",
"credit institution",
"financial solvency",
"ratio",
"share capital"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/762b4ae5-517f-4c96-9c18-1a5624baaa76 | eng | [
"print"
] | null |
COMMISSION REGULATION (EC) No 167/97 of 30 January 1997 amending Regulation (EEC) No 2219/92 laying down detailed rules for the application of the specific supply arrangements for Madeira relating to milk products regarding the amounts of aid | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Madeira",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/fc4de31e-646f-497f-9e26-919a05b5cacd | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGLAMENTO (CE) N° 168/97 DE LA COMISIÓN de 30 de enero de 1997 por el que se modifica el Reglamento (CE) n° 2993/94 por el que se fijan las ayudas para el abastecimiento de productos lácteos a las islas Canarias en virtud del régimen establecido en los artículos 2 a 4 del Reglamento (CEE) n° 1601/92 del Consejo | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Canary Islands",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply",
"supply balance sheet"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/f4114a94-a4b1-44e3-b5aa-e675eb5bcea7 | spa | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
KOMISSION ASETUS (EY) N:o 171/97, annettu 30 päivänä tammikuuta 1997, vilja- ja riisialan tuotantotukien vahvistamisesta | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereals",
"production refund",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/d196500f-e7d3-4057-a252-876f0dc521b1 | fin | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
RÈGLEMENT (CE) N° 173/97 DE LA COMMISSION du 30 janvier 1997 modifiant les taux des restitutions applicables à certains produits des secteurs des céréales et du riz exportés sous forme de marchandises ne relevant pas de l'annexe II du traité | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal flour",
"cereals",
"export refund",
"groat",
"meal",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/c59d856e-0ced-4bee-8347-9375a372f4a3 | fra | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Kommissionens förordning (EG) nr 168/97 av den 30 januari 1997 om ändring av förordning (EG) nr 2993/94 om fastställande av stöd för försörjning av Kanarieöarna med mjölkprodukter inom ramen för den ordning som fastställs i artiklarna 2-4 i rådets förordning (EEG) nr 1601/92 | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Canary Islands",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply",
"supply balance sheet"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/f4114a94-a4b1-44e3-b5aa-e675eb5bcea7 | swe | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
PERGUNTA ESCRITA n. 155/97 do Deputado Amedeo AMADEO ao Conselho. Produtos transformados à base de limões | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU aid",
"citrus fruit",
"economic support",
"food processing",
"fruit product",
"production aid"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/13c80ef1-d42a-4b24-b30c-52d51c02a6a9 | por | [
"print"
] | null |
Gemensamma EES-kommitténs beslut nr 1/97 av den 30 januari 1997 om ändring av bilaga II (tekniska föreskrifter, standarder, provning och certifiering) till EES-avtalet | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | swe | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
For more information about employment, competitiveness and solidarity United Kingdom and Northern Ireland. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU employment policy",
"European social policy",
"Northern Ireland",
"United Kingdom",
"access to EU information"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/36adcff9-139a-4021-8689-bf505f5af380 | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Odluka Zajedničkog odbora EGP-a br. 1/97 od 30. siječnja 1997. o izmjeni Priloga II. (Tehnički propisi, norme, ispitivanje i potvrđivanje) Sporazumu o EGP-u | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | hrv | [
"fmx4",
"pdfa1a",
"print",
"xhtml"
] |
L_1997085HR.01006601.xml
11/Sv. 055
HR
Službeni list Europske unije
46
21997D0327(02)
L 085/66
SLUŽBENI LIST EUROPSKE UNIJE
30.01.1997.
ODLUKA ZAJEDNIČKOG ODBORA EGP-a
br. 1/97
od 30. siječnja 1997.
o izmjeni Priloga II. (Tehnički propisi, norme, ispitivanje i potvrđivanje) Sporazumu o EGP-u
ZAJEDNIČKI ODBOR EGP-a,
uzimajući u obzir Sporazum o Europskom gospodarskom prostoru, kako je prilagođen Protokolom o prilagodbi Sporazuma o Europskom gospodarskom prostoru, dalje u tekstu „Sporazum”, a posebno njegov članak 98.,
budući da je Prilog II. Sporazumu izmijenjen Odlukom Zajedničkog odbora EGP-a br. 76/96 (1);
budući da Direktivu 95/28/EZ Europskog parlamenta i Vijeća od 24. listopada 1995. o ponašanju materijala pri gorenju koji se upotrebljavaju u unutarnjoj konstrukciji određenih kategorija motornih vozila (2), treba unijeti u Sporazum,
ODLUČIO JE:
Članak 1.
Iza točke 45.s (Direktiva 95/1/EZ Europskog parlamenta i Vijeća) u poglavlju I. Priloga II. Sporazumu umeće se sljedeća točka:
„45.t
395 L 0028: Direktiva 95/28/EZ Europskog parlamenta i Vijeća od 24. listopada 1995. o ponašanju materijala pri gorenju koji se upotrebljavaju u unutarnjoj konstrukciji određenih kategorija motornih vozila (SL L 281, 23.11.1995., str. 1.).”
Članak 2.
Tekstovi Direktive 95/28/EZ na islandskom i norveškom jeziku koji su priloženi odnosnim jezičnim inačicama ove Odluke, vjerodostojni su.
Članak 3.
Ova Odluka stupa na snagu 1. veljače 1997., pod uvjetom da su sve obavijesti iz članka 103. stavka 1. Sporazuma podnesene Zajedničkom odboru EGP-a.
Članak 4.
Ova se Odluka objavljuje u odjeljku o EGP-u i Dodatku o EGP-u Službenom listu Europskih zajednica.
Sastavljeno u Bruxellesu 30. siječnja 1997.
Za Zajednički odbor EGP-a
Predsjednik
C. DAY
(1) Još nije objavljeno u Službenom listu.
(2) SL L 281, 23.11.1995., str. 1.
|
COMMISSION REGULATION (EC) No 170/97 of 30 January 1997 fixing the export refunds on cereal-based compound feedingstuffs | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"animal nutrition",
"cereal product",
"export refund"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/04408c59-a2d6-404b-9452-aeb9d64fa228 | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Reglamento (CE) nº 164/97 de la Comisión de 30 de enero de 1997 por el que se adoptan medidas excepcionales de apoyo al mercado de carne de vacuno de Francia en aplicación de la Decisión 97/18/CE | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | spa | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
QUESTION ECRITE no 155/97 de Amedeo AMADEO au Conseil. Produits transformés à base de citrons | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU aid",
"citrus fruit",
"economic support",
"food processing",
"fruit product",
"production aid"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/13c80ef1-d42a-4b24-b30c-52d51c02a6a9 | fra | [
"print"
] | null |
EMP Ühiskomitee otsus nr 1/97, 30. jaanuar 1997, millega muudetakse EMP lepingu II lisa (tehnilised normid, standardid, katsetamine ja sertifitseerimine) | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | est | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 224
ET
Euroopa Liidu Teataja
11/2. kd
21997D0327(02)
L 85/66
EUROOPA ÜHENDUSTE TEATAJA
27.3.1997
EMP ÜHISKOMITEE OTSUS
nr 1/97,
30. jaanuar 1997,
millega muudetakse EMP lepingu II
lisa
(tehnilised normid,
standardid, katsetamine ja
sertifitseerimine)
EMP ÜHISKOMITEE,
võttes arvesse Euroopa Majanduspiirkonna lepingut, mida on kohandatud Euroopa Majanduspiirkonna
lepingut kohandava protokolliga, edaspidi “leping”, eelkõige selle artiklit 98,
ning arvestades, et:
lepingu II lisa muudeti EMP Ühiskomitee 13. detsembri 1996. aasta otsusega nr 76/96; (1)
lepingusse tuleb lisada Euroopa Parlamendi ja nõukogu 24. oktoobri 1995. aasta direktiiv 95/28/EÜ teata-
vate mootorsõidukikategooriate siseehituses kasutatavate materjalide põlemiskäitumise kohta, (2)
ON VASTU VÕTNUD JÄRGMISE OTSUSE:
Artikkel 1
Lepingu II lisa I peatüki punkti 45s (Euroopa Parlamendi ja nõukogu direktiiv 95/1/EÜ) järele lisatakse
järgmine punkt:
“45t. 395 L 0028: Euroopa Parlamendi ja nõukogu direktiiv 95/28/EÜ teatavate mootorsõidukikate-
gooriate siseehituses kasutatavate materjalide põlemiskäitumise kohta (EÜT L 281, 23.11.1995,
lk 1).”.
Artikkel 2
Euroopa Parlamendi ja nõukogu direktiivi 95/28/EÜ islandi- ja norrakeelne tekst, mis on lisatud käesoleva
otsuse vastavates keeltes versioonidele, on autentne.
Käesolev otsus jõustub 1. veebruaril 1997 tingimusel, et kõik lepingu artikli 103 lõikes 1 ettenähtud teated
on EMP Ühiskomiteele esitatud.
Artikkel 3
Käesolev otsus avaldatakse Euroopa Ühenduste Teataja EMP osas ja EMP kaasandes.
Artikkel 4
Brüssel, 30. jaanuar 1997
EMP Ühiskomitee nimel
eesistuja
C. DAY
(1) Euroopa Ühenduste Teatajas seni avaldamata.
(2) EÜT L 281, 23.11.1995, lk 1.
|
COMMISSION REGULATION (EC) No 169/97 of 30 January 1997 fixing the export refunds on products processed from cereals and rice | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal product",
"export refund",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/b0e0de66-7f97-4e7c-95b7-42bc50eb4039 | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
KOMISSION ASETUS (EY) N:o 172/97, annettu 30 päivänä tammikuuta 1997, tuonnin kiinteistä arvoista tiettyjen hedelmien ja vihannesten tulohinnan määrittämiseksi | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"citrus fruit",
"fruit vegetable",
"import price",
"perennial vegetable"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/6c824bec-9666-42d6-a7e0-91d65c0ba87c | fin | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
SKRIFTLIG FORESPØRGSEL nr. 148/97 af Amedeo AMADEO til Rådet. Solvensnøgletal for kreditinstitutter | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"approximation of laws",
"credit guarantee",
"credit institution",
"financial solvency",
"ratio",
"share capital"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/762b4ae5-517f-4c96-9c18-1a5624baaa76 | dan | [
"print"
] | null |
ΚΑΝΟΝΙΣΜΟΣ (ΕΚ) αριθ. 173/97 ΤΗΣ ΕΠΙΤΡΟΠΗΣ της 30ής Ιανουαρίου 1997 για τροποποίηση των ποσοστών των επιστροφών που εφαρμόζονται σε ορισμένα προϊόντα των τομέων των σιτηρών και της όρυζας που εξάγονται υπό μορφή εμπορευμάτων που δεν υπάγονται στο παράρτημα ΙΙ της συνθήκης | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal flour",
"cereals",
"export refund",
"groat",
"meal",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/c59d856e-0ced-4bee-8347-9375a372f4a3 | ell | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
KOMISSION ASETUS (EY) N:o 166/97, annettu 30 päivänä tammikuuta 1997, maito- ja maitotuotealan vientitukien vahvistamisesta | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"export refund",
"milk",
"milk product"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/16f0e789-75e8-4867-bc90-7233569d9860 | fin | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Directiva 97/6/CE da Comissão de 30 de Janeiro de 1997 que altera a Directiva 70/524/CEE relativa aos aditivos na alimentação para animais (Texto relevante para efeitos do EEE) | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"animal nutrition",
"antibiotic",
"food additive",
"food chemistry",
"foodstuffs legislation",
"veterinary drug"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/bb896151-d74b-4918-acdc-cb20345cf86c | por | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
RÈGLEMENT (CE) N° 170/97 DE LA COMMISSION du 30 janvier 1997 fixant les restitutions à l'exportation des aliments composés à base de céréales pour les animaux | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"animal nutrition",
"cereal product",
"export refund"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/04408c59-a2d6-404b-9452-aeb9d64fa228 | fra | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGLAMENTO (CE) N° 167/97 DE LA COMISIÓN de 30 de enero de 1997 por el que se modifica el Reglamento (CEE) n° 2219/92 por el que se establecen las disposiciones de aplicación del régimen específico para el abastecimiento de productos lácteos a Madeira en lo que respecta a los importes de la ayuda | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Madeira",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/fc4de31e-646f-497f-9e26-919a05b5cacd | spa | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
SCHRIFTELIJKE VRAAG nr. 137/97 van de leden Claudio AZZOLINI , Antonio TAJANI aan dee Raad. Afschaffing van drijfnetten voor zwaardvisvangst in Italië | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EC Decision",
"EU financing",
"FIFG",
"Italy",
"fishing net",
"fishing vessel",
"redevelopment aid",
"sea fish",
"summary procedure",
"vocational retraining"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/39620153-c815-4170-a277-f29c8cabbfb5 | nld | [
"print"
] | null |
REGULAMENTO (CE) Nº 171/97 DA COMISSÃO de 30 de Janeiro de 1997 que fixa as restituições à produção nos sectores dos cereais e do arroz | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereals",
"production refund",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/d196500f-e7d3-4057-a252-876f0dc521b1 | por | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Komisjoni määrus (EÜ) nr 164/97, 30. jaanuar 1997, millega kehtestatakse veiselihaturu toetamise erandmeetmed Prantsusmaal otsuse 97/18/EÜ kohaldamisel | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | est | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 240
ET
Euroopa Liidu Teataja
03/20. kd
31997R0164
31.1.1997
EUROOPA ÜHENDUSTE TEATAJA
L 29/1
KOMISJONI MÄÄRUS (EÜ) nr 164/97,
30. jaanuar 1997,
millega kehtestatakse veiselihaturu toetamise erandmeetmed Prantsusmaal otsuse 97/18/EÜ
kohaldamisel
EUROOOPA ÜHENDUSTE KOMISJON,
ON VASTU VÕTNUD KÄESOLEVA MÄÄRUSE:
võttes arvesse Euroopa Ühenduse asutamislepingut,
Artikkel 1
võttes arvesse nõukogu 27.
juuni 1968. aasta määrust (EMÜ)
nr 805/68 veise- ja vasikalihaturu ühise korralduse kohta, (1)
viimati muudetud määrusega (EÜ) nr 2222/96, (2) eriti selle ar-
tiklit 23,
Prantsusmaal
lubatakse maksta kompensatsiooni nende
1.
veiste eest, keda peetakse Prantsusmaa territooriumil asuvas
põllumajandusettevõttes ja kes tapetakse otsusega 97/18/EÜ
heakskiidetud Prantsuse likvideerimiskava järgi.
ning arvestades, et:
komisjon kiitis oma otsusega 97/18/EÜ (3) heaks Prantsusmaa
esildatud meetmed BSE-tõve tõrjumiseks ja likvideerimiseks
selles liikmesriigis; eespool nimetatud otsuse kohaselt tuleks
Prantsusmaale kõnealuste loomade tapmiseks anda rahalist abi
vastavalt põhimõtetele, mis on sätestatud komisjoni 19. aprilli
1996. aasta määruses (EÜ) nr 716/96, millega kehtestatakse
erimeetmed Ühendkuningriigis, (4)
veiselihaturu
viimati muudetud määrusega (EÜ) nr 2423/96 (5); järelikult on
kohane kehtestada ühenduse toetuseks 70 % tapetud loomade
turuväärtusest; Prantsusmaa seab turuväärtuse kindlakstegemi-
seks sisse süsteemi, mis tagab iga looma õiglase ja objektiivse
hindamise;
toetamise
on vaja tagada, et kõnealused loomad tapetaks ja hävitataks
viisil, mis ei ohusta inimeste ega teiste loomade tervist; seetõttu
on vaja täpsustada nende loomade hävitamise ja Prantsuse
ametiasutuste poolt teostatava kontrolli tingimused;
2.
Lõikes 1 osutatud loomad tapetakse kas põllumajanduset-
tevõttes või jäätmetehases. Ükski eespool osutatud loomade osa
ei tohi sattuda inimeste või loomade toiduahelasse, samuti ei
tohi neid kasutada kosmeetika- või farmaatsiatoodetes.
Hoolimata esimeses lõigus sätestatust
ja vastavalt vajalikule
kontrollile transporditakse loomad pärast põllumajanduset-
tevõttes tapmist viivitamata jäätmetehasesse töötlemiseks ja
hävitamiseks.
3.
Prantsusmaa pädev asutus:
— saab hoolimata lõikest 1 loa enne loomade töötlemist ja
hävitamist tapetud loomade ajust võetud proove laboratoor-
selt uurida,
— saab loa enne tapetud loomade töötlemist ja hävitamist
kasutada piiratud hulka loomi uurimis- või õppe-eesmärgil,
— korraldab vajalikke halduskontrolle ja tõhusat kohapealset
järelevalvet lõikes 2 osutatud toimingute suhtes, ning
tuleb sätestada komisjoni ekspertide võimalus kontrollida
täpsustatud tingimuste täitmist;
— kontrollib neid toiminguid sagedaste ja etteteatamata reidide
alusel, eelkõige selleks, et veenduda, kas kogu saadud
materjal on tegelikult hävitatud.
käesolevas määruses sätestatud meetmed on kooskõlas veise- ja
vasikalihaturu korralduskomitee arvamusega,
Nende kontrollimiste ja ülevaatuste tulemused tehakse taotluse
korral kättesaadavaks komisjonile.
(1) EÜT L 148, 28.6.1968, lk 24.
(2) EÜT L 296, 21.11.1996, lk 50.
(3) EÜT L 6, 10.1.1997, lk 43.
(4) EÜT L 99, 20.4.1996, lk 14.
(5) EÜT L 329, 19.12.1996, lk 43.
4.
Lõikes 1 nimetatud loomade nahku ei pea hävitama,
tingimusel et neid on töödeldud viisil, mis laseb neid kasutada
ainult nahatoodete valmistamisel.
03/20. kd
ET
Euroopa Liidu Teataja
241
Artikkel 2
1.
Kompensatsioonisumma looma kohta, mille artikli 1
lõike 1 kohaselt Prantsusmaa maksab tootjatele või nende
vahendajatele, võrdub iga kõnealuse looma objektiivse turu-
väärtusega Prantsusmaal, mis tehakse kindlaks Prantsuse pädeva
asutusega kokkulepitud objektiivse hindamissüsteemi alusel.
Ühendus kaasrahastab 70 % kulutustest, mis on seotud
2.
lõikes 1 osutatud kompensatsiooniga artikli 1 kohaselt tapetud
loomade eest.
Hoolimata lõikes 1 sätestatust on Prantsuse pädeval
lubatud maksta käesoleva kava alusel tapetud veiste
3.
asutusel
eest lisasummasid. Ühendus ei kaasrahasta selliseid kulutusi.
Artikkel 3
tagamaks selle
Prantsusmaa võtab kõik vajalikud meetmed,
kava asjakohane rakendamine. Ta teavitab komisjoni võetud
meetmetest ja neisse tehtud muudatustest niipea kui võimalik.
Prantsuse pädev asutus:
Artikkel 4
— tapetud loomade keskmise turuväärtuse, ja
— artikli 2 lõikes 3 osutatud lisasummade koguväärtuse;
b) koostab igas kvartalis üksikasjaliku aruande nendest kont-
rollreididest, mis on korraldatud vastavalt artiklis 3 osutatud
meetmetele, ja edastab selle igas kvartalis komisjonile.
Artikkel 5
Ilma et see piiraks nõukogu määruse (EMÜ) nr 729/70 (1) artik-
li 9 kohaldamist, korraldavad komisjoni eksperdid, keda vaja-
duse korral saadavad liikmesriikide eksperdid, koostöös Prant-
suse pädeva asutusega kohapealseid kontrolle, et veenduda
käesoleva määruse kõigi sätete järgimises.
Artikkel 6
Käesoleva määruse kohaselt võetud meetmeid peetakse sekku-
mismeetmeteks määruse (EMÜ) nr 729/70 artiklis 3 määrat-
letud tähenduses.
Artikkel 7
a) teatab viivitamata iga kord, kui
rakendatakse artiklis 1
osutatud plaani, komisjonile käesoleva kava kohaselt:
— tapmiseks välja valitud loomade arvu,
— tapetud loomade arvu,
Käesolev määrus jõustub selle Euroopa Ühenduste Teatajas aval-
damise päeval.
Seda rakendatakse alates 1. aprillist 1996.
Käesolev määrus on tervikuna siduv ja vahetult kohaldatav kõikides liikmesriikides.
Brüssel, 30.
jaanuar 1997
Komisjoni nimel
komisjoni liige
Franz FISCHLER
(1) EÜT L 94, 28.4.1970, lk 13.
|
ΚΑΝΟΝΙΣΜΟΣ (ΕΚ) αριθ. 168/97 ΤΗΣ ΕΠΙΤΡΟΠΗΣ της 30ής Ιανουαρίου 1997 για την τροποποίηση του κανονισμού (ΕΚ) αριθ. 2993/94 για τον καθορισμό των ενισχύσεων για τον εφοδιασμό των Καναρίων Νήσων σε γαλακτοκομικά προϊόντα στο πλαίσιο του καθεστώτος που προβλέπεται στα άρθρα 2 έως 4 του κανονισμού (ΕΟΚ) αριθ. 1601/92 του Συμβουλίου | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Canary Islands",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply",
"supply balance sheet"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/f4114a94-a4b1-44e3-b5aa-e675eb5bcea7 | ell | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Uredba Komisije (ES) št. 164/97 z dne 30. januarja 1997 o sprejemu izrednih ukrepov podpore trgu z govejim mesom v Franciji pri uporabi Odločbe 97/18/ES | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | slv | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 240
SL
Uradni list Evropske unije
03/Zv. 20
31997R0164
31.1.1997
URADNI LIST EVROPSKIH SKUPNOSTI
L 29/1
UREDBA KOMISIJE (ES) št. 164/97
z dne 30. januarja 1997
o sprejemu izrednih ukrepov podpore trgu z govejim mesom v Franciji pri uporabi Odločbe
97/18/ES
KOMISIJA EVROPSKIH SKUPNOSTI JE
SPREJELA NASLEDNJO UREDBO:
ob upoštevanju Pogodbe o ustanovitve Evropske skupnosti,
Člen 1
ob upoštevanju Uredbe Sveta (EGS) št. 805/68 z dne 27. junija
1968 o skupni ureditvi trga za goveje in telečje meso (1), kakor
je bila nazadnje spremenjena z Uredbo (ES) št. 2222/96 (2),
zlasti člena 23 Uredbe,
Franciji se dovoli plačilo odškodnine za goveje živali, ki
1.
se nahajajo na kmetijskih gospodarstvih na ozemlju Francije in
so zaklane v skladu s francoskim načrtom za zatiranje, ki je bil
odobren z Odločbo 97/18/ES.
je z Odločbo Komisije 97/18/ES (3) Komisija sprejela
ker
ukrepe, ki
jih je predlagala Francija za nadzor in zatiranje
bolezni BSE v tej državi članici; ker je treba v skladu z zgoraj
navedeno Odločbo Franciji zagotoviti
finančno pomoč za
izvedbo zakola prizadetih živali v skladu s smernicami, ki jih
določa Uredba Komisije (ES) št. 716/96 z dne 19. aprila 1996
o sprejemu izrednih ukrepov podpore za trg govejega mesa v
Združenem kraljestvu (4), kakor je bila nazadnje spremenjena z
Uredbo (ES) št. 2423/96 (5); ker je zaradi tega primerno predvi-
deti sofinanciranje Skupnosti v višini 70 % tržne vrednosti
zaklanih živali; ker naj za določitev tržne vrednosti Francija
uvede sistem, s katerim zagotovi pošteno in objektivno vredno-
tenje vsake živali;
ker je treba zagotoviti, da so prizadete živali pobite in uničene
na način, ki ne predstavlja nobene nevarnosti za zdravje ljudi
ali zdravje drugih živali; glede na to, da je zato treba podrobno
določiti pogoje za uničenje teh živali in nadzor, ki ga izvajajo
francoski organi;
2.
Živali iz odstavka 1 se pobije bodisi na kmetiji ali v kafi-
leriji. Noben del zgoraj opredeljenih živali ne sme priti v
človeške ali živalske prehrambene verige ali se uporabiti v
kozmetičnih ali farmacevtskih proizvodih.
Ne glede na prvi pododstavek in ob upoštevanju potrebnega
nadzora se živali po usmrtitvi na kmetiji takoj prepelje v kafile-
rijo v predelavo in uničenje.
3.
Pristojni francoski organi:
— smejo, ne glede na odstavek 1, pred predelavo in uničenjem
poslati v laboratorijski pregled vzorec možganov zaklanih
živali,
— smejo pred predelavo in uničenjem uporabiti omejeno
število živali v raziskovalne in izobraževalne namene,
— izvedejo potrebne upravne preglede in učinkovit nadzor na
kraju samem postopkov iz odstavka 2 in
ker je treba določiti, da strokovnjaki Komisije nadzorujejo
skladnost z navedenimi pogoji;
— nadzirajo te postopke na podlagi pogostih in nenajavljenih
pregledov, predvsem da bi se prepričali, da je bil ves mate-
rial učinkovito uničen.
ker so ukrepi, predvideni s to uredbo, v skladu z mnenjem
Upravljalnega odbora za goveje in telečje meso,
Rezultate teh pregledov, nadzora in preskusov se na zahtevo da
na voljo Komisiji.
(1) UL L 148, 28.6.1968, str. 24.
(2) UL L 296, 21.11.1996, str. 50.
(3) UL L 6, 10.1.1997, str. 43.
(4) UL L 99, 20.4.1996, str. 14.
(5) UL L 329, 19.12.1996, str. 43.
4.
Kože živali iz odstavka 1 ni treba uničiti pod pogojem, da
so bile obdelane na tak način, da se jih lahko uporabi samo za
proizvodnjo usnja.
03/Zv. 20
SL
Uradni list Evropske unije
241
Člen 2
1.
Višina odškodnine na žival, ki jo Francija plača rejcem ali
njihovim zastopnikom po členu 1(1), je enaka objektivni tržni
vrednosti v Franciji za vsako tako žival, določeni na podlagi
sistema objektivnega vrednotenja, ki so ga sprejeli pristojni
organi v Franciji.
Stroške v zvezi z višino odškodnine iz odstavka 1 sofi-
2.
nancira Skupnost v višini 70 % za živali, zaklane v skladu s
členom 1.
3.
Ne glede na odstavek 1 lahko pristojni francoski organ
izplača dodatne zneske za govedo, zaklano po tej shemi. Skup-
nost takšnih stroškov ne sofinancira.
Člen 3
Francija sprejme vse potrebne ukrepe za zagotovitev pravilne
uporabe te sheme. Komisijo v najkrajšem možnem času obvesti
o sprejetih ukrepih ter o kakršnih koli spremembah teh
ukrepov.
Pristojni francoski organi:
Člen 4
— povprečni tržni vrednosti zaklanih živali in
— skupni višini dodatnih plačil iz člena 2(3)
po tej shemi;
(b) pripravijo podrobno poročilo o nadzoru, ki ga izvajajo po
ukrepih iz člena 3 in ga vsako četrtletje pošljejo Komisiji.
Člen 5
Brez poseganja v določbe člena 9 Uredbe Sveta (EGS)
št. 729/70 (1) izvedenci Komisije, ki jih, kadar je to primerno,
spremljajo izvedenci iz držav članic, izvedejo v sodelovanju s
francoskimi organi oblasti preglede na kraju
pristojnimi
samem, s katerimi preverijo, ali so upoštevane vse določbe te
uredbe.
Člen 6
Ukrepi, sprejeti po tej uredbi, veljajo za intervencijske ukrepe v
smislu člena 3 Uredbe (EGS) št. 729/70.
Člen 7
(a) vsakič, ko se uporabi načrt iz člena 1, obvestijo Komisijo o:
— številu živali, določenih za zakol,
— številu zaklanih živali,
Ta uredba začne veljati z dnem objave v Uradnem listu Evropskih
skupnosti.
Uporablja se z učinkom od 1. aprila 1996.
Ta uredba je v celoti zavezujoča in se neposredno uporablja v vseh državah članicah.
V Bruslju, 30. januarja 1997
Za Komisijo
Franz FISCHLER
Član Komisije
(1) UL L 94, 28.4.1970, str. 13.
|
Om er meer van te weten over werkgelegenheid, groei, concurrentievermogen en solidariteit : België. Deel 7.,Pour en savoir plus concernant l'emploi, la croissance, la compétitivité et la solidarité : Belgique. Volume 7. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Belgium",
"EU employment policy",
"European social policy",
"access to EU information"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/5593af16-623e-4487-9f6e-613fba407252 | nld | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
WRITTEN QUESTION No. 155/97 by Amedeo AMADEO to the Council. Products processed from lemons | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU aid",
"citrus fruit",
"economic support",
"food processing",
"fruit product",
"production aid"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/13c80ef1-d42a-4b24-b30c-52d51c02a6a9 | eng | [
"print"
] | null |
KOMMISSIONENS FÖRORDNING (EG) nr 167/97 av den 30 januari 1997 om ändring av förordning (EEG) nr 2219/92 om tillämpningsföreskrifter för den särskilda försörjningsordningen för Madeira avseende mjölkprodukter gällande stödens storlek | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Madeira",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/fc4de31e-646f-497f-9e26-919a05b5cacd | swe | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
KOMMISSIONENS FÖRORDNING (EG) nr 172/97 av den 30 januari 1997 om fastställande av schablonvärden vid import för bestämning av ingångspriset för vissa frukter och grönsaker | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"citrus fruit",
"fruit vegetable",
"import price",
"perennial vegetable"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/6c824bec-9666-42d6-a7e0-91d65c0ba87c | swe | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Besluit van de Commissie van 30 januari 1997 tot beëindiging van de antidumpingprocedure in verband met de invoer in Spanje van Portlandcement van oorsprong uit Roemenië, Turkije en Tunesië | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Spain",
"anti-dumping legislation",
"cement",
"import",
"originating product",
"third country"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/1fe01c43-1450-4f67-a3cd-bc9c0c2d9d82 | nld | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
KOMISSION ASETUS (EY) N:o 169/97, annettu 30 päivänä tammikuuta 1997, vilja- ja riisijalosteiden vientiin sovellettavien tukien vahvistamisesta | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal product",
"export refund",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/b0e0de66-7f97-4e7c-95b7-42bc50eb4039 | fin | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
VERORDNUNG (EG) Nr. 172/97 DER KOMMISSION vom 30. Januar 1997 zur Festlegung pauschaler Einfuhrwerte für die Bestimmung der im Sektor Obst und Gemüse geltenden Einfuhrpreise | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"citrus fruit",
"fruit vegetable",
"import price",
"perennial vegetable"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/6c824bec-9666-42d6-a7e0-91d65c0ba87c | deu | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
RÈGLEMENT (CE) N° 167/97 DE LA COMMISSION du 30 janvier 1997 modifiant le règlement (CEE) n° 2219/92 portant modalités d'application du régime spécifique pour l'approvisionnement de Madère en produits laitiers en ce qui concerne le montant des aides | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Madeira",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/fc4de31e-646f-497f-9e26-919a05b5cacd | fra | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Sverige. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU employment policy",
"European social policy",
"Sweden",
"access to EU information"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/bb7c7c35-b934-46e8-87ba-50667e3e42ee | swe | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGOLAMENTO (CE) N. 171/97 DELLA COMMISSIONE del 30 gennaio 1997 che fissa le restituzioni alla produzione nel settore dei cereali e del riso | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereals",
"production refund",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/d196500f-e7d3-4057-a252-876f0dc521b1 | ita | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
VERORDNUNG (EG) Nr. 170/97 DER KOMMISSION vom 30. Januar 1997 zur Festsetzung der Ausfuhrerstattungen für Getreidemischfuttermittel | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"animal nutrition",
"cereal product",
"export refund"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/04408c59-a2d6-404b-9452-aeb9d64fa228 | deu | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
1997 m. sausio 30 d. Komisijos reglamentas (EB) Nr. 164/97, patvirtinantis išskirtines paramos priemones Prancūzijos jautienos rinkai, taikant Sprendimą 97/18/EB | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | lit | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 240
LT
Europos Sąjungos oficialusis leidinys
31997R0164
1997 1 31
EUROPOS BENDRIJŲ OFICIALUSIS LEIDINYS
KOMISIJOS REGLAMENTAS (EB) Nr. 164/97
1997 m. sausio 30 d.
patvirtinantis išskirtines paramos priemones Prancūzijos jautienos rinkai,
taikant Sprendimą
97/18/EB
EUROPOS BENDRIJŲ KOMISIJA,
PRIĖMĖ ŠĮ REGLAMENTĄ:
03/20 t.
L 29/1
atsižvelgdama į Europos bendrijos steigimo sutartį,
1 straipsnis
atsižvelgdama į 1968 m. birželio 27 d. Tarybos reglamentą
(EEB) Nr. 805/68 dėl bendro galvijienos
rinkos organiza-
vimo (1) su paskutiniais pakeitimais, padarytais Reglamentu (EB)
Nr. 2222/96 (2), ypač į jo 23 straipsnį,
Prancūzija įpareigojama mokėti kompensaciją už jos teri-
1.
torijoje esančių ūkių galvijus, paskerstus remiantis Sprendimu
97/18/EB patvirtintu Prancūzijos planu, skirtu likviduoti BSE.
kadangi Komisija Komisijos sprendimu 97/18/EB (3) patvirtino
Prancūzijos pasiūlytas priemones, skirtas kontroliuoti ir likvi-
duoti BSE toje valstybėje narėje; kadangi pagal pirmiau minėtą
sprendimą finansinė pagalba Prancūzijai už minimų gyvūnų
paskerdimą turėtų būti suteikta laikantis 1996 m. balandžio
19 d. Komisijos reglamente (EB) Nr. 716/96, patvirtinančiame
išskirtines Jungtinės Karalystės jautienos rinkos rėmimo prie-
mones (4), su paskutiniais pakeitimais, padarytais Reglamentu
(EB) Nr. 2423/96 (5), nustatytų gairių; kadangi
tam tikslui
reikėtų numatyti, kad Bendrija padengtų 70 % paskerstų
gyvūnų rinkos vertės; kadangi gyvūno rinkos vertei nustatyti
sąžiningą ir objektyvų kiekvieno
Prancūzija turėtų sukurti
gyvūno įvertinimą garantuojančią sistemą;
kadangi būtina užtikrinti, kad minimi gyvūnai būtų nužudyti ir
sunaikinti taip, kad nekiltų grėsmė žmonių ar kitų gyvūnų svei-
katai; kadangi tam būtina nurodyti šių gyvūnų sunaikinimo ir
Prancūzijos valdžios institucijų atliktinų patikrinimų reikala-
vimus;
kadangi reikėtų numatyti, kad Bendrijos ekspertai tikrintų nuro-
dytų reikalavimų laikymąsi;
2.
1 dalyje minėti gyvūnai nužudomi ūkyje arba utilizavimo
įmonėje. Jokia pirmiau minėtų gyvūnų skerdenų dalis neturi
patekti į maisto ar pašarų grandines ar būti naudojama kosme-
tikos produktams arba vaistams gaminti.
Nepaisant pirmos pastraipos nuostatų ir taikant būtiną kont-
rolę, ūkyje nužudyti gyvūnai nedelsiant vežami
į utilizavimo
įmonę, kur perdirbami ir sunaikinami.
3.
Prancūzijos kompetentinga institucija:
— nepaisant šio straipsnio 1 dalies nuostatų,
prieš perdirbimą
gyvūnų smegenų bandinių laboratorinius tyrimus,
sunaikinimą
arba
įpareigojama
vykdyti paskerstų
— gali prieš perdirbimą arba sunaikinimą naudoti
gyvūnų skaičių tyrimams arba informacijai gauti,
ribotą
— atlieka būtinus 2 ir 3 dalyse nurodytų operacijų administra-
cinius patikrinimus ir veiksmingą priežiūrą vietoje ir
— kontroliuoja minėtas operacijas
ir
netikėtais patikrinimais, ypač siekiant įsitikinti, kad buvo
veiksmingai sunaikintos visos skerdenų dalys.
remdamasi dažnais
kadangi šiame reglamente numatytos priemonės atitinka Galvi-
jienos vadybos komiteto nuomonę,
Minėtų patikrinimų ir kontrolės priemonių rezultatai prieinami
Komisijai jos prašymu.
(1) OL L 148, 1968 6 28, p. 24.
(2) OL L 296, 1996 11 21, p. 50.
(3) OL L 6, 1997 1 10, p. 43.
(4) OL L 99, 1996 4 20, p. 14.
(5) OL L 329, 1996 12 19, p. 43.
4.
Šio straipsnio 1 dalyje minėtų gyvūnų odų nereikia
naikinti, jei jos apdorotos taip, kad tiktų tik odos gaminiams
gaminti.
03/20 t.
LT
Europos Sąjungos oficialusis leidinys
241
2 straipsnis
— vidutinę paskerstų gyvūnų rinkos vertę, ir
1.
Kompensacijos suma už gyvūną, kurią Prancūzija gamin-
tojams arba jų tarpininkams turi mokėti pagal 1 straipsnio
1 dalies nuostatas, yra lygi objektyviai kiekvieno gyvūno vertei
Prancūzijos rinkoje, nustatytai remiantis objektyvaus vertinimo
sistema, kuriai pritarė Prancūzijos kompetentinga institucija.
2 straipsnio 3 dalyje minėtas papildomas sumas (bendrą
sumą);
b) parengia išsamią ataskaitą apie kontrolės priemones, kurias
jos įgyvendina remdamosi 3 straipsnyje nurodytomis prie-
monėmis, ir perduoda ją Komisijai kiekvieną ketvirtį.
Bendrija finansuoja 70 % išlaidų, susijusių su 1 dalyje
nuostatas
pagal 1 straipsnio
už
2.
minėta
paskerstus gyvūnus suma.
kompensacijos
Nepaisant 1 dalies nuostatos, Prancūzijos kompetentingai
leidžiama išmokėti papildomas sumas už galvijus,
3.
institucijai
paskerstus pagal šią sistemą. Šių išlaidų Bendrija nefinansuoja.
3 straipsnis
Prancūzija patvirtina visas būtinas priemones, užtikrinančias
visišką šio reglamento nuostatų laikymąsi.
Ji kuo greičiau
praneša Komisijai apie taikytas priemones ir apie visus jų pakei-
timus.
4 straipsnis
Prancūzijos kompetentinga institucija:
5 straipsnis
Tarybos
(EEB) Nr. 729/70 (1)
Nepažeisdami
reglamento
9 straipsnio nuostatų, Komisijos ekspertai, prireikus kartu su
valstybių narių ekspertais, bendradarbiaudami su Prancūzijos
kompetentingomis institucijomis atlieka patikrinimus vietoje,
kad įsitikintų, ar laikomasi visų šio reglamento nuostatų.
6 straipsnis
Priemonės, taikytos remiantis šiuo reglamentu, laikomos inter-
vencinėmis priemonėmis, kaip apibrėžta Reglamento (EEB)
Nr. 729/70 3 straipsnyje.
7 straipsnis
a) kiekvienąkart, kai taikomas 1 straipsnyje nurodytas planas,
nedelsdama praneša Komisijai pagal šią sistemą:
— skerdimui atrinktų gyvūnų skaičių,
— paskerstų gyvūnų skaičių,
Šis reglamentas įsigalioja jo paskelbimo Europos Bendrijų oficia-
liajame leidinyje dieną.
Jis taikomas nuo 1996 m. balandžio 1 d.
Šis reglamentas yra privalomas visas ir tiesiogiai taikomas visose valstybėse narėse.
Priimta Briuselyje, 1997 m. sausio 30 d.
Komisijos vardu
Franz FISCHLER
Komisijos narys
(1) OL L 94, 1970 4 28, p. 13.
|
KOMMISSIONENS FÖRORDNING (EG) nr 171/97 av den 30 januari 1997 om fastställande av produktionsbidragen för spannmål och ris | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereals",
"production refund",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/d196500f-e7d3-4057-a252-876f0dc521b1 | swe | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Para mayor información en torno al empleo, el crecimiento, la competitividad y la solidaridad : España. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU employment policy",
"European social policy",
"Spain",
"access to EU information"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e18bbb9c-f334-4af8-9bb2-8e07ab620588 | spa | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
SCHRIFTELIJKE VRAAG nr. 148/97 van Amedeo AMADEO aan dee Raad. Solvabiliteitsratio voor kredietinstellingen | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"approximation of laws",
"credit guarantee",
"credit institution",
"financial solvency",
"ratio",
"share capital"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/762b4ae5-517f-4c96-9c18-1a5624baaa76 | nld | [
"print"
] | null |
Реорганизация и производственная кооперация : пример сектора деревообработки. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"CIS countries",
"EU programme",
"Mongolia",
"Russia",
"technical cooperation",
"wood industry"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/613603ab-e4f5-4c07-819c-47efc730f991 | rus | [
"pdfa1b",
"print_stpl"
] | null |
KOMMISSIONENS FÖRORDNING (EG) nr 173/97 av den 30 januari 1997 om ändring av bidragssatserna för vissa spannmåls- och risprodukter som exporteras i form av varor som inte omfattas av bilaga II till fördraget | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal flour",
"cereals",
"export refund",
"groat",
"meal",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/c59d856e-0ced-4bee-8347-9375a372f4a3 | swe | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Für weitere Informationen zu den Themen Beschäftigung, Wachstum, Wettbewerbsfähigkeit und Solidarität : Österreich. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Austria",
"EU employment policy",
"European social policy",
"access to EU information"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e716971f-233a-48c2-b8cd-2eedd3fbe821 | deu | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Règlement (CE) nº 164/97 de la Commission du 30 janvier 1997 arrêtant des mesures de soutien exceptionnelles en faveur du marché de la viande bovine en France en application de la décision 97/18/CE | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | fra | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGLAMENTO (CE) N° 172/97 DE LA COMISIÓN de 30 de enero de 1997 por el que se establecen valores globales de importación para la determinación del precio de entrada de determinadas frutas y hortalizas | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"citrus fruit",
"fruit vegetable",
"import price",
"perennial vegetable"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/6c824bec-9666-42d6-a7e0-91d65c0ba87c | spa | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
ΚΑΝΟΝΙΣΜΟΣ (ΕΚ) αριθ. 172/97 ΤΗΣ ΕΠΙΤΡΟΠΗΣ της 30ής Ιανουαρίου 1997 για καθορισμό των κατ' αποκοπή τιμών κατά την εισαγωγή για τον καθορισμό της τιμής εισόδου ορισμένων οπωροκηπευτικών | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"citrus fruit",
"fruit vegetable",
"import price",
"perennial vegetable"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/6c824bec-9666-42d6-a7e0-91d65c0ba87c | ell | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Komisjoni direktiiv 97/6/EÜ, 30. jaanuar 1997, millega muudetakse nõukogu direktiivi 70/524/EMÜ söödalisandite kohtaEMPs kohaldatav tekst | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"animal nutrition",
"antibiotic",
"food additive",
"food chemistry",
"foodstuffs legislation",
"veterinary drug"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/bb896151-d74b-4918-acdc-cb20345cf86c | est | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 250
ET
Euroopa Liidu Teataja
03/20. kd
31997L0006
5.2.1997
EUROOPA ÜHENDUSTE TEATAJA
L 35/11
KOMISJONI DIREKTIIV 97/6/EÜ,
30. jaanuar 1997,
millega muudetakse nõukogu direktiivi 70/524/EMÜ söödalisandite kohta
(EMPs kohaldatav tekst)
EUROOPA ÜHENDUSTE KOMISJON,
võttes arvesse Euroopa Ühenduse asutamislepingut,
võttes arvesse nõukogu 23. novembri 1970. aasta direktiivi
70/524/EMÜ söödalisandite kohta, (1) viimati muudetud direk-
tiiviga 96/66/EÜ, (2) eriti selle artiklit 11,
ning arvestades, et:
vastavalt direktiivi 70/524/EMÜ artiklile 11 võib liikmesriik,
kellel on uue teabe või pärast asjakohaste sätete vastuvõtmist
olemasoleva teabe ümberhindamise tulemusena üksikasjalikud
tõendid selle kohta, et mõne I lisas loetletud söödalisandi kasu-
tamine on ohtlik loomade või inimeste tervisele või keskkon-
nale, ajutiselt peatada kõnealuse söödalisandi kasutusloa;
ja Saksamaa keelasid vastavalt 20. mail 1995 ja
Taani
19.
jaanuaril 1996 oma territooriumil antibiootikumi avopart-
siini kasutamise loomasöödas; kooskõlas direktiivi 70/524/EMÜ
sätetega teatasid mõlemad liikmesriigid teistele liikmesriikidele
ja komisjonile oma otsuse põhjused, mis olid üksikasjalikult ja
nõuetekohaselt argumenteeritud; Taani
selle teabe
20. mail ja 13.
juulil 1995 ning Saksamaa 5. märtsil 1996;
edastas
väites, et loomadele antud sööda kaudu tekitab see glüktopep-
tiidide hulka kuuluv antibiootikum resistentsust inimmeditsiinis
kasutatavate glüktopeptiidide suhtes, on Taani
ja Saksamaa
seisukohal, et avopartsiin kujutab ohtu inimeste tervisele; nende
arvamuse kohaselt võib see resistentsuse ülekandumine piirata
tähtsa, üksnes inimeste raskete nakkushaiguste ravimisel või
ennetamisel kasutatava antibiootikumide klassi tõhusust ning
sellest
tulenevalt ei ole täidetud üks direktiivi 70/524/EMÜ
alusel nõutavatest tingimustest söödalisandi lubamise kohta;
komisjon on konsulteerinud söötade teaduskomiteega; pärast
olukorra põhjalikku uurimist jõudis kõnealune komitee oma
21. mail 1996. aastal esitatud otsuses järeldusele, et kuna glük-
topeptiidide suhtes resistentsete loomse päritoluga organismide
(enterokokkide) või nende geenide
inimeste
haigustes puuduvad põhjusliku seose kindlaksmääramiseks krii-
tilise tähtsusega algandmed, ei ole vajalik glüktopeptiidide kasu-
jaoks jätta; komitee tunnistab
tamist üksnes inimmeditsiini
suhtes
rolli
ja Saksamaalt saadud aruanded tõstatavad
siiski, et Taanist
tõsiseid küsimusi, ning sedastab, et soovitab avopartsiini kasuta-
mise söödalisandina läbi vaadata niipea, kui tõestatakse, et resis-
tentsuse ülekandumine loomadelt inimestele on võimalik; lisaks
sellele soovitab komitee ettevaatusabinõuna, et ühtki muud
glüktopeptiidi, millel on avopartsiiniga sarnane antibiootiline
mõjupiirkond ja toimemehhanism, ei kiideta heaks enne, kui
komitee on rahul uuringu tulemustega, mis tuleb eelnevalt läbi
viia;
kuigi andmed ei ole piisavad, et lõplikult kindlaks määrata resis-
tentsuse ülekandumise riski, millele Saksamaa ja Taani tugi-
nevad, ei luba kättesaadavad tõendid seda riski täpsema teadus-
liku teabeta kindlalt välistada;
läbi tuleks viia erinevaid uuringuid, et teha täpsemalt kindlaks
loomasöötades kasutatavate söödalisandite tekitatud ja inimes-
tele ülekantud resistentsus antibiootikumide suhtes; kiiresti
tuleb
elavate
antibiootikume
mikroobide resistentsuse järelevalvesüsteem;
loomades
saavates
luua
sellises ebakindluse õhkkonnas on soovitatav olla äärmiselt ette-
vaatlik ja vältida mis tahes riskide võtmist, mis võiksid vähen-
dada teatud inimmeditsiinis oluliste glüktopeptiidide, nagu
näiteks vankomütsiini tõhusust;
avopartsiini kasutamise keelamist tuleb käsitleda esialgse kaitse-
ning ettevaatusabinõuna, mille võib uuesti
läbi vaadata, kui
avopartsiini söödalisandina kasutamise kohta väljendatud kaht-
lused edasisi uuringuid ning sisseseatavaid järelevalveprog-
ramme silmas pidades hajuvad;
käesolevas direktiivis sätestatud meetmed on kooskõlas alalise
söödakomitee arvamusega,
ON VASTU VÕTNUD KÄESOLEVA DIREKTIIVI:
Artikkel 1
(1) EÜT L 270, 14.12.1970, lk 1.
(2) EÜT L 272, 25.10.1996, lk 32.
Direktiivi 70/524/EMÜ I lisa muudetakse vastavalt käesoleva
direktiivi lisale.
03/20. kd
ET
Euroopa Liidu Teataja
251
Artikkel 2
Komisjon vaatab enne 31. detsembrit 1998 käesoleva direktiivi
sätted uuesti läbi, võttes aluseks tulemused, mis on saadud:
2.
Liikmesriigid edastavad komisjonile käesoleva direktiiviga
reguleeritavas valdkonnas nende poolt vastuvõetud siseriiklike
põhiliste õigusnormide teksti.
— mitmesugustest
eriti
glükopeptiidide kasutamise tõttu kujuneva resistentsuse
kohta, ja
antibiootikumide,
uurimistöödest
— antibiootikume saavates loomades elavate mikroobide resis-
tentsuse järelevalveprogrammi tulemusena, mida teostavad
eelkõige asjaomaste söödalisandite ringlusse laskmise eest
vastutavad isikud.
Artikkel 3
1.
Liikmesriigid jõustavad käesoleva direktiivi lisa täitmiseks
vajalikud õigusnormid hiljemalt 1. aprillil 1997. Liikmesriigid
teatavad sellest viivitamata komisjonile.
Kui liikmesriigid need meetmed võtavad, lisavad nad nendesse
meetmetesse või nende meetmete ametliku avaldamise korral
nende juurde viite käesolevale direktiivile. Sellise viitamise viisi
näevad ette liikmesriigid.
Artikkel 4
Käesolev direktiiv jõustub kolmandal päeval pärast selle avalda-
mist Euroopa Ühenduste Teatajas.
Artikkel 5
Käesolev direktiiv on adresseeritud liikmesriikidele.
Brüssel, 30.
jaanuar 1997
Komisjoni nimel
komisjoni liige
Franz FISCHLER
252
ET
Euroopa Liidu Teataja
03/20. kd
Käesolevaga jäetakse direktiivi 70/524/EMÜ I lisa A osast “Antibiootikumid” välja kanne nr E715 “avopartsiin” koos
kõigi asjakohaste üksikasjadega (keemiline valem, kirjeldus, looma liik või kategooria, vanuse ülempiir, miinimumsi-
saldus, maksimumsisaldus, muud sätted).
LISA
|
VERORDENING (EG) Nr. 172/97 VAN DE COMMISSIE van 30 januari 1997 tot vaststelling van forfaitaire invoerwaarden voor de bepaling van de invoerprijzen van bepaalde soorten groenten en fruit | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"citrus fruit",
"fruit vegetable",
"import price",
"perennial vegetable"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/6c824bec-9666-42d6-a7e0-91d65c0ba87c | nld | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Regulamento (CE) nº 164/97 da Comissão de 30 de Janeiro de 1997 que adopta medidas excepcionais de apoio ao mercado de carne de bovino em França, em aplicação da Decisão 97/18/CE | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | por | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Per saperne di più sull'occupazione, la crescita, la competitività e la solidarietà : Italia. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU employment policy",
"European social policy",
"Italy",
"access to EU information"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/12bd034e-c829-11e6-a6db-01aa75ed71a1 | ita | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Impianto semiindustriale per il colaggio in continuo di nastri : progetti pilota e dimostrativi. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"industrial research",
"iron and steel product",
"research report",
"special steels",
"steel"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/52f41bd3-436c-11ea-b81b-01aa75ed71a1 | ita | [
"pdf",
"pdfx",
"print"
] | |
Labour market studies : Finland. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Finland",
"economic analysis",
"labour market"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/a099d59c-4139-4a8d-8564-5e70175285af | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"pdfx",
"print"
] | [**M\ Series ΝΊ Labour Market Studies
FINLAND
Employment & social affairs
European Commission
Labour Market Studies
Finland
By
The Finnish Labour Market Institute for Economic Research
and
ECOTEC Research and Consulting Ltd
December 1996
This report was f i n a n c ed by a nd p r e p a r ed for the use of the European
Commission, Directorate-General
Industrial Relations
a nd Social Affairs.
It does not necessarily represent the Commission's
official position.
for Employment,
A great deal of additional information on the European Union is available on the Internet.
It can be accessed through the Europa server (http://europa.eu.int)
Cataloguing data can be found at the end of this publication
Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1997
ISBN 92-827-8754-0
© ECSC-EC-EAEC, Brussels · Luxembourg, 1997
Reproduction is authorized, except for commercial purposes, provided the source is acknowledged
Printed in Belgium
A report by
The Finnish Labour Market Institute for Economic Research
and
ECOTEC Research and Consulting Ltd
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION
SUMMARY
1 ANALYSIS OF THE LABOUR MARKET SITUATION
1.1 Demographic trends
1.1.1 Size and structure of the population, 1980-1995
1.1.2 Developments in the labour force, 1980-1995
1.1.3 Labour force projections, 1995-2005
1.2 Structure of the workforce
1.2.1 Labour force participation
1.2.2 Size and composition of employment
1.2.3 Patterns of work
1.2.4 Level and structure of unemployment
1.3 Main trends in job creation and job loss
1.4 Wages and salary trends
1.4.1 Inter-industry wage dispersion
1.4.2 The gender wage gap
1.4.3 Minimum wages
1.4.4 Individual pay differentials
1.4.5 Real wage flexibility
4
5
12
12
12
13
14
16
16
18
21
23
27
29
29
30
31
31
32
1.5 Analysis of the principal causes of the rise in unemployment since 1980
35
1.5.1 Developments in the 1980s
1.5.2 Economic crisis in the 1990s
2 LABOUR MARKET INSTITUTIONS
2.1 Public Institutions
2.2 Collective Wage Bargaining
2.2.1 Labour relations
2.2.2 Collective bargaining procedure
2.2.3 Dealing with conflicts
2.2.4 Pressures for change
2.3 Participation systems and personnel funds
2.3.1 Participation systems
2.3.2 Personnel funds
35
36
39
39
40
40
41
44
45
46
46
47
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
3 LABOUR MARKET LEGISLATION 49
3.1 Employment Protection Schemes 49
3.1.1 The current position 49
3.1.2 Rules of recruitment 50
3.1.3 Rules of individual and collective dismissals 51
3.1.4 Recent debate and policy actions 52
3.2 Regulation of Working Time 54
3.2.1 Working hours 54
3.2.2 Annual leave 55
3.2.3 Career breaks and work sharing 55
3.3 Minimum Wage Regulation 59
4 LABOUR MARKET POLICIES 61
4.1 Passive measures 61
4.1.1 Unemployment benefit schemes: Basic characteristics and recent
developments 61
4.1.2 Unemployment benefit schemes: The present position 61
4.1.3 Reform of the unemployment benefit schemes in Spring 1996 66
4.1.4 Funding of the unemployment benefit schemes 67
4.1.5 Unemployment pension scheme 68
4.1.6 The balance of passive and active measures 69
4.2 Active measures 70
4.3 Implementation of active labour market policy measures by public
employment offices 75
4.4 Description of existing active measures 77
4.4.1 Employment subsidy for employers 77
4.4.2 Labour market training 78
4.4.3 Apprenticeship training 79
4.4.4 Start-up grants 80
4.4.5 Part-time pay supplement 81
4.4.6 Job rotation scheme 82
4.5 Evaluation of good practice in active measures 83
5 OTHER POLICIES HAVING AN IMPACT ON THE LABOUR MARKET 86
5.1 Macro-economic policies 86
5.2 Education and vocational training 90
5.3 Tax and benefit 94
5.4 Industrial policies 96
■ 2-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
6 THE NATIONAL DEBATE: POLICY PERSPECTIVES
6.1 Macro-economic conditions
6.2 Income taxation
6.3 Labour market deregulation
6.4 Work sharing
REFERENCES
INDEX
ANNEX
99
99
99
101
102
103
108
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
INTRODUCTION
This report provides an account of the labour market in Finland. It was produced for
the European Commission, DG V (Directorate-General for Employment, Industrial
Relations and Social Affairs) by the Finnish Labour Institute for Economic Research,
who carried out the research and drafted the report, which was edited by ECOTEC
Research and Consulting Ltd. At the Labour Institute for Economic Research, the
report was written by Dr. Tuire Santamäki-Vuori in co-operation with Ms. Silve
Parviainen, M.Sc.
This study is one of a series of reports covering all the fifteen member states. Their
aims are to take stock and analyse labour market developments in the EU in order to
inform employment policies in the light of the conclusions of the Essen Summit:
the promotion of investments in vocational training
the increase in the employment-intensiveness of growth
the lowering of indirect wage costs
the increase in the effectiveness of labour market policy
the strengthening of measures for groups particularly affected by unemployment.
The report is structured in six sections, as follows:
• Section 1 provides an analysis of the labour market situation in Finiand. It examines
the background to the labour market by considering: demographic trends; the
structure of the workforce; trends in job creation, job loss and wages and salaries;
and the causes of unemployment.
• Section 2 describes the main labour market institutions, including public
employment services, collective wage bargaining and employee participation
systems.
• Section 3 examines labour market legislation. This section includes a discussion of
employment protection schemes, regulations on working time and minimum
wages.
• Section 4 describes Finland's labour market policies, in terms of both active and
passive measures. Implementation of active measures by public bodies is
discussed and the range of existing active labour market policy measures are
described. This section concludes with an evaluation of good practice in active
measures.
• Section 5 presents an overview of other policies which have an impact on the
labour market and which are not discussed in Section 4. The discussion Includes,
therefore, macro-economic policies, policies on education and training, taxation
and social security and industrial policies.
The final Section places the discussion in the report in the context of the national
debate in Finland. This Section examines current debate in the areas of macro-
economic policy and conditions, income taxation, deregulation of the labour
market and work sharing. A short summary of the report is presented before Section
1.
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
SUMMARY
The labour market context
In Finland, the 15-64 working age group grew by 5% from 1980 to 1995. Overall,
population growth has been attributed to natural growth, or the excess of births over
deaths (4.7 million in 1980 and 5.1 million in 1995), The excess is falling, however, and
by the year 2013, the number of deaths is expected to exceed that of births.
Since the early 1980s, migration into Finland has also contributed to population
growth. The number of foreign citizens was about 70,000 at the end of 1995,
compared with approximately 15,000 in the mid-1980s.
Evidence shows that the growth in the population is accompanied by an ageing of
the population. Until recently, the working age proportion of the population was
relatively high. However, the proportion of people aged under 25 in the working age
group (15-64 years) declined from 23% in 1980 to 18% in 1995.
Projections of the labour force also reflect the general ageing of the population. It is
predicted that almost 30% of the labour force will be aged over 50 in 2005,
compared to 20% in 1995.
Economic recovery and growth is polarised with rapid growth in exports and
industrial production and a modest revival in domestic consumption. Overall,
employment growth has been slow. There has been concern about the slow
reduction of the unemployment rate and about the prospect of jobless growth in
the economy.
This, together with concerns about the growth of female unemployment, are
contributing to a debate about the need for a more balanced growth across all
sectors of the economy. The role of wages, Indirect labour costs, value-added taxes
and personal income taxation as contributory factors to increases in demand in the
private service sector has been widely acknowledged.
The labour force participation rate of young people dropped sharply during the
recession of the early 1990s, although recent data show an improvement in the rate.
The labour market position of low-skilled workers has been worsening relative to
those with higher skill levels. Workers with basic education tend to have lower labour
force participation rates and higher unemployment rates.
Unemployment rose dramatically from 3.4% in 1990 to a peak of 18,4% in 1994.
Hitherto, Finland's unemployment rate had been below the OECD average. A large
proportion of the rise in unemployment can be attributed to the increase in the
recurrence of spells of unemployment and, in particular, to the lengthening of
unemployment periods. Average periods of continuous unemployment rose from 15
weeks in 1990 to 45 weeks in 1995.
The unemployment rate started to fall in Finland in 1995, although long-term
unemployment is projected to continue rising. The proportion of unemployed people
who have been unemployed for 12 months or more has risen from 3% in 1990 to
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
almost 30% in 1996. Economic recovery is not, therefore, removing the problem of
long-term unemployment.
Labour market institutions
Finland's network of public employment offices is a branch of the Ministry of Labour.
There are 13 regional labour districts and 183 local employment offices. Public
employment services include: job placement; vocational guidance; labour market
training; information on training and occupational choice; and vocational
retraining. Until 1994, there was a public monopoly of employment services provision,
although permits could be granted to private associations for job-placement
services. Private provision of the range of employment services is now permitted,
although there has been little take-up by the private sector,
Traditionally, the Finnish Labour Market has been highly organised. The right to
organise is safeguarded by the Constitution and the right to bargain collectively is
guaranteed through a system of collective agreements, based on legislation, The
extent of unionisation among wage-earners has grown during the last few years, In
line with the increase in unemployment. The high unionisation rate may also be
related to the fact that membership fees are tax deductible and that the unions are
involved in the administration of unemployment insurance,
Collective bargaining amongst labour market organisations is not governed by
statutory regulations. In practice, negotiations begin with central organisations
producing an agreement on the general principles. This provides the framework for
subsequent negotiations at the union level, which are aimed at producing collective
agreements. Talks on implementing the agreements are then held at workplaces.
Collective agreements prescribe the minimum terms to be observed in all
employment contracts. An employer bound by a collective agreement is required
to observe the provisions in respect of non-unionised workers, unless they have
specific exclusion, under the terms of the agreement. If a nation-wide, universal
collective agreement applies in a given sector, the agreement is automatically
extended to unorganised employers in that sector. The main function of a universally
binding collective agreement is to give workers in non-organised enterprises the
same minimum employment conditions as enjoyed by organised workers. Collective
agreements cover more than 90% of employees. The proportion covered via
extensions based on universal validity has been estimated at about 20%. In the
service industry, in particular, there are sectors with no universally binding collective
agreements to guarantee minimum terms of employment.
The main challenge for the Finnish unions In the next few years is to adjust their
bargaining strategies to a target of low inflation. This is not easy within the multi-level
bargaining structure. It is feasible that within the constraints set by collective
agreements, there will be more firm-specific arrangements related to performance
pay schemes, profit sharing, work organisation and training. In the European
context, the main question will be whether the labour market organisations will find it
advisable to co-ordinate their actions on a national or on an international level. At
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
this stage, it is not clear what direction the unions and employers' organisations will
take.
Labour market legislation and policies
Employment protection in Finland traditionally has been developed co-operatively
by employers' and employees' representatives and the State. New legislation has
often been drawn up on the basis of case law, although in recent reforms intended
to relax employment protection, the Government has adopted a more proactive
stance.
Total labour market policy expenditure averaged 2,5% of GDP from 1985 to 1991, It
reached almost 7% In 1993 and 1994, as a result of the rise in unemployment.
However, expenditure on passive measures, adjusted for unemployment, declined
between 1990 and 1993. Expenditure on active measures accounted for 25% of total
labour market expenditure in 1993 and 1994, despite the expressed target of
resorting more to active than to passive measures,
Among Finland's passive measures are unemployment benefit schemes based on
both insurance and assistance principles. There was a major change in 1985, when
both insurance benefit and the basic allowance became liable to tax and
insurance benefit became earnings-related. In 1994, basic unemployment
allowance was changed with the introduction of a qualifying condition relating to
employment record and a maximum payment duration. Importantly, new labour
market support was Introduced for people who are not eligible for the benefits or
whose benefits have been exhausted.
In May 1996, the Government submitted to Parliament proposals for reform of
unemployment benefit schemes. Extensive changes are planned, to be
implemented from the beginning of 1997, The changes include extensions of
qualifying conditions for the benefit and no index adjustments to the level of benefits
in 1997-1999. These reforms ore aimed at improving the functioning of the labour
market and at making savings in unemployment expenditure. The changes also
make the distinction between active and passive measures less clear-cut.
In addition to the unemployment allowance, there is also an unemployment pension
scheme, which is intended to provide income security for long-term unemployed
people aged 60-64 who have received unemployment allowance for the maximum
period.
A new impetus was given to active labour market programmes by the 1987
Employment Act. The Act reinforced the policy emphasis on young and long-term
unemployed people. In addition, the Act was intended to balance regional
discrepancies so that unemployment in any district would not be dissimilar to the
country average. Statutory obligations to arrange training or work for young and
long-term unemployed people were lifted in 1993, although such groups continue to
be the main targets for active labour market policy measures.
In the early 1990s, there was a doubling of active labour market policy measures.
However, the coverage of the measures decreased substantially, since there was a
7-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
large Increase in the number of unemployed job-seekers. The overall coverage of
active measures among all unemployed people fell from more than 30% in 1988-
1990, to less than 20% since 1992.
The role of active measures in terminating spells of unemployment has remained
fairly stable, hovering between 22% and 25% of total terminated spells. Due to
differences in employment prospects in the normal labour market and the priority
given to young and long-term unemployed people when targeting active measures,
the importance of active measures in terminating unemployment spells varies across
different groups of unemployed job-seekers.
Macro-economic policies
The Government, appointed in April 1995, set itself the objective of halving
unemployment (i.e. to 9% by 1999) and turning central government indebtedness
into decline by the end of Its four-year election period. Strong competitiveness and
lower real Interest rates were considered to be essential preconditions for sustained
economic growth and a permanent reduction in unemployment. The austerity
measures which had been implemented by the previous Government were
maintained and new expenditure cuts totalling FIM 20 billion, or 3.5% of GDP, were
agreed by the new Government.
In September 1995, the Council of State adopted the Finnish convergence
programme describing the measures necessary to satisfy the criteria for monetary
union. Some of the Government's targets, such as public finances and the halving of
unemployment, are more demanding than the criteria of the convergence
programme itself. At this time, Finland was projected to have good prospects of
satisfying all the convergence criteria within the next few years. It was anticipated
that general government net lending would be balanced and indebtedness would
stabilise as soon as 1996. As to labour market performance, the unemployment rate
was expected to be down to 12.5% In 1999. The Government's objective of halving
unemployment would require a further fall of 100,000 in the number of unemployed
people.
However, since the beginning of 1996, economic conditions have been less
favourable. Short-term economic projections for 1996 and 1997 have also been less
optimistic. Despite this, the preconditions for faster growth in years to come do exist;
real interest rates have fallen, prices are competitive and household indebtedness
has decreased, allowing a revival in the housing market, for instance. Economic
growth is generally expected to rebound in the latter half of 1996. This is based
largely on a similar scenario of the gradual speeding-up of economic growth in the
EU. Despite slower growth, the current account will be in surplus, the general
government deficit is falling, inflation Is extremely low, the long-term incomes
agreement should keep prices down for the next few years and the floating of the
markka has not prompted any major turbulence In interest rates.
The fact that economic development has been less robust than expected means,
however, that the public budget deficit will not be reduced as fast as originally
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
planned. Even so, the government economy will go on improving, and in 1997 the
general government financial deficit will probably be one of the lowest in the EU.
It is clear that the poorer economic outlook will result in few positive labour market
developments. The slow fall In unemployment means that the problem of long-term
unemployment has become more serious. Some 10% of the labour force can now
be counted as long-term unemployed, if the figures Include recurrent
unemployment Interrupted by short-term periods of work or traineeship. The need to
reduce long-term unemployment has become a priority for all structural policies
designed to promote job creation.
Education and vocational training policies
The number of students in education has increased sharply, so that in the early 1990s
enrolment rates were almost four times those of 1960. Currently, over 90% of young
people continue in upper secondary education and nearly 60% of the relevant age
group qualify for a place at university. Such increases have acted as a buffer
against the impact of the deteriorating position of young people in the labour
market.
There has also been a considerable increase in adult education. Almost 3% of the
adult population attend open university and about 25% make use of liberal
education institutes. Vocational training Is encouraged through a study leave
system, which provides people with a financial contribution from the state for their
studies. New starts in long-term self-motivated vocational training tripled between
1989 and 1993, although recent cuts in adult study grants has led to lower
participation in such training In 1995,
Overall, the volume of adult training has been regarded as inadequate to meet ever
increasing needs. There has been a tendency for training to accumulate among
those with the best qualifications. This group of people also has the highest
expressed need for additional training. The mismatch between expressed need and
actual participation in training is greatest among those with lower educational
qualifications. This may be taken as an indication of hidden willingness to undertake
further education, in particular among the least educated people. To provide equal
opportunities for adequate adult training, a discussion about regular training under
a kind of study insurance scheme has recently been raised.
It was proposed by the government that starter places In basic and further training
(Including apprenticeship training) should be increased by 33,000 in 1994 and that
the number of starter places would exceed the initial level by 34,000 in 1995.
However, the implementation of the proposals was delayed and the targets have
not been attained, Nevertheless, the aim to increase the number of training places
has not been abandoned; on the contrary, it forms a vital part of the multi-annual
employment programme, which was prepared for the meeting of the European
Council in December 1995.
Higher education and research is regarded as a vital part of Finland's development
strategy, According to the long term objectives, universities and polytechnics will
- 9-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
cater for 60-65% of the age group. The policy concerns In education are expansion
of the scope of programmes, provision of multi-disciplinary learning and wider
choice for individuals, The main aims in the near future are the flexibility of the
educational system as a whole, the development of evaluation systems and
widening the use of pathways. A system of lifelong learning Is to be created, where
educational modules are approved as part of a qualification.
Tax and benefit
The gross tax rate, or total taxes per GDP, in Finland is not high, although income
taxation is one of the highest in the EU. Action has been taken to reduce the rate of
income taxation and, in line with the 1995 incomes policy settlement, the
government Intends to continue to reduce income taxation in 1997.
There have been temporary reductions in the employers' share of unemployment
insurance expenditure, with the corresponding Increase in the central government
share financed by a special unemployment tax.
There has been concern about Incentive trcps. Proposed measures to tackle the
problems include alleviation of the taxation of small amounts of earned income,
alleviation of means-testing in unemployment benefits with respect to earned
income, as well as changes in the schemes for support care for small children. Efforts
have also been made to Identify any remaining inequalities in entitlement to social
security depending on the form of employment; in the existing schemes, thresholds
either on working hours or earnings may place atypical forms of employment at a
disadvantage in terms of annual or sick leave and employment pension.
Industrial policies
The government intends to promote competitiveness based on innovations, research
and development, skilled labour and high standards of environmental protection.
The creation of new jobs in SMEs and service enterprises is an important goal. The
government Is also committed to promoting job-creation in recycling and other
areas of environmental protection. Self-employment will be supported by promoting
service co-operatives. Active industrial policy also concerns state-owned
companies, which will be partly privatised. However, the state will retain its majority
ownership in some companies that are vital for the nation's energy supply. The value
of State property amounts to FIM 120 billion, of which FIM 50 billion is in equities.
Parliament has empowered the authorities to sell equities up to FIM 25 billlon,
The multi-annual employment programme spelt out policies to enhance
entrepreneurship and encourage local Initiatives. The national productivity
programme, which was launched In 1993 to raise productivity by developing the
quality and flexibility of working life, will continue until spring 1999. A similar
programme was introduced in 1996, with a focus on the development of skills and
Innovations based on local initiatives. The latter Involves research-driven
development within enterprises in co-operation with universities and research
institutes. Its core features are the development of multi-skilled work and teamwork in
organisations capable of using networking methods. Finally, an action programme
10-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
for developing the information society was initiated. Its aim is to provide all citizens
with the basic skills and technical opportunities to use the services of the information
society.
The national debate
There are four aspects which characterise the national debate about the labour
market in Finland:
• Macro-economic conditions.
Recently, the domestic economy has Improved - interest rates have fallen, the
current is in surplus, budget deficits are decreasing, inflation is low and household
Indebtedness has fallen. However, weak international developments, including
the unexpected halt in economic growth in Europe, have resulted in slower than
expected domestic economic growth.
• Easing of income taxation.
The government has decided that fiscal consolidation should be achieved
without any increase in the overall level of taxation, Capital and corporate tax
rates were raised from 25% to 28% In 1996 and an easing of the taxation of
earned income was initiated in 1996, through a reduction of employees' social
insurance fees. The government has agreed similar reductions In 1997 and 1998,
although scope for further shifts in the structure of taxation seem to be quite
limited.
• Further reforms and, in particular, deregulation in the labour market.
Most of the recommendations aimed at increasing labour market flexibility involve
the removal of existing constraints that are thought to worsen the functioning of
the labour market. Eliminating negative influences - rather than accentuating
positive ones through training, mobility or active labour market policies - has,
therefore, become the basis for improving the operation of the labour market.
• Work-sharing, as a means of increasing flexibility and employment.
As employment trends show improvements, the idea of work sharing is becoming
more popular. The hitherto voluntary basis of such arrangements has led to
tensions, although this means that a more prescriptive approach can now be
adopted.
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
7 ANALYSIS OF THE LABOUR MARKET SITUATION
1.1 Demographic trends
1.1.1 Size ond structure of the population, 1980-1995
There are two principal determinants of population size: demographic factors such
as birth and death rates; a nd migration. From 1980 to 1995, the 15-74 a ge group
grew by 6% (223,000 people) a nd the 15-64 a ge group by 5%. The Finnish Labour
Force Survey categorises people a g ed 15 to 74 as part of the working a ge
population, since many self-employed people continue to work beyond the normal
pension age. In 1995, the labour force participation rate a m o ng those a g ed 65-74
years was 3%, accounting for 13,000 people in the labour force. In the remainder of
this document, unless otherwise stated, labour market figures refer to the 15-74 a ge
group.
Population growth has mainly been attributed to natural growth, that is the excess of
births over deaths by some 15,000 people annually. The difference has steadily
narrowed, however, a nd from the year 2013 onwards, the number of deaths Is
projected to exceed that of births (Ministry of Labour, 1996a).
The total fertility rate has remained fairly stable during the past twenty years or so,
fluctuating between 1.6 a nd 1.85. The natural renewal of the population would
require a total fertility rate of 2.1. By European standards, the fertility rate is quite
high, although clearly lower than Ireland or Sweden. The difference in the total
fertility rate c o m p a r ed to the EU average seems to be attributed to differences in
family size rather than differences in the proportion of childless women. Moreover,
unlike most other countries, there has not been a downward trend in the Nordic
countries. Except for women under 25, the age-specific fertility rates have actually
risen (Komiteanmietintö, 1995),
Given the high educational level and high participation in full time work a m o ng
Finnish women, the relatively high fertility rate is quite striking. There is some evidence
that until the 1990s, generous family support (at 4.3% of GDP in 1991) may have
partly offset the declining birth rate that tends to a c c o m p a ny higher educational
and income levels amongst women (llmakunnas, 1994).
In any event, the decline in the number of births from over 100,000 during the post
war baby-boom years (1946-1949), to about 60,000 at present implies that the
population is ageing. Developments in the size of population by a ge a nd gender
are shown in Table 1 '. Until recently, the structure of the population has been
advantageous In the sense that the proportion of the groups of prime working age
has been quite high, a nd that of older people has been low. The gradual ageing of
the population is also shown in the a ge structure of those 15-64 years. The proportion
of people under 25 in the total working a ge population (here, a g ed 15-64) declined
from 23% in 1980, to 18% In 1995.
' Further background statistics on population, employment, unemployment and labour force
participation rates are given in the Annex (Tables AT to A6).
-12-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 1: Developments in the size of the population by age and gender, 1980-1995
Total population (1,000)
Breakdown by age
Aged 0-14
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-54
Aged 55-64
Aged 15-64
Aged 65-74
Aged 75-
Aged 65-
1980
4788
1985
4911
1990
4999
J 995
5116
967
761
2011
469
3241
378
196
579
953
722
2107
511
3340
368
246
614
965
645
2210
505
3360
385
280
670
978
631
2266
511
3408
431
297
730
Aged0-14and65-
1546
1567
1635
1708
Breakdown by age, %
Aged 0-14
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-54
Aged 55-64
Aged 15-64
Aged 65-74
Aged 75-
Aged 65-
20.2
15.9
42.0
9.8
67.8
7.9
4.1
12.1
19.4
14.7
42.9
10.4
68.1
7.5
5.0
12.5
19.3
12.9
44.2
10.1
67.3
7.7
5.6
13.4
19.1
12.3
44.4
9.9
66.7
8.4
5.8
14.2
A g e d 0 - 1 4 a n d 6 5-
32.2
31.9
32.7
33.3
Breakdown by gender, % females
51.7
51,6
51.5
51.3
Source: Statistics Finland, Population Statistics.
Traditionally, net migration has tended to diminish the population of Finland,
pronounced by particularly high emigration to Sweden at the end of the 1960s that
was particularly strong. Since the early 1980s, migration flows have b e c o me positive
and, as in many European countries, migration has contributed significantly to
population growth. In the early 1990s, net immigration ran at about 9,000 per
annum, although foreign citizens or the foreign-bom population makes up just 1-2%
of the total population. This masks a rapid increase, such that the number of foreign
citizens was a b o ut 70,000 at the end of 1995, c o m p a r ed to 15,000 in the mid 1980s.
/. 1.2 Developments
in the labour force, 1980-1995
The labour force participation rate - the ratio of the labour force to the population
of working a ge - exhibits a procyclical variation, so that labour force participation
Increases In economic upswings and decreases during recessions. In addition to
demographic factors, changes In the labour force participation rate have strongly
affected developments in the labour force, especially during the d e ep recession in
the early 1990s.
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
The labour force grew in the 1980s by more than 100,000 people, but in the recession
years the sharp drop in the labour force participation rate of young people
diminished the labour supply to a large extent (Table 2). Despite the increase of
more than 100,000 people in the working a ge population during the period
1990-1995, the labour supply in 1995 was almost 60,000 less than at the beginning of
the recession. The ageing of the population Is reflected In the a ge distribution of the
work force as a substantial rise in the proportion of the prime-age group 25-54; in the
1990s, the shift was strengthened by the cyclical drop in youth labour force
participation. Otherwise, the composition of the work force remained fairly stable.
Women have accounted for 47-48% of the total work force during the whole period
from 1980 to 1995,
Table 2: Developments in the labour force by age and gender, 1980-1995
Labour force (1,000)
Breakdown by age, %
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-54
Aged 55-64
Aged 65-74
1980
2442
1985
2566
1990
2555
1995
2497
17.2
71,9
9.4
1.6
15.6
73.7
9.7
1.0
14.0
76.9
8,4
0.7
10.4
79.9
9.2
0.5
Breakdown by gender, % females
46.7
47.9
47.4
47.5
Percentage changes
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-54
Aged 55-64
Aged 65-74
Total
Females
Males
1980-1990
1990-1995
-14,8
+12.0
-6.5
-50.0
+5.6
+6.9
+4,4
-27.7
+1.6
+6.5
-31.6
-2.3
-2.1
-2.4
Source: Statistics Finland, Labour Force Survey.
A few regional aspects are also worth noting (Annex, Table Al 3). Firstly, the growth in
labour supply in the 1980s was greatest in Uusimaa, the southernmost province of
Finland which includes the Greater Helsinki area. Secondly, mostly due to
inter-reglonal migration, the decline In the labour supply in the early 1990s took
place In all areas except Uusimaa. The proportion of the total labour force based in
Uusimaa has increased, to 29% in 1995.
1.1.3 Labour force projections, 1995-2005
According to the latest report on Finland's long-term employment prospects
compiled by the labour administration, the population a g ed 15-64 will peak towards
the end of the next d e c a d e, amounting to a total increase of 70,000 by the year
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
2010 (Ministry of Labour, 1996a). The basic population scenario is based on the
present fertility rate, net annual Immigration of 2,000 people (less than during the
past ten years on average) and a slight rise in average life expectancy, The
projected decrease in the number of children under 15 Is offset by an equivalent rise
in the number of older people aged 65 or more. The overall proportion of children
and old-age pensioners is projected to remain unchanged, at around 33% up till
2010.
Table 3 shows projected changes in the structure of the labour force up to 2005. The
projections are conditional on economic developments and any changes In social
welfare policy. As to economic activity, the basic labour force scenario is based on
the assumption that the unemployment rate will decrease from 17.2% In 1995 to
13.0% in 2000 and further to 10.4% in 2005. According to this scenario, the labour
force will initially increase slightly - up 2% by 2005, but decrease thereafter as a result
of the ageing of the population (which tends to reduce the average labour force
participation rate). In comparison to the base year 1995, age-specific labour force
participation rates are projected to increase, however. This holds for both women
and men. Despite the expected fall in the relative size of the public sector, which has
traditionally employed more women than men, the growth of care and other
services in the private sector is projected to provide female jobs. As a result, it is
expected that the demand for female labour will grow.
Irrespective of the detailed quantitative projections, however, significant changes in
the age structure of the labour force are obvious, as the number of those over 50
years of age will increase rapidly - by 45% in the basic scenario. Almost 30% of the
total work force will be over 50 in 2005, compared to 20% in 1995.
15-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 3: Projected developments in the supply of labour il,000 people), 1995-2005
Population:
Aged 15-64
Aged 15-74
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-39
Aged 40-49
Aged 50-54
Aged 55-64
Aged 65-74
Labour Force
Total
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-39
Aged 40-49
Aged 50-54
Aged 55-64
Aged 65-74
Breakdown by age, %
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-39
Aged 40-49
Aged 50-54
Aged 55-64
Aged 65-74
1995
2000
2005
3409
3839
3455
3888
3473
3915
631
1120
841
305
511
430
657
1036
783
424
554
433
647
982
754
392
698
442
Change
1995-2005
%
1,000
+64
+77
+16
-138
-87
+87
+187
+ 12
+2
+2
+3
-12
-10
+29
+37
+3
2497
2541
2555
+58
+2
+36
-109
-92
+78
+ 141
+5
+14
-11
-12
+31
+62
+36
259
972
771
253
229
14
10.4
38.9
30.9
10.1
9.2
0,6
288
906
712
352
265
16
11.3
35.7
28.0
13.8
10.4
0.6
295
863
678
331
369
19
11.5
33.8
26.5
13.0
14.4
0.7
Source: Ministry of Labour (1996)
1.2 Structure of the workforce
1.2.1 Labour force
participation
Labour supply is linked with variations In labour d e m a n d. This was particularly striking
during the d e ep recession in the early 1990s. The deterioration of the relative labour
market position of young people led to a sharp drop in their labour force
participation rate (Table 4). The fall in this supply of labour was related to several
factors: fewer students worked whilst studying; the number of starter places
Increased; and studies continued for longer periods. The number of full-time students
Increased by 74,000, or by 30%, from 1989 to 1994.
16-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 4: Developments in the labour force participation rates by aae and gender, 1980-1995
Aged 15-74
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-54
Aged 55-64
Aged 65-74
Aged 15-64:
All
Females
Males
1980
67.5
54.8
87.5
49.3
10.0
7985
69.2
54.9
90.2
48.7
7.1
1990
68.4
55.0
89.6
42.4
4.8
1995
65.1
41.0
88.2
44.6
3.0
74.3
69.3
79.3
76.1
73.1
79.1
75.7
72.5
78.9
72.9
70.0
75.6
Source: Statistics Finland, Labour Force Survey.
Chart 1 shows the proportion of teenagers a nd young adults ( a g ed 20-24) who are
students. The Increase In the proportion of students in the population is almost a
perfect mirror-image of the decrease in the labour force participation rates of young
people. Withdrawal from the labour market for other reasons, e.g. for domestic work,
was therefore negligible.
Chart 1 : Proportion of the population who are students mot in the labour forcei in the
younger aae groups, 1986-1995
■Ages 15-19
■ Ages 20-24
86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95
Source: Statistics Finland, Labour Force Survey.
With the exception of cyclical fluctuations, the average labour force participation
rate has remained stable over the past 15 years. Table 4 shows that about t wo thirds
of those a g ed 15-74 and three quarters of those a g ed 15-64 are part of the labour
force, either employees or unemployed. The breakdown by a ge and gender shows
some underlying changes, however. Women's participation rate has grown slightly
and early retirement has diminished the participation rate, particularly a m o ng older
men. The overall labour force participation rate has remained high a nd stable
mainly as a result of the Increased participation rate of middle-aged women, the
17-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
increase in general educational attainments, as well as the Increased proportion of
prime-aged groups of working age,
The labour force participation rate for men, particularly older men, is lower than the
EU average. As in other Nordic countries, women's labour force participation is very
high. Since the 1970s, the entry of women into the labour market has been
encouraged and facilitated by a number of social policy measures. These Include:
the 1976 shift from joint to separate taxation of spouse's income; extensions of
maternity and parental leaves; changes In maternity allowances In 1982; increasing
the number of child day-care places; and Introducing child-care leave In 1985.
Some of the schemes - like the child-care leave scheme - result in lower labour force
participation during the leave, but in the longer run they Improve the possibility of
combining a career with family responsibilities. These initiatives were motivated by
production needs, as well as the Nordic welfare state principle that care and other
welfare services should be provided by the public sector. In 1995, women
accounted for 47% of the total labour force.
Finnish women under 50 have a higher level of education than Finnish men, if the
proportion of the population with at least an upper secondary education is used as
a criterion. Among women under 40 years of age, the proportion of those with a
tertiary educational qualification is higher than that of men. For both men and
women, the disparities In educational attainment are very large across age groups -
the biggest In the OECD countries in 1991 (Statistics Finland, 1994). The percentage of
Finns aged 55-64 with an upper secondary or tertiary qualification (30%) was below
the average (38%) for the OECD countries. The corresponding figure for young Finns
aged 25-34 was 80%, which was much higher than the OECD average (66%).
The more favourable labour market position of better educated people Is also
shown in their relatively higher labour force participation rates. This difference Is most
obvious in the prime-aged (25-54) group. In 1994, the labour force participation rate
in this age group was 93% for those with higher education, compared to 84% for
those with a basic education (Statistics Finland, 1995a).
1.2.2 Size and composition of employment
In the long run, developments In labour supply and labour demand tend to be
linked (Chart 2). In the 1980s, the growth In the labour force by more than 100,000
was associated with a similar growth in employment. In the early 1990s, the collapse
of output swept away nearly one fifth of jobs. The recovery in production began
during the latter half of 1993, but the upturn in employment took place almost a
year later. Despite the economic upswing, the number of employed people In 1995
was about 400,000 less than In 1990, when the boom turned abruptly Into a deep
economic crisis.
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Chart 2: Labour force and employment d.OOOsY 1970-1995
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
- Labour force
•Employment
0 *1
1
1
1
1
1
1
i —i
1
1
1
I
I
I
I — -ι
| —i
1
1
1
1
I
I
70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94
Source: Statistics Finland, Labour Force Survey
Industrial structure has changed greatly during the past few decades and sectoral
patterns of employment exhibited some exceptional features during the recession, A
striking feature of the 1970s was the relative stability of the industrial (manufacturing
and construction) share of total employment, even though employment In
agriculture and forestry fell, while that of services rose. Finland was then one of the
few countries in Western Europe in which the industrial share of total employment
actually increased, hovering around 35% of the total. In most countries, the decline
in the years after 1975 was quite substantial.
The decline in the share of the secondary sector started in the early 1980s, and
thereafter the employment structure became more typical of Western European
economies. By the mid 1990s, the share of the tertiary sector (services) amounted to
nearly two-thirds of the total (Table 5). Even though the number of people working in
the primary sector declined by 50% from 1980 to 1995, they still accounted for about
8% of all employment in 1995, which itself is more than in most other Central or
Northern European countries.
Unlike most cyclical downturns, substantial job losses were experienced in all
branches during the economic crisis. Even though job losses started In the
manufacturing and construction sector, the service sector accounted for half of the
number of total job losses In the early 1990s. An upward trend in total employment
began in mid-1994. During the economic upturn, jobs have increased most in
manufacturing where the rapid growth of output started first and where the output
level exceeded that of the previous cyclical peak (by 16% in 1995), In 1995,
employment Increased In almost all branches, except for finance, Insurance and
agriculture.
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Toble 5: Sectoral distribution of employment (Ί.000 people-), 1980-1995
Total employment
Primary Sector
Secondary sector
Industry
Construction
Tertiary sector
Trade
Transport and communications
Finance, insurance, real estate and
business services
Public, social and personal services
1980
1995
% Change
2328
314
803
627
176
1201
328
184
127
1980-1990
+6
-34
-5
-11
+16
+25
+20
-3
+87
1990-1995
-16
-24
-25
-18
-41
-11
-24
-11
-8
2068
158
574
454
120
1328
300
158
208
% Share
1995
100.0
7.6
27.8
22.0
5.8
64.2
14.5
7.6
10.1
562
662
+22
-3
32.0
NB: The classification of industries is SIC 1979 for 1980 and SIC 1988 for 1990 and
1995. The discontinuity of the time series concerns mainly the division between
trade, business personal services and personal services. In 1989, the difference
of the new and old classification was +19,000 in trade, +40,000 in business
services and -62,000 in personal services.
Source: Statistics Finland, Labour Force Survey.
Changes in the sectoral structure of employment have been related to a fall in the
numbers of self-employed a nd unpaid family workers, as well as to a rise in public
sector employment (Table 6). As local government has largely been responsible for
both the availability and the production of welfare services, such as social, health
and educational services, the growth In these services has been reflected in the
growth of public services. This expansion p a v ed the way for w o m en to enter the
labour market, since women have long taken the majority of jobs in services. In 1995,
women's share of local government employment was 75%.
According to the Labour Force Survey, public sector employment a c c o u n t ed for
30% of total employment in 1995. Since part of this is a c c o u n t ed for by public utilities
(un-incorporated enterprises), which are Included In the business sector, the
appropriate public sector share of total employment was somewhat lower in the
National Accounts, 25% in 1994. This figure was the lowest of the Nordic countries,
but much higher than the EU average. However, great caution is necessary in
comparing the figures of the Labour Force Survey and National Accounts. The level
of employment In National Accounts is about 5% lower than in the Labour Force
Survey. The difference is most marked in respect of the numbers of self-employed
and entrepreneurs, since the National Accounts classifies owners of small joint-stock
companies who work in the c o m p a ny as employees, whereas the Labour Force
Survey counts such people as self-employed (for details, see Rytkönen, 1995).
•20·
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 6: Distribution of employment by status and by type of activity (%), 1980-1994
Self-employed
Employees
Business sector
Public sector
Other*
1980
14.7
85.3
78.0
17.8
4.2
1990
12.9
87.1
75.3
21.9
2.8
1994
13.1
86.9
71.6
25.1
3.2
* Other sector covers non-profit institutions and household services.
Source: Statistics Finland, National Accounts.
There Is strong and persistent occupational sex segregation (Annex, Table Al 4)
which has affected the incidence of employment, adjusted by gender, during the
recession. Initially, labour losses in manufacturing a nd construction industries gave
rise to heavy job losses for men. However, an early recovery in the exports sector
restored manufacturing jobs first. Redundancies in both private and public services
followed later a nd their recovery has taken place later than in male-dominated
sectors. Last year, the relative increase in men's employment was 3.5%, but just 0,7%
in women's employment.
1.2.3 Patterns of work
(a) Part-time work
The number of regular annual hours is fairly low in Finland, but in other respects the
intensity of working is high. There is plenty of overtime work, but little part-time work.
Moreover, the share of part-time jobs in total employment has remained fairly stable
during the past fifteen years. In 1995, about 8% of all employed people and 11% of
employed w o m en worked fewer than 30 hours per week In their main job. If the cut
off point of 35 hours were applied, the proportion of part-time work would obviously
be higher, amounting to 14% In 1995. Some 65% of those e n g a g ed in part-time work
were women.
Part-time work is heavily concentrated in trade a nd in the hotel a nd catering
industry, where employees tend to prefer full-time jobs. In general, Involuntary
part-time work increased substantially during the recession, In autumn 1993, 46% of
workers on part-time schedules were doing so involuntarily because of a lack of
full-time job opportunities (Annex, Table A9). On the other hand, one In every five
full-time employees - some 322,000 people - would rather have taken a part-time job
if it had been available at a pro-rata rate of pay, although most of them (247,000
people) would have wished to take it only temporarily. On balance, the c o m b i n ed
effect of these factors is such that employees prefer more extensive part-time job
opportunities, even though the mismatch of actual a nd preferred schedules is
presently quite pronounced. In the EU countries, where on average 30% of
employed w o m en and 4% of men work part-time, the preference is for full-time jobs.
-21
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
(b) Fixed-term employment contracts
Some 14% of employees were employed on fixedterm contracts in 1993, the
percentage being clearly higher In the public than In the private sector (Annex,
Table AIO). By international standards, fixedterm contracts have been exceptionally
common in Finland. To some extent, temporary contracts have been the result of
the large and Increased volume of subsidised job schemes designed to help
unemployed people into employment, while Institutional arrangements such as
childcare leave and study leave have also encouraged the recruitment of
supplementary personnel on temporary contracts,
Fixedterm contracts have been more common among young people. This has
affected the Incidence of cyclical labour adjustments. At the turn of the 1990s, the
proportion of young people working on fixedterm contracts was approximately
three times that of adults. This caused redundancies to be targeted at young people
and was one contributory factor in the drastic deterioration In the relative labour
market position of young people during the recession years (Annex, Chart Al). The
number of employed young people fell by 50% In total, while the corresponding
drop was 13% for adults aged 2574.
In the early 1990s, patterns of labour use seem to have changed significantly, with a
greater reliance on fixed term contracts In hiring new staff. Most terminated
employment contracts come to an end within a year. Furthermore, the proportion of
new contracts which are arranged on a fixedterm has traditionally been many
times the proportion of all contracts which are fixedterm. Although changes in the
characteristics of current contracts have thus far been moderate, changes are more
pronounced In new contracts. In 1993, 60% of new contracts were fixed term, while
In 1989 the corresponding figure was 39%.
Some indication of more recent developments during the upturn is provided in the
Working Conditions Barometer (Ylöstalo and Kauppinen, 1995; Ministry of Labour,
1995). The data refer to changes that have take place in the workplace of the
employee rather than In the position of the Individual, Responses from autumn 1994
suggest that during the preceding 12 months, new employees had been recruited
on temporary contracts in 14% of workplaces and on permanent contracts in 12% of
workplaces. Along with the economic revival, the figures were higher in autumn
1995; 36% for temporary contracts and 29% for permanent contracts. Obviously,
both types of contract could have been used In the same workplace. It is worth
noting, however, that there was little change in the relative use of the two types of
contract.
To satisfy shortterm needs for additional staff, firms have relied Increasingly on
temporary work agencies and employment contracts have frequently been
changed to subcontracting with newly selfemployed people. Overall, great
concern has been expressed about the emerging trend toward atypical
employment and work without an employment contract. The fear is that they will
undermine labour law and contribute to a general erosion of employment
protection.
■22
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
1.2.4 Level and structure of unemployment
By Western European standards, unemployment has traditionally been quite low In
Finland, even though it was higher than in other Nordic countries, with the exception
of Denmark. In the 1980s, the unemployment rate averaged about 5%. Regional
disparities were large and persistent, with the eastern and northern parts of the
counrry having the highest rates. Since there are huge differences in regional
population density, the workforce is very unevenly distributed across the country.
Therefore, in terms of absolute numbers, about half the total unemployed in the
1980s were concentrated in very small areas around larger towns and in declining
industrial districts in southern Finland.
The youth unemployment rate has usually been approximately double that of adults,
but similar to that In most other countries. The male unemployment rate has been
higher than that of women. The disparities in the unemployment rate by level of
education have been the most pronounced. Despite the temporary equalising
tendency during the recession, in 1994 the unemployment rate among those with a
basic education was treble that of those with higher education.
Chart 3: Unemployment rates by level of educational attainment, 1994
Postgraduate
Graduate level
Undergraduates
Lowest level of higher
ed.
Upper level of upper
secondary
Lower level of upper
secondary
Basic level
• -
ί
, ^
.{
,,?
»MH* -
.*< .. « t ί
é^iem^M»^i^B^&i^^xmå&øMMi:
Source: Statistics Finland, Labour Force Survey.
■23
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 7: Unemployment rates bv aae and gender, selected years, 1980-1995
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-29
Aged 30-34
Aged 35-39
Aged 40-44
Aged 45-49
Aged 50-54
Aged 55-59
Aged 60-64
Total
Females
Males
1980
13.5
6.4
5.4
3.6
3,3
2.5
3.3
3.9
5,0
4.2
4.7
4.7
4.7
1985
14.1
7.7
5.1
4.3
3.4
2.8
3.2
4.7
7.2
6.0
1990
8.6
5.9
3.2
2.8
2.7
2.7
2.3
3.4
4.8
1.4
1994
36.7
32.4
21.4
16.9
15.3
14.8
13.9
14.4
25.6
13.7
1995
32.0
29.1
19.4
15.7
14.5
13.9
13.2
13.6
27.0
12.3
5.0
3.4
18.4
17.2
4.6
5.5
2.8
4.0
16.7
19.9
16.7
17.2
Source: Statistics Finland, Labour Force Survey
The dramatic rise in unemployment - from 3.4% in 1990 to a peak of 18.4% in 1994 -
contrasts with the relatively Impressive labour-market performance of the preceding
decades, when the unemployment rate In Finland was generally one to three
percentage points below the OECD average (Chart 4), The surge of unemployment
a c c o m p a n i ed the decrease of total output by over 12%. Even though
unemployment In the early 1990s affected a broader cross-section of the population
than previously, the disparities by region, gender, a ge a nd education remained
similar, although the size of the disparities t e n d ed to narrow. Surprisingly, the
deterioration of the labour market position of young people did not show at all In
their relative unemployment rate, which remained approximately double that of the
adult unemployment rate. This was due to the steep fall In the youth labour force
participation rate,
The relative unemployment rate of older people has t e n d ed to Increase, however,
as the average duration of spells of unemployment a m o ng those a g ed 55 years or
more has Increased considerably. This reflects the weak employment opportunities
for older people in a slack labour market, as well as the unlimited duration of
unemployment benefits up to the a ge of 60 (which is the eligibility a ge for
unemployment pension). There are some economic Incentives which discriminate
against older people (Santamdkl-Vuori, 1996a). For example, in enterprises
employing more than 50 people, payroll taxes for financing employers' contributions
to pension funds are graded by age, the scale varying smoothly from 14% for young
people to 30% for those over 53 years of age. Moreover, large firms are individually
responsible for financing disability pensions paid to their former workers and, from
1989, a partial experience-rating applies to the funding of unemployment pensions.
■24-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Chart 4: The unemployment rate in Finland and in the OECD countries, 1970-95
% 20
•Finland
-OECD
70
72
74
76
78
80
82
84
86
1
—ι
88
1 1
90
1 1
92
r—
94
Source: OECD Labour Force Survey
In the late 1980s, when the average unemployment rate was slightly more than 4%,
the annual inflow of people into the unemployment pool was about 10% of the
labour force. In 1991-1995 when the average unemployment rate was nearly 15%,
the corresponding relative inflow rate was about 15%. Thus, the relative inflow rate
increased one and a half times and the unemployment rate trebled, c o m p a r ed with
the earlier period. This implies that most of the rise in unemployment was attributable
to an increase in the recurrence of unemployment spells and, In particular, to the
lengthening of unemployment periods.
Changes in the recurrence of unemployment spells c an be illustrated by considering
the number of people becoming unemployed, alongside the number of new
unemployment spells. We see from Chart 5 that in the late 1980s, the annual relative
inflow of new spells was one a nd a half times that of the inflow of new people.
During the recession, the corresponding ratio was a b o ut two. Increases in the
average length of unemployment spells were even more striking. The average length
of ongoing spells of unemployment rose from 15 weeks in 1990, to 45 weeks in 1995.
In terminated spells of unemployment, the corresponding change was from 12
weeks In 1990 to 25 weeks in 1995. There are marked differences across a ge and
gender, however. Unemployment duration tends to increase with a ge (Table 8) a nd
the spells are longer for men than for women. As for terminated spells in 1995, the
average duration for women was 22 weeks, c o m p a r ed to 28 weeks for men.
•25-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Chart 5: Annual flows into registered unemployment, as percentage of labour force ("the left
scale) and the average length of current unemployment spells in weeks (the right scale),
1986-1995
86
87
88
89
Average length of current unemployment spells
New spells of unemployment
New unemployed job seekers (as % of labour force)
Source: Ministry of Labour, Annual Register Data.
Table 8: Average duration (weeks') of terminated and ongoing spells of unemployment by
aae and gender
Age
Terminated spells in 1995
Ongoing spells
in Feb 96
15-19
20-24
25-29
30-34
35-39
40-44
45-49
50-54
55-59
60-64
Total
N=
All
Females
13
16
18
22
23
23
24
27
33
89
13
19
22
25
26
27
28
31
38
92
Males
14
21
27
29
31
32
34
37
44
97
19
25
34
40
44
49
53
56
90
68
25
856,343
22
452,920
28
403,423
48
443,646
Source: Statistics by the Ministry of Labour.
The sharp rise in unemployment coincided with a more uneven distribution of the
unemployment burden. The proportion of long-term unemployed (12 months or over
continuously) in total unemployment has been relatively low in Finland, averaging
- 2 6-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
some 11% during the 1980s (Annex, Table Al 1). However, Finland experienced a
temporary drop in long-term unemployment in the late 1980s. At this time, the
economy was picking up and, more importantly, active labour market policies were
giving a high priority to long-term unemployed people.
The 1987 Employment Act (operative In high-unemployment regions since 1988 and
in the whole country since 1990) obliged either the State or local authorities to
arrange training, or a temporary job, for six months for long-term unemployed
people. Besides people who had been continuously unemployed for over a year,
the provision also covered recurrently unemployed people whose spells of
unemployment amounted to a total of 12 months during two preceding years. The
statutory placement obligation for the recurrently unemployed was abandoned in
1992 and the whole obligation was repealed from the beginning of 1993. Such
selective manpower policy measures contributed to the fact that the proportion of
the long-term unemployed In total unemployment dropped to 3% in 1990 and 1991.
Thereafter, long-term unemployment has been rising sharply, so that at present it
amounts to about 140,000 people, or 30% of total unemployed job-seekers.
Along with the economic recovery, the flow into long-term unemployment slowed
down in 1994. The relative outflow rate has continued to fall (Annex, Table Al 2),
which Is related to the trend towards longer and longer spells of unemployment
which have a lower probability of ending, Therefore, long-term unemployment will
be further aggravated and is going to become an entrenched problem in Finland.
Moreover, if the definition of the most hard-hit group Is relaxed to Include those, for
instance, who - after long-term unemployment - are participating in active labour
market policy schemes or who become unemployed again after completing a
programme, long-term unemployment might amount to some 250,000 people, or
10% of the total labour force (Santamäki-Vuori, 1996b).
The unemployment rate for men has fallen more than that for women, reflecting the
sharp disparities in sectoral developments during the economic up-turn. Indeed, the
average unemployment rate among women remained the same - at 16.7%- both in
1994 and 1995, while for men there was a drop from 19.9% in 1994 to 17.6% in 1995.
The fall In the unemployment rate was most pronounced among youths aged 15-24,
however, from 33.6% in 1994 to 29.9% in 1995. More generally, the disparities across
regions and educational levels have started to widen again.
7.3 Main trends in job creation and job loss
Data on job turnover are based on the Business Register, produced by Statistics
Finland. In 1993, the number of registered employers and enterprises subject to
turnover tax was about 117,000 (Annex, Table Al 3). In terms of employment, these
enterprises cover 95% of non-agricultural industries. Since many personal services
were exempted from value-added tax in 1993, the coverage In terms of all
enterprises subject to trade tax was no more than 60%. This data base has been
utilised mostly In order to describe the setting up and failure of companies, rather
than the number of jobs entailed.
- 2 7-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
A more detailed comparative study by OECD (1994a) on job turnover covers the
period 1986-1991. In respect of Finland, this is a problematic period covering both
the economic boom and then the collapse in 1991, with heavy staff cuts amounting
to 9% of the personnel in the enterprises covered (Annex, Table Al 3). The results
need to be treated with caution, since some of the data may be misleading since
they relate to two very different periods. However, the following conclusions can be
drawn from the OECD study.
Firstly, the average annual rate of job gains was equal to 10% of total employment
and the corresponding rate of job losses was equal to 12%, giving an annual rate of
job turnover at 22, on average. Job turnover was greater in services than in
manufacturing, but in both sectors the main source of both job gains and job losses
was labour adjustments in the existing establishments, rather than firm openings or
closures.
Secondly, virtually all new (98%) and existing (95%) establishments are very small (with
1-19 employees). However, a significant proportion of new jobs are generated by
new medium-sized establishments (Table 9). In 1991, new establishments employing
20-99 employees accounted for 25% of new jobs created by new establishments,
while the corresponding figure for those employing more than 100 employees was
less than 17%. This may be related to the fact that new establishments do not always
represent true 'births', since changes in ownership, for instance, are also counted as
new establishments. A recent analysis by Statistics Finland suggests that no more
than about half of all new establishments are newly created.
Thirdly, small establishments contribute a high share of both gross job gains and gross
job losses. During the period 1986-91, small establishments employing less than 20
people accounted for 53% of gross job gains and for 38% of gross job losses. This was
the only category registering net gains. However, corporate networking and close
interaction between large and small firms might have been an important factor in
ensuring the success of small businesses.
Table 9: Distribution of employment in new and existing enterprises by size class
1-19 employees
20-99 employees
100-499 employees
500+ employees
New enterprises
1990-91 (%)
Existing enterprises
1993 (%)
Establishments
98.1
1.7
0.2
0.0
100
Employment
58.1
25.2
13.2
3.5
100
Establishments
95.2
3.8
0.8
0.2
100
Employment
29.2
16.8
18.7
35.3
100
Source: For new enterprises - OECD (1994a) and for existing enterprises -
Business Register of Statistics Finland.
As pointed out in Section 1.2.2 (Table 6), the decline of employment in agriculture
and forestry has contributed to a slight decline in self-employment as a proportion of
total employment, during the period 1980-1994. If the primary sector is excluded,
-28-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
however, there has been a substantial rise in the proportion of entrepreneurs in total
employment - from 5% in 1980 to 10% in 1993 (Aho and Koski, 1995). Moreover,
broadly similar developments are shown in all main industries which may be related
to Increases in subcontracting and extemalisation.
As to projected developments by the year 2000, the labour administration has
recently compiled estimates on job opportunities by occupation (Ministry of Labour,
1996a). Taking into account both the outflows from the labour market (about
300,000 people and mainly due to ageing) and net employment increases (about
140.000 people), the total number of job openings (440,000) are expected in four
sectors particularly:
• manufacturing work (88,000);
• technical executive or expert work (69,000);
• social service work (66,000); and
• administrative executive and expert work (48,000),
1.4 Wages and salary trends
1.4.1 Inter-industry wage dispersion
From 1980, real earnings for regular working hours have Increased by about 30%. The
rise was markedly higher in the private sector than in the public sector In the 1970s,
but thereafter there have been similarities across the different employer sectors
(Annex, Chart A2). However, in the 1990s the private sector has once again shown
higher increases.
Within the industries (the business sector), relative wage differentials between the
main sectors narrowed markedly in the 1970s, but since the early 1980s the wage
dispersion has tended to widen again (Chart 6). In 1994, disparities in the average
hourly earnings Petween the main sectors were still less than In the early 1970s. On
the other hand, even under circumstances of nearly unchanged overall wage
dispersion, significant changes in relative wages offsetting each other at the
aggregate level seem to have taken place. Recently, as a result of the union-level
bargaining round in autumn 1994 in particular, wage developments In the export
sector, service and public sector have tended to differ to an increasing degree. A
new feature of the Finnish labour market Is that wage changes reflect strongly the
productivity and profitability developments In the particular branch or sector. It can
be argued, however, that if wages are to be used to allocate efficiently resources in
the economy, these differences In compensation for similar work should not be
permanent.
■29-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Chart 6: Wage dispersion (weighted coefficient of variation 'J between industries, 1960-1994
0.16
14 ;-V^
^
0.04
0.02
0.00
— ι — ι — ι — ι - 1 —ι ι ι ι ι ι — r — ι — ι — r — ι —ι ι ι ι — ι — ι — τ — ι — τ — ι — ι — ι — ι — 1 — 1 — ι —ι
60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94
* In calculating the coefficient of variation the standard deviation of each
industry hcs been weighted by the shgre of employees of thot industry. This
procedure constitutes o step towords megsuring wgge differentials among
employees. The unweighted coefficient of variation exhibits a similar
development, the rise since the early 1980s being even more pronounced,
however. The calculgtlons involve the nine moin industrial groups in the
National Accounts, and the wages refer to average hourly wages (annual
wages and salaries divided by the total number of performed working hours).
Source: Statistics Finland, Nationol Accounts,
In the manufacturing sector, w a ge differentials between branches have exhibited a
more stable development than In industry as a whole. However, due to strong
occupational segregation by gender, developments In the inter-industry differentials
In average earnings were affected by a long-term narrowing of the gender w a ge
gap. In manufacturing, for instance, w a ge dispersion between branches has
increased for females and males, even though the overall dispersion has not moved
upward to a similar extent. The same underlying process is likely to have affected
developments in the business sector as a whole. By International comparison, the
inter-industry w a ge dispersion in Finland has been at the average European level
and clearly larger than in Sweden and Denmark (Asplund, 1995b).
1.4.2 The gender wage gap
In the long run, most of the narrowing of the gender w a ge g ap seems to be due to
increased educational attainments a m o ng women. Interestingly, the unexplained
part of the g ap that cannot be attributed to differences in any observed qualities
between the genders, has not narrowed at all (see Asplund, 1995a, for changes in
the gender w a ge g ap for non-manual employees in Finnish industry in 1980-1994),
During recent years, the long-term equalising tendency in female and male earnings
has stopped, however, and w a ge differentials have begun to increase (Annex,
- 3 0-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Chart 3). In 1994, the gender wage gap amounted to about 25%, across the whole
economy.
1.4.3 Minimum wages
As noted earlier, minimum wages are set by collective agreements In Finland. This
implies that the level of minimum wages differs across sectors and there is some
grading by age. Beside the normal grading by age, a twoyear agreement by the
central labour market organisations valid from mid1993 to mid1995 allowed, on
certain conditions, the employment of young people under 25 on pay which was
1050% lower than the minimum wages agreed in collective agreements, In practice,
the agreement mainly concerned young people under 25 who, after completing
studies, were entering the labour market for the first time as well as young people in
a summer job or in apprenticeship training.
Experience with the temporary agreement suggests that the impacts were
negligible, possibly except for summer jobs (Saari, 1996; SantamäkiVuori and
Sauramo, 1995). Moreover, as discussed in Section 1.3, the scaling of payroll taxes by
age favours the employment of young people over that of adults. Due to the huge
number of minimum wages, there is no clear way to construct time series for
minimum wages and to estimate the developments In the ratio of the minimum
wage to the average wage. Since the early 1980s, there have, therefore, been no
such estimates available.
Some indirect evidence, however, is obtained by looking at the distribution of
individual wages and salaries and differences between the lower and upper ends of
the distribution. Even though caution should be exercised in international
comparisons, since the results may be affected by such factors as whether the data
are based on administrative registers or household Inquiries, some preliminary
findings are worth noticing. In particular, the lowest wages seem to be rather low
relative to median wages in Finland, and the same also applies to the highest wages
(Robinson, 1994; SantamäkiVuori, 1995; OECD, 1993). The dispersion below the
median is rather wide and rather narrow above it. The results suggest that the
relative level of minimum wages is not particularly high in Finland (for international
comparisons, see Annex, Table Al 4).
1.4.4 Individual pay differentials
As to developments since the early 1980s, the changes in individual wage dispersion
have been moderate (Table 10). The range seems to have widened somewhat
during the boom of the late 1980s and narrowed again during the recession of the
early 1990s. The rise in wage inequality which preceded the recession was
associated with large changes within almost each agegender group, industry and
educational category (Eriksson & Jäntti, 1995). If the figures for years 1980 and 1992
are compared, the figure Dl /D5 describing the level of the lowest decile compared
■31
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
to the median w a ge has increased slightly. Preliminary d a ta from 1994 suggest that a
similar compression continued in that year also.
Toble 10: Trends in individugl pgy differentigls, 1980-1992
D9/D5
D1/D5
D9/D1
1980
1.55
0.54
2.87
1986
1.56
0.56
2.79
1989
1.60
0.56
2.86
1990
1,59
0.59
2.69
1991
1.58
0.60
2.63
1992
1.55
0.60
2.58
Dl /D5 denotes the poy level of the lowest decile relative to the median pay,
whereas D9/D5 denotes the pay level of the highest decile relative to the
median,
Source: Statistics Finland (1995b)
There are at least two reasons for recent developments. One is related to the various
additional w a ge payments which increased in the boom years a nd shrank during
the recession. As these different cash-based profit sharing systems, bonuses a nd
overtime payments which affected mostly employees belonging to the highest
deciles decreased during the recession, the overall pay distribution t e n d ed to
narrow.
Another reason relates to the higher incidence of unemployment a m o ng those with
lowest wages. For instance, 46% of the women who b e c a me unemployed in 1992
had been in the lowest quintile of the pay distribution in 1991, whereas those
belonging to the highest quintile formed only 4% of newly registered unemployed
women. For men, the figures were 38% and 9% respectively. As the proportion of the
lowest w a ge groups In the pay comparison drops, the dispersion appears to
b e c o me narrower.
1.4.5 Real wage
flexibility
At the macro level, real w a ge flexibility seems to have been high in Finland (for a
survey of Finnish evidence, see Tyrväinen, 1995). For many observers, a distinctive
feature of the Finnish wage-setting process has been the role played by the
Scandinavian inflation model, or the so-called EFO policy model of w a ge
determination. A key feature of the model is that the 'open' export sector acts as a
w a ge leader, a nd that productivity growth and changes In export prices (with
subsequent adjustment for changes in terms of trade) provide a basis for permissible
w a ge changes In the economy. In this strict sense, the EFO model seems to provide
an Insufficient description of the Finnish experience. Yet it may be argued that the
EFO model has influenced policy-making by adding, to the principles of the
negotiated incomes policy, a concern to sustain International competitiveness.
The co-ordination of the w a ge setting process has m a de it easier to deal faster with
adverse macro-economic shocks and to prevent w a ge spirals, Admittedly, real
w a ge flexibility has often been attained through devaluation, thereby accentuating
inflation propensity in the economy. Devaluations were used to correct the
•32-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
functional distribution of income in favour of capital which contributed to the very
high investment rate, typical of the Finnish economy. In fact, the combination of low
real wage rigidity and high nominal w a ge rigidity has characterised macro
economic w a ge performance. It accords with the fact that real labour costs have
been adjusted through inflation.
A completely new situation emerged in 1991 when the Finnish markka was tied to the
ECU, rendering unfeasible the restoration of the external balance via exchange rate
changes. The considerable need to adjust real wages by cuts in nominal wages did
not succeed, however. This may be taken as an indication of resistance to cut
nominal wages. An important additional viewpoint is that under conditions of
exceptionally high Indebtedness of households a nd enterprises, deepening the
underlying deflation process was considered to be too risky for economic
performance. In autumn 1991, the currency was devalued by 14% and, In 1992, it
was left floating.
The depreciation of the currency resulted in a very significant change in the
functional distribution of income (Chart 7). Along with high w a ge inflation in the late
1980s, price competitiveness deteriorated. The depreciation of the currency, w a ge
freezing in the early 1990s a nd the rapid productivity growth resulted in a huge
improvement in the price competitiveness of manufacturing industry in Western
markets (Chart 8). The competitiveness of exports slightly weakened In 1995, mainly
due to the appreciation of the markka. Competitiveness is, nevertheless,
exceptionally g o od In 1996.
Chart 7: Share of wages and salaries plus employers' social security contributions in value
added in industries, 19751995
S^ <Ä>~
58
56
54
52
50
48
46
44
ι ι—
75 77
79
81
83
85
—ι 1 1—
87 89
91
93
95
Source: Statistics Finland, National Accounts.
■33
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Chart 8: Price competitiveness of manufdcturing industry in Western markets, 1975-1995
(Average 1970 - 1994 =100)
Note: Measured in terms of unit labour costs relative to the 14 most important
competitor countries. The weights used are these countries' export shares in
Western Europe, weighted by the commodity composition of Finnish exports.
Source: Ministry of Finance.
Recently, the EFO model has been a m e n d ed to apply to circumstances
characterised by the target of low inflation and floating (or permanently fixed)
exchange rates (Tulopoliittinen selvitystoimikunta, 1995). The new model is based on
the idea that the room for w a ge increases is equal to the sum of the target inflation
and average productivity growth, less changes in non-wage labour costs. The total
labour costs for e a ch unit of output then increase in line with the target inflation.
Under conditions of permanently fixed exchange rates, the target Inflation would be
defined by inflation in the monetary union area.
In order to ensure that w a ge developments fit better with local conditions, the need
for greater reliance on local level bargaining has been recurrently emphasised in
Finland. On the other hand, the capacity for centralised, or co-ordinated,
bargaining to offer a potential vehicle to achieve low nominal w a ge agreements
and thus to minimise inflationary expectations has recently been more widely
recognised. This was illustrated by the w a ge settlements in autumn 1995. Wage
inflation had accelerated after the preceding year's union level w a ge round. In
attempting to tackle this w a ge inflation, there was reliance on a traditional
corporatist arrangement with a high degree of centralisation and also with close
state involvement (for details, see Allén & Klander, 1996).
Beside wages, changes In indirect w a ge costs have also affected total labour costs.
In 1996, the average rate of employers' social security contributions in Finland was
25.8% of the payroll (Lehtinen, 1996a). Employers' social security contributions consist
of the following items: national pension contribution, sickness insurance contribution,
insurance for occupational hazards, group life Insurance contribution,
unemployment insurance contribution and employment pension contribution.
•34-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Except for the national pension contribution, the contributions are used to finance
insurance for employees.
Chart 9: Employers' social security contributions, percentage of wage bill, in various countries
in 1996
Source: Lehtinen (1996)
The social security contributions paid by Finnish employers are not particularly high,
when compared to those in other European countries (Chart 9). However, they
increased rapidly in the early 1990s. Such Increases were mainly a result of the
soaring unemployment Insurance expenditure (e.g. the employers' average
unemployment insurance contribution increased by some five percentage points
from 1990 to 1995, cf. section 5.3), but thereafter, employers' unemployment
Insurance contributions have been lowered again. Moreover, countries that have
high employers' contributions do not generally rank very high in terms of taxation of
employees, and vice versa. In Finland, however, moderate employers' social security
contribution combined with top tax rates on employees give rise to a very high total
taxation of labour.
7.5 Analysis of the principal causes of the rise in unemployment since 1980
1.5.1 Developments
in the 1980s
By the mid 1980s, Finland had built up a g o od reputation for economic dynamism.
The country underwent a recent a nd rapid transition from a predominantly primary
product economy to one in which services predominate and in which
high-technology Industry flourishes. In addition, adjustment to the international
upheavals of the 1970s and 1980s was less painful than in many other countries. The
percentage change in consumer prices in Finland, from 1980 to the mid-1990s, was
very similar to that for the EU average, Since the recession of 1977-78, when the
unemployment rate rose to a peak of more than 7%, the recorded unemployment
- 3 5-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
rate dropped to an average of less than 5% in the 1980s and less than 4% in 1989
and 1990. In southern Finland, the recorded unemployment rate was less than 1.5%
at the beginning of the 1990s. Admittedly, however, unemployment was higher than
in the early 1970s, but by the standards of Western Europe generally, the figures were
low until the recent economic crisis.
In interpreting developments In the 1980s, at least two points are worth noting,
however. Firstly, to cope with labour market problems In the late 1970s, there was a
growing reliance on supply-oriented measures and unemployment pension, in
particular. Labour shedding in manufacturing took place via departures from the
labour market, while new entrants took most of the jobs in the expanding service
sectors. Thus, it Is plausible to argue that industrial restructuring has been associated
with a substitution of labour force entrants for older displaced workers. Secondly, to
tackle unemployment, there was more emphasis on direct employment measures in
the late 1980s, reflecting a change of emphasis in Finnish labour market policies. The
efforts to provide - as a measure of last resort - temporary subsidised jobs for some
groups of unemployed people served to diminish long-term unemployment and to
narrow regional disparities in unemployment.
1.5.2 Economic crisis in the 1990s
After a good performance for most of the 1980s, the Finnish economy was hit by a
severe recession in 1991. A slowdown was already under way in early 1990, and in
the following 3 years output declined by around 12% - the most severe drop
recorded in any OECD country in recent decades, As a consequence, employment
decreased by a total of 18% and the unemployment rate, which had been among
the lowest internationally in 1990, rose to 18.4% in 1994.
The main factor behind the crisis was a collapse in domestic demand, but the
depression was also exacerbated by external shocks such as recession in the world
economy, a collapse in exports to the former Soviet Union, deterioration of price
competitiveness in Western markets, worldwide overcapacity of the forest industry
and a reversal of favourable terms of trade. It is widely accepted that the crisis was
a joint result of 'bad luck, bad banking and bad policies'. The relative significance of
the individual factors has been the subject of extensive discussion in Finland.
Moreover, the sharp rise in real interest rates revealed underlying inefficiencies in the
economy - including the low rate of return of investments - that were concealed
under the more regulated circumstances.
Fundamental questions about the conduct of macro-economic policy have also
been raised, because the process of decline started with the deregulation of
financial markets in the mid 1980s. Financial liberalisation was associated with a
self-enforcing spiral of credit expansion and asset inflation, increasing sharply the
indebtedness of firms and households and their exposure to the risks attached to
interest rates, exchange rates and asset prices. During the boom, fiscal policy never
took the necessary restrictive stance. The worst misjudgement was probably made in
monetary policy, however, both in boom and bust (see, e.g. Bordes et al, 1993;
-36-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Pekkarinen, 1995). During the years of the bust, defending the fixed exchange rates
necessitated punitive interest rates, as speculation against the currency intensified
with deteriorating economic circumstances. In a badly over-debted economy, asset
deflation was accelerated by high Interest rates, with a chain of bankruptcies as a
result. Massive credit losses were accruing to banks, leading to a severe bank crisis.
The recessionary spiral worsened, as indebted firms and households cut down their
consumption and expenditure,
The markka was devalued under heavy speculative pressure in autumn 1991. In
autumn 1992, it was allowed to float and after a period of hesitation, monetary
policy was relaxed and interest rates started to fall In early 1993, facilitating a
gradual recovery of the economy towards the end of the year. During the two
subsequent years, with average economic growth at slightly more than 4%,
employment has improved by some 3%.
Notwithstanding the huge economic fluctuations, the conventional relationship
between the changes In output and employment has shown striking stability in
Finland - in particular, if the rapid structural change from the labour Intensive
domestic sector to the capital intensive export sector during the early stages of the
economic recovery is taken info account.
According to the estimates by the European Commission (Directorate-General II),
one percentage change in output growth (relative to trend) gives rise to a change
of 0.63 percentage points in the unemployment rate in Finland (European Economy
No 60, 1995). This is a figure not dissimilar from the EU average of 0.54.
The estimates of the elasticity of unemployment rate to output - as well as those of
the non-accelerating rate of inflation (NAIRU) and the output gap - are very sensitive
to the particular estimation method chosen (cf. Giorno et al, 1995). The most recent
estimates by OECD suggest that the level of NAIRU might at present be as high as
15%. Updated domestic estimates are not available, though. Due caution is required
in assessing the precise level of the NAIRU, because of the nature of the estimation
methods and the sharp fall in the rate of inflation,.
In the 1980s, there was some evidence In Finland that the moderate rise in NAIRU was
associated with a decrease in hidden unemployment, partly as a result of changes
in the unemployment benefit system in 1972 and 1985. There was also some
evidence on the mechanism of partial hysteresis In the labour market; wage inflation
seemed to be influenced not only by changes in unemployment, but by the level of
unemployment. Thereafter, discussion about the factors contributing to the rising
level of NAIRU has been less clear cut. A substantial proportion of any change is likely
to be attributed to two factors: the sharp rise in long-term unemployment
(Pehkonen, 1994) and the substantial rise in the tax wedge, i.e. the difference
between the real (deflated at producer prices) cost of labour and the real (deflated
at consumer prices) take-home pay.
As shown in Chart A4 in the Annex, the ratio of product to consumption pay - a
measure of the tax wedge - rose from 1.8 in 1985, to 2.2 in 1994. A rise in consumer
prices relative to producer prices, tightening income taxation and rises in social
-37-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
security contributions by both employers and employees each contributed to this
outcome.
Any influences due to changes in labour market mismatch are much more
debatable. Moreover, a recent analysis points to the critical role of labour demand
(unemployment-vacancy ratio), compared to that of the mismatch In explaining the
outflow rate from unemployment (Rantala, 1995). The number of unemployed job-
seekers relative to the number of job vacancies increased from about 3 in 1989 to a
peak of more than 80 in 1993, the ratio being slightly less than 60 in 1995.
-38-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
2 LABOUR MARKET INSTITUTIONS
2.1 Public Institutions
In Finland, the Ministry of Labour directs and supervises the operation of the entire
labour market administration. The Ministry is responsible for active labour market
policy, the implementation of which has been delegated to the 13 regional labour
districts and the 183 local employment offices. There are several bodies at all levels
of administration, through which the social partners c an influence labour market
policies. The Council for Labour Affairs is the highest tripartite body which takes pari
in drawing up the Ministry's budget, as well as guidelines, action plans and policy
targets for regional and local public employment service (PES) offices. Tripartite
bodies also advise the regional PES offices and tripartite committees a t t a c h ed to
each local office to take decisions about the labour market situation of individuals
for benefit purposes (European Commission, 1996; OECD, 1995a).
The network of public employment offices is a branch of the Ministry of Labour at the
local level. Until 1994, there was a public monopoly in the provision of employment
services. The Ministry could grant permits, however, to private associations - often
white-collar trade unions and occupational associations - to engage in
job-placement activities. Since 1986, the activities of temporary work agencies have
been regulated through a licensing system. In 1994, the new Employment Services
Act abolished the permit procedure for job placement and regulations on the hiring
of labour were lifted. In general, the private provision of employment services was
then permitted. The removal of these restrictions has had little impact to date, partly
due to the prolonged slack In the labour market.
Public employment services include:
•
job placement;
• vocational guidance;
•
•
labour market training;
information services regarding training and occupational choices and;
• vocational retraining.
To claim unemployment benefits, unemployed job-seekers are obliged to register at
public employment offices. Although the function of benefit payment was
separated from the employment offices in 1985, the public employment service
retains the control function for assessing the responsibility of claimants to seek jobs.
Moreover, the public employment service has a vital role in the overall
implementation of active labour market policy measures (ALMP). Most ALMP
spending passes directly through the employment offices, in the form of payments to
training providers or employment subsidies paid to public and private sector
employers.
In practice, the public employment service is more involved in the granting of
employment subsidies a nd in placing unemployed v/orkers in training, than it is in
matching job-seekers to ordinary job vacancies. This tendency b e c a me more
39-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
pronounced during the heavy recession, as the number of job vacancies broke
down. In 1989, the total annual number of registered job vacancies was about
380,000. The number dropped to 114,000 in 1993, but along with the economic
recovery the number of registered job vacancies started to increase, amounting to
170,000 in 1995.
2.2 Collective Wage Bargaining
2.2.1 Labour relations
Traditionally, the Finnish labour market has been highly organised. The right to
organise is safeguarded by the Constitution and the right to bargain collectively is
guaranteed through a system of collective agreements, based on legislation. The
extent of unionisation among wage-earners has grown steadily since the late 1960s,
when the political integration of the trade union movement took place and the
development of an effective negotiated incomes policy became established, In
1994, about 79% of employees covered by collective agreements were union
members (Sandqvist, 1996), If retired, student and non-paying union members are
included, the extent of unionisation is about 97%. During the last few years of very
high unemployment, there has been a clear tendency towards higher unionisation.
Strikingly, the level of unionisation is higher in the public sector and among
white-collar employees than It is in the private sector and among blue-collar
employees. Since there are high proportions of women in the public sector and in
white-collar occupations, unionisation among women ¡s a little higher than among
men. Within the private sector, however, the unionisation rate among women is
lower than among men, which is partly related to the lower unionisation in
temporary and part-time jobs and to lower unionisation in small workplaces (Ilmonen
and Kevätsalo, 1995; Kauppinen, 1992).
The high unionisation rate seems to be related to the highly centralised bargaining
process and the high rate of unemployment (Kauppinen, 1992). The unionisation rate
may also be related to the fact that membership fees are tax deductible, fees are
collected mainly by employers (automatic dues check-off) and the involvement of
the unions in the administration of unemployment insurance (Ul) benefits
(Kauppinen, 1992; OECD, 1995a). The Ul system Is voluntary In Finland. Funds are
mainly organised by the unions, although there is also an independent Ul fund.
Employees have a legal right to join a union Ul fund without joining the union itself,
but this right is rarely exerted.
Typically, trade unions are organised nation-wide by industry, Industry unions, in turn,
are members of central confederations. There are three wage-earners' central
organisations, nearly one hundred unions and at most workplaces a branch union
and shop stewards. The largest of the central confederations is the Central
Organisation of Finnish Trade Unions (SAK), with over 1.1 million mainly blue-collar
workers. The two other central organisations are the Finnish Confederation of Salaries
Employees (STTK), with 620,000 members, and the Confederation of Unions for
-40-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Academic Professionals in Finland (AKAVA), which has about 320,000 members. STTK
represents technical and other salaried employees in industry, in private services and
In the public sector. STTK was reorganised in 1993 when one of the former central
organisations went bankrupt.
The extent of organisation among employers is also high (Statistics Finland, 1995d).
There are four major central organisations and three smaller ones. In the private
sector, almost 700,000 employees work In firms which are members of the two largest
confederations. The bigger one, the Confederation of Finnish Industry and Employers
(TT), consists of 28 member associations representing about 6,000 member
companies with 450,000 employees mainly in manufacturing industries, transport and
the construction sector. The second largest confederation is the Employers'
Confederation of Service Industries in Finland (PT). In the public sector, there are four
employers' organisations who sign a collective agreement on behalf of state,
municipalities, church and some other public institutions. The two major organisations
are the Commission for Local Authority Employers (KT), representing more than 700
municipalities and local federations with about 400,000 employees, and the State
Employer Office (VTML), representing all civil servants and other employees of central
government.
Finnish industrial relations are characterised by the close connection between the
political and labour market systems, i.e. corporatism. There has been close co
operation between the employees' and employers' organisations on the one hand
and the government on the other. In addition, the organisation promoting the
interests of agricultural producers, MTK, has always been very much involved in
political decision making. A benchmark year in the development of a
comprehensive Incomes policy was 1968, when on the Government's Initiative a first
stabilisation agreement was reached, following a large devaluation in 1967 and
other measures designed to boost international competitiveness. Thereafter,
although it has not been the case in each round, centralised negotiations have
tended to be comprehensive, in that besides wages, the social partners have
negotiated over prices, taxes, social security policy and working-time adjustments. In
particular, tax decisions and social welfare reforms have been linked to pay
bargaining. Some observers believe that this has imposed a disciplinary background
on pay bargaining at the centralised level.
2.2.2 Collective bargaining procedure
The collective bargaining procedure between the labour market organisations is not
governed by statutory regulations. In practice, the negotiations procedure may be
characterised as multi-layered (Chart 10). Initially, the central labour market
organisations try to agree on general guidelines in a round of negotiations which, if
successful, leads to a framework agreement. These agreements are not actual
collective agreements, but merely provide the framework for the negotiations at the
union level. However, central organisations have signed agreements on special
-41
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
issues (e.g. co-determination procedures and labour protection) which are valid for
an indefinite period a nd are observed as parts of collective agreements.
The second step takes place at the union level, when individual unions negotiate the
collective agreements. Legally binding collective agreements c an only be
concluded between individual trade unions a nd employer organisations or an
individual employer. There are about 600 to 700 such agreements In force, mostly
settled at the Industry level (Ministry of Labour, 1994). Lastly, talks on implementing
the agreement are held at workplaces.
Chart 10: The system of collective bargaining
Central orggnisgtions seek a framework
agreement along general lines
Union-level bargaining.
Most collective agreements are at this
level.
If no collective agreement is reached, the
union or employers' organisation can issue
notice of a strike or lock-out. The national
conciliator submits a proposal, which can
be accepted or rejected.
Framework
agreement
reached
New
collective
agreement
Strike and/or lock-out
• A strike or lock-out can begin two weeks after notice has
been given to the opposite side and to the national
conciliator. In most cases, a lock-out is used only as a
counter-measure to a strike.
• On the recommendation of a conciliator, the Minister of
Labour can defer a strike or lock-out for a further two weeks
(three weeks for public sector officials) for the purpose of
conciliation, if it is clearly detrimental to the public interest.
Source: Ministry of Labour (1990)
Wage drift, which seems to be closely related to the d e m a nd of labour, Is generated
at this local level. It arises from compensation, on which there has not been
agreement in collective negotiations and is a particular feature of the
Implementation of the agreement In the private sector. Wage drift acts as an error
correcting factor in the adjustment process where the target is influenced by the
bargaining process (Tyrväinen, 1995). However, at the national level a significant
-42-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
portion is also due to structural changes in the composition of employees and
changes in tasks. During the period 1970-1995, wage drift constituted on average
30% of the total increase in earnings. The average annual increase in negotiated
nominal wages was about 6% and the wage drift 2.5%, adding up to an 8.5% annual
earnings increase. In 1991-1994, nominal earnings Increased 2.5% on average, and
the contribution by wage drift was about 1% across the whole economy.
Wage drift has been a feature of the private sector. To prevent what negotiators
perceived as undesired changes in relative wages, an earnings development
guarantee has been introduced in many centralised collective agreements. This has
helped to compensate public sector employees, e.g., for not having wage drift,
Since 1968, 19 central agreements on wages and salaries have been concluded In
Finland, each of them for a period of one or two years. On a few occasions, the
central organisations have failed to reach any agreement. In such cases,
Industry-level bargaining has followed on a decentralised basis. Individual trade
unions and employers' organisations within specific industries have been able to
dissociate from central agreements. From time to time, this has led critics to claim
that the centralised Incomes policy lacked credibility and has raised demands for a
more decentralised bargaining process.
Collective agreements prescribe the minimum terms to be observed in all
employment contracts. An employer bound by a collective agreement is required
to observe the provisions In respect of non-unionised workers, unless they have
specific exclusion, under the terms of agreement. If a nation-wide, universal
collective agreement applies in a given sector, the agreement is automatically
extended to unorganised employers in that sector. The main function of a universally
binding collective agreement Is to give workers in non-organised enterprises the
same minimum employment conditions as organised workers.
There is also a system of minimum conditions based on the collective agreement
mechanism, rather than on statutory provisions for minimum pay. A collective
agreement is viewed as universal if at least half of the total employees in the sector
fall within its scope. There are about 140 universally valid collective agreements and,
in total, collective agreements cover more than 90% of employees. The proportion of
employees covered via the extensions based on universal validity has been
estimated at about 20% (OECD, 1994b). In the services industry, in particular, there
are sectors with no universally binding collective agreements to guarantee minimum
terms of employment.
Although the main focus of collective bargaining is at the sectoral level, some local
agreements are also concluded. They can be either completely independent
agreements between the employer and the union, or more often, they are based
on clauses In sectoral collective agreements which provide a local agreement for
organised employers. Matters often delegated to the local level include working
time arrangements, pay on a piece-rate basis and various supplements. In the 1990s,
local bargaining on flexible working time arrangements, in particular, has increased
markedly. When local bargaining In Finnish companies was studied, it emerged that
-43-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
local bargaining depends very much on the Internal bargaining relations in the
company, On the employers' side, rigid organisational practices and authoritarian
management are major obstacles to promoting local agreements. On the other
hand, if the employees belong to many different unions, this can also build barriers
to local bargaining.
In the public sector, terms of employment determined in collective agreements have
traditionally served also as maximum conditions. Felt to be rigid, this system has been
amended recently by giving more bargaining rights to the local level.
2.2.3 Dealing with conflicts
There ¡s a conciliation system and a permanent state conciliator dealing with
conflicts of interest relating to working life. The purpose of this conciliation system is to
assist the labour market organisations in reaching a collective agreement when the
straight negotiations have failed. Anyone intending a work stoppage due to a
labour dispute Is obliged to give advance notice to the relevant conciliator in order
to allow sufficient time for mediation. Finland has a system of compulsory conciliation
in that the parties are required to participate in the conciliation process under a
State conciliator. However, the final settlement of disputes is left to the parties
concerned.
Issues related to the contents, scope, validity or violation of a collective agreement,
as well as to the correct interpretation of a specific clause, are settled by the Labour
Court. The Court's decision is final. Neither employers or employees bound to a
collective agreement may initiate a labour dispute affecting the agreement as long
as the agreement is in force. The parties are obliged to maintain labour market
peace. An Individual employer, coalition of employers or association of employees
can be penalised for violating this obligation.
However, after agreements have expired, the wage-earner party can use a strike or
other labour dispute measures to put pressure on the employer. The employer, on
the other hand, can react with a lockout,
Traditionally, the incidence of industrial disputes in Finland has been relatively high,
by international standards. This has been interpreted as an indication of the relatively
contentious nature of industrial relations and the deep-rooted authoritarian attitudes
of management. The shift towards a better dialogue at the local level may be
underway, however. Each year, there have been a few union strikes, and a
considerable number of short wildcat strikes. The latter were quite frequent,
especially In the 1970s and early 1980s. In the 1990s, there has been a notable fall In
the number of labour disputes, in particular in wildcat strikes. The right to go on strike
and to resort to a lockout was permitted for public sector employees and employers,
from 1970 onwards. In the 1980s, public sector strikes involving nurses, doctors and
teachers became more frequent.
Labour disputes not connected to collective agreements lie within the jurisdiction of
general courts. The Equality Ombudsman is responsible for overseeing the
. 4 4.
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
compliance with the Act on Equality Petween Women and Men. However, the
enforcement mechanism established under the law Is not particularly strong.
2.2.4 Pressures for change
As the Finnish economy was hit by a severe recession at the beginning of the 1990s,
the attitudes of employers towards a centralised incomes policy became more
critical. However, as a response to the deep economic crisis, a freeze in contractual
wage increases was agreed by labour market organisations for 1992 and 1993, In
spring 1993, the basic principles of universal validity, of mandatory minimum
employment terms and of tripartite preparation of labour law and labourmarket
policy became controversial issues in the demands for locallevel bargaining and for
lowering the threshold of employing young people. The dispute was, however,
settlea and the Government agreed to observe the tripartite principles, without any
changes being made in the nature and universal validity of collective agreements.
As to youth wages, the central organisations concluded a twoyear agreement on
trainee wages.
The central bargaining process in 1993 did not succeed, however, as the employers
did not consent to open negotiations with the confederations of trade unions. This
led to industrylevel agreements, even though sectorspecific cooperation within
Industry, services and the public sector increased. Industry settled with 3% rises, the
service sector adopted a zero solution and in the public sector, annual salaries were
cut by 2 or 3% as a result of changes in holiday bonuses. There was then great
variation across industries in terms of export activity. Employers' representatives, and
to a lesser extent the employees' side, were not enthusiastic about centralised
agreements. However, in autumn 1995, a return to a centralised twoyear
agreement took place. There was a moderate general increase in wages, with some
additional increases in lowwage sectors. An agreement on developing the quality
of working life was also concluded by the partners.
In recent public discussion, there has been continuing debate on local pay
bargaining. Furthermore, demands have frequently been raised for changes to
universal validity and to the mandatory status of collective agreements on minimum
conditions. The impetus for these demands stems largely from the perceived need
for wage restructuring through lower wages and, at a local level, the possibility of
lower wage increases or even wage cuts. An opposite argument In favour of
centralised pay bargaining would emphasise the beneficial role of wage co
ordination in internalising the effects of wage settlements on price competitiveness
and unemployment. Furthermore, centralised pay bargaining systems are likely to be
better equipped at dealing with adverse shocks to an economy, such as trade loss
associated with the two oil price increases. However, the sustalnabillty of this kind of
system is debatable.
The main challenge for the Finnish unions in the next few years is to adjust their
bargaining strategies to the low Inflation target. This is not easy within the multilevel
bargaining structure. In any event, it is plausible that within the constraints set by
■45
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
collective agreements, there will be a greater diversity of firm-specific arrangements
related to performance pay schemes, profit sharing, work organisation and training.
In the European context, the main question will be whether the labour market
organisations will find it advisable to co-ordinate their actions on a national or an
International level. At this stage it is not clear In what direction the unions and
employers' organisations will proceed. However, the first experiments on European-
level co-ordination will be launched in some sectors in the near future.
2.3 Participation systems and personnel funds
2.3.1 Participation systems
Finnish participation systems are based on collective agreements and labour law.
The 1946 general agreement between the central organisations recognised shop
stewards as the employees' official workplace representatives, Thereafter,
opportunities for employees to have an Influence on decision-making have been
improved through laws regulating representative participation in various areas, both
in private companies and In the public sector.
In the private sector, these labour laws include the Act on the Supervision of Labour
Protection (1973), the Co-operation within Companies Act (1978), Personnel Fund
Act (1989), and the Act on Personnel Representation In Administration (1990). In the
public sector, the participation system roughly corresponds to that In the private
sector. In state departments, Institutions and public utilities the act on co-operation
entered into force in 1988. In the municipal sector, the co-operation is based on the
1993 general agreement of the labour market organisations. The laws and
agreements superseded the earlier recommendations on workplace democracy.
The Act on Co-operation within Companies applies to companies employing at least
30 people. The Act should also be applied to companies employing at least 20
people when the company Intends to give notice to at least 10 employees, for
economic or production-related reasons. According to this law, the employer is
obliged to negotiate with staff representatives on certain matters related to the work
performed and working conditions, employment, utilisation of outside labour,
training, staff facilities and the impact on staff of changes in ownership. It is
noteworthy, however, that the law does not prescribe co-determination on these
matters. Except for some minor matters, the firm makes the final decisions without
any obligation to take into account the opinions of the employees. In cases of
dismissals, temporary lay-offs or transfers to part-time work, the employer's obligation
to consult employees was strengthened in 1989 by defining minimum periods for
negotiations when there is disagreement between the parties. The minimum periods
vary between seven days and three months. If employers do not adhere to their
obligation, the employees concerned have a right to compensation, amounting to
a maximum of 20 months' pay.
A recent study on co-operation and participation within enterprises suggests that the
opportunities for Influencing negotiations were generally rated between
- 4 6-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
'reasonable' and "slight' by staff representatives (Kalrinen et al, 1995). In small
businesses, in particular, co-operation was usually very limited. It was the informative
function of the co-operation procedure which was emphasised by staff
representatives. Employers and employees disagreed about the need to extend the
scope of co-operation procedures. With regard to Issues such as working time, lay
offs, productivity, investment and equal opportunities, however, both parties agreed
that the co-operation system would be a suitable procedure for local company
level negotiations.
Co-operation on labour protection at the workplace is based on the Act on the
Supervision of Labour Protection. In larger companies regularly employing more than
150 people, the Act on Personnel Representation in Company Administration gives
staff the right to participate in management on issues related to the company's
business operation, finances and position of the staff. Administrative representation
can be implemented as jointly agreed by the employer and the staff. If not
otherwise agreed, staff elect at least one representative to the company's
supervisory board, board of directors or similar body.
2.3.2 Personnel funds
In 1990, Finland Introduced a deferred profit-sharing scheme, aimed at promoting
economic democracy and deepening co-operation within the company, as well as
boosting competitiveness. The Act on Personnel Funds applies to companies
employing at least 30 people According to the Act, the personnel of a company or
a smaller unit in the business can establish a fund provided that the company has
introduced a profit-related pay scheme. The establishment of the fund is on a
completely voluntary basis. The funds are owned and run by the personnel, but the
Act leaves scope for variation In the coverage of the fund, the division of the capital
Into individual and joint shares, or the investment policy of the fund.
This deferred profit-sharing scheme provides tax incentives to employers since
payments made by employers Into the funds are not liable to payroll taxes. The
original regulations stipulated that, after ten years, the employee was allowed to
withdraw annually 10% of the money In the fund, though the whole could be
withdrawn on leaving the company. To encourage the establishment of new funds,
the withdrawal restrictions were relaxed from the beginning of 1996, by reducing the
term to five years and Increasing the annual withdrawal limit to 15%. Moreover, a
Government Bill has been submitted to Parliament to abolish the taxation of
withdrawn funds. According to the Bill, the Income Tax Act will be amended to allow
20% of all income from personnel funds to be totally tax-exempt, with 80% being
taxed as earned Income.
At the moment, roughly 90,000 employees - about 5% of all employees - are covered
by the existing 40 personnel funds. Take-up was Initially quite rapid, but along with
the heavy recession Interest declined and a few funds have even been suspended.
The majority of personnel funds were established in large manufacturing companies
that had already Introduced a comprehensive cash-based profit sharing system.
- 4 7-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Such systems continued to exist alongside the deferred profit sharing system of the
investment fund. Staff funds are less common In small and medium-sized companies
and in the service sector.
In all companies, economic democracy was related to industrial democracy (Repo,
1994). Funds were seen as a means of shifting the dialogue from work related issues
to the use of capital. The more profound understanding of business was expected to
lead to higher work motivation, feelings of responsibility and willingness to accept
changes at work.
- 4 8-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
3 LABOUR MARKET LEGISLATION
3.1 Employment Protection Schemes
3.1.1 The current position
In accordance with Nordic tradition and the tripartite principle, much of Finnish
labour law has been developed co-operatively by employers' and employees'
representatives and the State. Laws have often been enacted in response to labour
disputes and resulting compromises, rather than as a result of unprompted
government initiative. Case law has often formed the basis of new legislation, so that
formerly regulated terms and conditions of employment have been gradually
incorporated into labour law, Traditionally, amendments in labour law have thus
been the result, rather than the instigation, of changes in prevailing practice (Bruun
1987). However, in recent reforms aiming at relaxing employment protection, the
Government has adopted a more active role.
A General Agreement on Protection against Arbitrary Dismissals was signed by the
central labour market organisations In 1966. Before then, employers had a virtually
unrestricted right to dismiss workers. The agreement provided that a worker could
not be dismissed or laid off without a specified, valid reason. In addition,
unorganised employers were obliged to follow these regulations, in line with the
universal validity of collective agreements. As a result of labour union claims and a
trend towards general jurisdiction, labour legislation has since been amended to
cover a wide variety of terms and conditions of employment.
One important exception concerns the order in which lay-offs or redundancies are
made. According to the current agreement there are two criteria for identifying
employees who are given special protection. One is Intended to serve the Interests
of enterprises by retaining the most qualified staff. The other safeguards those who
would most suffer hardship from job loss. These criteria mean that, when reducing
the workforce, older workers have relatively little protection. Furthermore, the Finnish
system means that low priority is given to the last-in-first-out principle.
Labour law is based on the concept of an employment relationship. A person is
considered to be an employee if certain criteria are met - working under contract
for an employer under the latter's direction and supervision, in return for a wage,
salary and other remuneration. If these criteria are not met, the person performing
the work is considered to be self-employed. A recent surge of a wide variety of new
patterns of work that do not meet the criteria of an employment relationship or that
have been specifically excluded from labour law has caused a new and unsettled
situation, however, as an increasing number of people seem to be left without
employment protection. A working group has recently charted the problems and
considered ways of rectifying them (Ministry of Labour, 1996b).
To summarise the current state of employment protection, it is useful to review laws
on recruitment rules, individual dismissal and collective redundancy.
-49-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
3.1.2 Rules of recruitment
According to the Employment Contracts Act, an employment contract can have a
fixed or an indefinite duration. Fixed-term contracts have been restricted to
'objective' situations, i.e. to perform a task which itself is of a fixed duration, for
traineeshlp, or if the permanent occupant of the post is temporarily absent.
However, exemptions are permitted for other, well-founded reasons given by the
employer, A temporary amendment to the Employment Contracts Act allowed fixed
term contracts of at least six months, in order to recruit people who had been
unemployed for over a year. This temporary amendment applied from the
beginning of 1995, to the end of 1996.
A fixed-term contract ends without any separate notice when the stated period runs
out, or when the specified work is completed. Dismissals or temporary lay-offs are not
permitted during the contract period. If the term of the contract Is contrary to the
provisions of the Act, the contract can be regarded as valid for an indefinite period.
This can also be the case where an employee has a series of fixed-term contracts,
without a justified reason. This is intended to provide a ban on contract chains.
To satisfy short-term needs for additional staff, firms can use temporary work
agencies. The system for licensing agencies was abolished in 1994. From April 1996,
public employment offices started to hire temporary workers, initially in the major
employment offices of Helsinki, Turku and Tampere.
In any employment contract, It is possible, but not necessary to agree on a
probationary period of four months maximum. If the employer arranges job-related
training lasting for more than four months, the maximum length of the probationary
period is six months. During the probationary period, it is possible for both parties to
end the contract, for reasons other than those prescribed by law. Before 1987, the
probationary period was three months. The further lengthening of the period has
obviously been on the employers' agenda. However, this does not currently
constitute a major issue in Finland.
There are no general affirmative action programmes (such as quotas) for disabled
people or for promoting equal opportunities. However, some labour administration
schemes are specifically targeted at disabled people. Moreover, the Act on Equality
between Women and Men includes provisions to promote gender equality and to
ban discrimination based on gender, pregnancy or parenthood.
There are two regulations which prescribe employers' recruitment practice. The first
means that part-time workers who would prefer full-time work have priority for similar
full-time jobs in their company. The second regulation applies where there have
been previous lay-offs for economic or production reasons. In such cases, the
employer Is obliged to contact the local public employment office to check If any of
the employees made redundant are still seeking a job, Such employees are given
priority for similar vacancies in the company for nine months.
- 5 0-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
3.1.3 Rules of individual and collective dismissals
a) Grounds for dismissals and pre-notification
Ending an indefinite employment contract presupposes either that notice is given on
one side or the other, or that there has been serious misconduct or offence of
omission. Whilst a contract Is in force, an employee can be 'laid off', meaning that
the employment relationship remains valid, but that work and pay are interrupted
indefinitely or for a fixed period. If there Is a temporary decrease in an employee's
work and the employer cannot reasonably provide other work or training, the
employee can be laid off for up to 90 days. When the employer becomes aware of
the need to lay off employees, he must warn the employees' representatives, and
the labour authorities if the layoffs affect more than 10 people. The employer must
also give at least 14 days notice to the employees concerned.
The shortest prenotiflcation period for dismissals Is one month (valid from March 1996
for contracts that have been in force for less than a year). The notice period
increases with tenure to six months, where a post has been held for over 15 years. If
the employer does not observe the notice period, the employee is entitled to full
pay in lieu.
An employer can give notice on a contract, based on either Individual grounds
relating to the employee's actions or on collective grounds relating to economic
or production reasons. The latter reasons are valid only if the amount of work has
fallen substantially and if the employee cannot be reasonably, in view of his skills and
abilities, transferred or retrained. Dismissal is illegal unless both of these conditions are
met. Where there ¡s a change of ownership of a business, the new owner may give
notice within a month of the transaction if the reasons for redundancies relate to the
change of ownership.
The Employment Contracts Act also contains provisions on protection against notice
for shop stewards, pregnant women and those on maternity, paternity, parental or
childcare ieave.
b) Obligation to negotiate and sanctions of illegal actions
Under the Cooperation within Enterprises Act, employees are consulted on
collective dismissals. The Act normally covers enterprises employing 30 or more
people, but extends to companies of 20 to 29 employees If the company intends to
make at least 10 employees redundant on economic or production grounds, The
Codetermination Act specifies the obligation to negotiate. This obligation Is fulfilled
when the matter is agreed upon or if, in cases of staff cuts, the minimum negotiating
periods have passed. There are three limits for minimum negotiation periods: seven
days, plus advance notice of three days, for dealing with the employer's proposal;
two months in cases of staff cuts due to change in ownership; or three months for
cases in which the proposed measure (dismissal, transfer to parttime work or
temporary layoff for more than 90 days) concerns more than 10 people. If the
employer fails to adhere to these standards, the dismissed employees have a right to
■51
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
compensation, amounting to a maximum of 20 months' earnings. In most cases any
monetary compensation has amounted to between four and six months' wages.
In cases of unfair Individual dismissals, the Dismissals Procedures Act imposes a
conditional compensation scheme to encourage reinstatement or re-engagement.
The employer has an 'interpretation prerogative' where there is disagreement.
Employees are obliged to observe their employer's decision until the dispute has
been settled in a court of law. In practice, employers have chosen, almost without
exception, the option of higher compensation. In cases of unfair collective dismissals,
compensation for damages are determined by the Court.
The labour market organisations have also agreed rules, incorporated into their
collective agreements, for protection from dismissal, This means that any employer
tied to this kind of collective agreement must observe these rules, as minimum terms.
The agreements Include further rules on the dismissal process and on compensation
applicable in cases of unfair dismissal. In the service sector there is no such general
agreement and protection is specified solely by legislation.
Since 1970, an employee dismissed for economic or production reasons is
guaranteed a lump-sum payment if finding a new job proves difficult because of
age or other reasons. Such compensation is paid from a collective fund so that firms
are not individually responsible for payments to their redundant workers. To qualify
for the redundancy payment, the claimant must be at least 45 years of age, have
been in the job for a minimum of five years and must have been registered as an
unemployed job-seeker for at least one month. The number of recipients of this
compensation has been rather low - about 22,000 people In 1994. In addition,
payments have not been high, with the non-taxable amount corresponding to one
or two months' net earnings. The scheme, administered by the Education and
Redundancy Payment Fund, has been gradually modified along the lines of an
adult education scheme, by paying supplements for time spent in training.
3.1.4 Recent debate and policy actions
At present, two factors characterise employment protection In Finland. First, social
aspects are not given a prominent role, and second, labour legislation is heavily
based on managerial leeway, which means that there is scope for employers'
unilateral solutions. According to opinion surveys carried out in the mid-1980s, Finnish
employers, in comparison with their counterparts in most other European countries,
regarded employment protection as of minor importance. In the 1990s, employers
have expressed strong demands for lowering the threshold for hiring new employees.
A survey, carried out among small and medium-sized enterprises in spring 1996,
showed that 13% of respondents regarded labour legislation, and regulations on
collective agreements, as the most Important obstacle in hiring new employees
(Suomen Yrittäjät). Non-wage labour costs and slack demand were most frequently
cited as the most important obstacles to hiring.
- 5 2-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Recently, many Western European countries have introduced legislative changes
designed to reduce employment protection. Chronically high unemployment has
increased workers' demands for greater employment protection, and simultaneously
the economic uncertainty has reduced the employers' willingness to offer any
long-term commitments to their work-force. Even though employment protection
favours employees' loyalty and commitment to the firm, there has been quite a
strong tendency to facilitate the hiring of workers on fixed-term contracts and to
make use of subcontracted labour.
Another matter of concern ¡s a potential conflict between the objectives of security,
efficiency and equity, Employment protection is an important need for workers, but
measures to promote employment security can reduce total employment. If this Is
the case, some workers are enjoying protection that is not offered to the whole work
force. In the 1970s and 1980s, however, there were many improvements in
employment security, without a resulting growth in 'precarious' employment. In
recent years, there has been an Increasing willingness to hire casual labour. Overall,
It is arguable that protection of some workers is attained at the expense of others'
insecurity,
No Finnish evidence on the effects of labour market regulation is available, and In
international empirical studies the evidence is generally mixed (e.g. Centre of
Economic Policy Research, 1995). If regulations make It difficult to dissolve existing
employment relationships, labour adjustment through a reduction of hours rather
than dismissals, becomes more likely. On the other hand, however, there will also be
less job creation. As a result, the inflow Into unemployment will tend to decrease, as
will the outflow from unemployment. This suggests that average unemployment is not
linked to laPour market regulation in any simple way, while rigid markets do tend to
have more stable unemployment.
In autumn 1995, a working group drew up a multi-annual employment programme
for Finland following the recommendations of the European Council meeting in
Essen. On 19 October, the Council of State based its decisions-ln-principle on the
proposals of this working group. One of the recommendations included relaxing
labour regulation on job security and fixed-term employment contracts. The
measures are being prepared under tight deadlines in various Ministries, in working
groups or In tripartite negotiations between the Government and the social partners.
Early in 1996 decisions were made on reducing the employer's period of notice to
one month, instead of the previous two, if employment had lasted less than one
year. Preparatory work on atypical employment contracts will continue, aimed at
giving such contracts a status equivalent to indefinite employment contracts. The
Ministry of Labour has proposed a repeal of the ban on chain contracts and the
position of people (e.g. trainees or self-employed people) working for one employer
without a contract will be clarified. Moreover, proposals for shortening negotiating
periods and clarifying negotiation procedures, aimed at formulating amendments to
the Co-determination Act, will be produced by the Government and labour market
organisations by the end of May 1996. If no other agreement is reached, the present
three-month period will be cut to two months.
- 5 3-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
3.2 Regulation of Working Time
3.2.1 Working hours
The Working Hours Act is α general law, supplemented in many sectors by more
specific Acts. Under the Act, there are upper limits of 8 regular working hours per day
and 40 per week. The Act lists the kinds of companies and jobs in which the
employer can calculate regular working hours over extended periods, e.g. 80 hours
over 2 weeks or 120 hours in three-weeks. Using a schedule drawn up in advance for
the whole period, an employer can specify up to 48 hours in a week, as long as the
weekly average does not exceed 40 hours. The maximum extended period is about
a year. Moreover, If agreed In advance, the regular working day can be increased
to nine hours, as long as the average working week in a three-week period is not
more than 40 hours.
Overtime comprises the time in excess of regular hours, on either the daily or weekly
basis. If the latter is used, overtime on individual days is not counted. As a general
rule, an employer may not allocate to a single employee more than 200 hours of
dally overtime and 120 hours of weekly overtime. Exemption may be granted to
exceed the annual limit by 50%, with an absolute ceiling of 480 hours of overtime per
year. In all cases, the employee's consent is required.
Employees must be paid extra for overtime. The premium for daily overtime is 50% for
the first two hours and 100% for each following hour. The premium for weekly
overtime is 50%, irrespective of the number of hours. Part-time workers can work
additional hours at normal wage rates, with a premium applying to those hours
which exceed normal 'full-time' working-time, For young people under 18, there are
some further restrictions related to overtime hours and to night work.
During the past five years, some striking changes have taken place In respect of
overtime hours. During the recession, paid overtime work - compensation either In
money or leisure time - decreased, but unpaid overtime work increased (Statistics
Finland, 1995d). During the up-turn since 1994, overtime working has been Increasing.
Last year even the number of paid overtime hours increased substantially,
amounting to near the level of the boom years, and the overtime hours have
increasingly been accumulated among the same people (Ministry of Labour, 1995).
Each week, an employee must be provided with a rest period of at least 30
continuous hours. In some sectors of industry, there are also provisions for a dally rest
period.
The legislation on working hours is largely mandatory. However, where the
contracting parties are national labour market organisations, it is possible to deviate
from some provisions through collective agreements, even though this may be
disadvantageous for employees. Most sectors have collective agreements
prescribing shorter regular hours, usually between 35 to 38 per week. The option of
locally agreed arrangements for flexible working time has been used mainly to
lengthen daily working hours, as long as they remain at the average level over a
■54-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
period of 7 to 8 weeks. This option has not, however, been open to unorganised
employers.
A comprehensive reform of the Working Hours Act was prepared on a tripartite basis.
The social partners could not agree on the details of the reform, but the
Government Bill was submitted to Parliament in April 1996 a nd will be implemented
when required by the EU Directive. The main features of the proposal concern local
negotiations, and the maxima for overtime and for rest periods. Options for local
negotiations, within the framework of collective agreements, will be extended to
unorganised companies which are required to observe collective agreements. The
maximum number of overtime hours will be reduced to 330 and the weekly rest
period will be Increased to 35 hours, averaged over 14 days. Daily rest periods will be
set at 11 hours a nd working hours, in the period, to 9. With the consent of employees,
it will be possible to shorten the rest period to 7 hours.
Employers resisted the cut In overtime hours and would have liked to agree a
reduction in the overtime hours pay premium. Unions were opposed to the changes
concerning daily rest periods, as well as to the further exclusion of upper-level senior
staff from the range of working hours protection.
3.2.2 Annual leave
The Annual Leave Act prescribes employees' rights to paid annual leave. The Act is
based on the earnings principle, which states that annual leave Is earned by work
carried out during the previous year. The amount of annual leave depends on the
number of months giving entitlement to leave. Work in a calendar month gives
entitlement to annual leave only when at least 14 days, or 35 hours, have been
worked. Under the Act, once an employment relationship has lasted a full year, the
maximum annual leave Is 30 week days, six of which have to be taken outside the
normal holiday season (May 2 to September 30). The provisions of the Act are
unconditional a nd any contract that reduces an employee's entitlement is null and
void. The social partners may, however, agree on entitlements that go beyond the
Act.
Reform of the Annual Leave Act is underway, Employees' organisations have
emphasised that annual leave should accrue in proportion to the amount of work
performed, without restrictions related to the number of hours or days worked.
Employers have proposed increases in the scope of local negotiations.
3.2.3 Career breaks and work sharing
a) Leaves arising from individual needs
In Finland every expectant or nursing mother is eligible for a maternity allowance.
The statutory leave is 263 working days, some of which (158 days) may be transferred
to the father if the mother agrees. In practice, the conversion of maternity leave into
parental leave has not affected the family division of labour to any considerable
■55-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
degree. Most of those fathers who take advantage of this option are on leave for
less than a month.
Employees also have discretionary rights to special leave for reasons related to
child-care and study. A system of child-care leave was introduced gradually
between 1985 and 1989. This makes it possible for either the mother or the father to
stay at home to take care of the child even after the parental leave, until the child
reaches the age of three. The employer is not obliged to remunerate the employee
but, in terms of employment security, the essential point is that after the leave the
employee is entitled to return to her or his previous job. The entitlement to return also
applies for other statutory leaves - parental, study or job-rotation leave.
According to the Study Leave Act an employee whose main employment with the
same employer has lasted for at least one year is entitled to a maximum of two
years' unpaid study ieave for any period of five years' service (for details of the
associated compensation, see Section 5.2). The employer has a right to postpone
the beginning of the leave for up to six months. If the leave has been granted for
more than 50 working-days, an employee can interrupt the leave. However, if the
employer has recruited another person to replace the permanent occupant, the
employer can refuse to accept the interruption.
Since the late 1980s, there has also been a voluntary part-time pension scheme
which does not include compulsory replacement. A part-time pension can be
awarded to employees aged 58-64 who have long work-careers and who change
from full- to part-time work (i.e. an average 16-28 hours per week). The replacement
rate is 50% of the earnings losses. The number of part-time pensioners is quite low,
amounting to 4,500 in 1994, or about 1% of the total population of eligible age,
b) Schemes to promote work sharing
During the past few years, three special schemes - the job rotation scheme, the part-
time pay supplement scheme and the '6+6 hour day shift model' - have been
launched to promote work sharing. So far, the take-up of these schemes has
remained rather low, however, A temporary job-rotation scheme, Introduced In
1996, was intended to give employees more scope to undertake studies and to take
ieave for personal or family reasons, while at the same time giving unemployed
people a foothold In working life. The scheme is based on a voluntary agreement
between a full-time employee and the employer. The employee may take unpaid
leave for a period of three to twelve months, retaining pension rights. The employer is
obliged to recruit an unemployed job-seeker for the same period, but not
necessarily for the same job. The employer is not entitled to any employment subsidy
In hiring the unemployed substitute, which means that there are no financial
incentives for employers to engage in the job rotation and the part-time pay
supplement schemes. The person on job rotation leave receives compensation
amounting to 60% of the appropriate unemployment allowance, up to a celling of
FIM 4,500 per month. If the person undertakes full-time vocational training, an
- 5 6-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
additional training supplement of FIM 1,000 is awarded. The Ministry of Labour, in
co-operation with the social partners, is to further promote the job rotation scheme.
Temporary job-sharing Is also encouraged by a part-time pay supplement scheme,
valid from March 1994 to the end of 1996. In this scheme, a person voluntarily
changing from full- to part-time work can be granted a pay supplement to
compensate (at most 50%) for loss of earnings. The supplement can be paid for a
maximum of twelve months, with the person thereafter entitled to return to full-time
work. The employer has to recruit an unemployed job-seeker for the same period,
The '6+6 hour day-shift model' is not new, but is a reinstated model for reducing
working time. In this model, work is organised in two consecutive six-hour shifts,
running, for example, from 6-12 and 12-18, or from 8-14 and 14-20. The shifts can
overlap and do not Include any lunch-break.
The day-shift model has reappeared as a means of increasing operation times,
reducing overtime and regular working hours in capital-intensive activities. A few
manufacturing enterprises have started to implement the model. In the firms
concerned, the very substantial increases in productivity have made It possible to
pay the same compensation for 6-hour work as for the previous 8-hour work. Under
such circumstances, it is hardly surprising that the system seems to work well, to the
satisfaction of both employers and employees. However, it will prove more difficult to
introduce the scheme in enterprises where the ensuing rise in productivity is not likely
to be as significant, In spring 1996, the government started to negotiate with the
Association of Finnish Local Authorities and the employee organisations on the
possibility of implementing the scheme in the public sector. The City of Helsinki has
expressed Interest In applying the scheme to a few social service units, seeking to
solve problems relating to inconvenient service hours.
The Government is encouraging arrangements for flexible working time, particularly
at the company level. This is part of the development of new patterns of work, taking
into account the need for convenient operating and service hours and the
individual needs of workers. Further negotiations will also be held with the social
partners on the reduction of restrictions on shop opening hours.
c) Provision of part-time work
As a rule, there are no obstacles to providing part-time jobs. A part-time contract
can be used if both employer and employee are In agreement. However, transfer to
part-time work, against the wishes of an employee, Is permitted only if there are
grounds for dismissal and the proper period of notice and negotiation is observed.
The same is true for temporary lay-offs that take place partially by changing over to
a shortened working week. Employees themselves have no right to reduce their
working hours, unless they are parents of children under school-age.
■57-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
d) Reduction of working hours
Traditionally, major demands for shorter working hours have coincided with periods
of rapid economic growth. As productivity has increased, people have wanted to
Increase leisure time, instead of taking higher real wages, Reductions In working time
have mostly taken the form of shorter weekly working hours and longer vacations. In
the late 1980s, working-time issues were increasingly discussed from the point of view
of longer time horizons, putting more emphasis on wider opportunities for career
breaks and sabbatical and study leaves. Moreover, flexible working time
arrangements serving the needs of production processes, in particular, were rapidly
introduced.
Recently, working time became a far more controversial issue as calls were made to
share work as a remedy to unemployment. Employers reject working-time reductions
and want, instead, more working-time flexibility, irregular patterns of work and longer
working-hours. Unions are more favourable towards various kinds of working-time
arrangements that reduce the number of performed working hours over a working
career. Offering employees better opportunities for regular adult training provides
one such route. However, views on general reductions of working time are more
diverse.
The most recent general reductions in working time were in the late 1980s, when the
number of annual hours for those working more than 40 hours per week was
gradually cut by a total of 68 (the so-called Pekkasvapaat). It is these reductions in
working-time, in particular, that many employers demand to be repealed, without
any increases in total earnings. Longer hours are considered by employers as means
of lowering unit costs and boosting competitiveness, i.e. as a measure of internal
devaluation.
The employers' demand for longer working time is also based on international
comparisons. In 1995, Finnish manufacturing industry showed an average of 1,716
regular annual working hours in day-work. This compares, for example, with 1,602
hours In Germany, 1,673 hours in Denmark and 1,697 in Austria. At the high end of
the scale, the number of annual hours in Portugal was 1,882. However, if differences
across countries in terms of absenteeism, overtime work and incidence of part-time
work are taken into account, the number of performed working-hours per employee
Is very high in Finland.
There are two aspects to the discussion of reducing working hours. The first relates to
the reduction of average annual or life-long working time, primarily as part of
general welfare policy. Examples of initiatives include those aimed at alleviating the
mismatch between actual and desired working hours and promoting opportunities
for self-financed sabbatical leaves by establishing, for example, 'time banks' and
'time savings' from overtime hours and untaken annual leave.
The second aspect of the discussion focuses on work-sharing, as exemplified by
schemes which depend on public finances, like job rotation or part-time pay
supplements.
■58-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Sector-specific reductions in annual hours could also be seen as a means of
achieving low inflation targets. Given the diversity of productivity growth rates and
the marked wage-wage-links In wage formation across the manufacturing industries,
the arising tensions In wage developments could be alleviated if part of productivity
gains could be used to increase leisure time. In the long run, this would also slow
down the decrease in the number of industrial jobs.
3.3 Minimum Wage Regulation
Minimum wages are set by collective agreements, As discussed in Section 2.2, these
mandatory terms apply also to non-signatory parties, if there is a national collective
agreement which is universally valid for the sector concerned. However, there are
sectors, especially in services, which have no universally binding collective
agreement.
Sectoral agreements imply that there are differences in minimum wage levels across
sectors. In most collective agreements, minimum wages are graded by age so that
under 18's can be paid lower wages. Moreover, municipalities have been divided
into two categories with separate scales of tariffs, to reflect variations in the cost of
living. This means that, in practice, there is some differentiation of minimum wages by
sector, age and region. In addition, for large employers, payroll taxes tend to lower
the relative labour costs for under 23's (cf. section 1.5). This is due to the fact that
employers' statutory contributions to employment pensions are lower for young
employees, whose employment contracts do not give entitlement to employment
pension.
It Is often suggested that minimum wages adversely affect the employment
prospects of young people who are trying to get a foothold in the labour market,
From the early 1980s onwards, the limited evidence suggests that minimum wages
had some, but not a substantial impact on youth unemployment.
A temporary two-year agreement (valid to mid-1995), between the central labour
market organisations allowed, on certain conditions, the employment of young
people on pay which was 10-50% lower than the minimum wages specified in
collective agreements. However, this scheme had no noticeable impacts (cf.
Section 1.4.3).
Recently, demands have frequently been made, in particular by employers but also
by outside observers, for a repeal of the mandatory status of minimum terms
specified in collective agreements, as well as the extension of collective agreements
to non-signatory parties. These demands are based on two factors. Firstly, they are
related to the promotion of local bargaining In general, to make It possible to take
local conditions and profitability concerns better into account when setting wages.
The second factor relates to the level of minimum wages. It Is argued that
unemployed people are unable to compete with incumbents on the basis of lower
wages, because of the wage floors negotiated by the insiders. The Government
programme says, however, that the principle of the universal applicability of
-59-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
collective agreements will be observed and a system of minimum standards for terms
of employment will be guaranteed (Halving unemployment, p. 36).
•60-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4 LABOUR MARKET POLICIES
4.1 Passive measures
4.1.1 Unemployment benefit schemes: Basic characteristics and recent
developments
Unemployment benefit schemes based on both insurance and assistance principles
are In operation In Finland. Membership of an insurance fund is voluntary and
unemployment Insurance funds are mainly operated by the trade unions, although
employees have a legal right to join a union Ul fund without joining the union itself.
However, this right is rarely exerted. There Is also a smaller independent insurance
fund. Basic unemployment allowance, as well as the recently introduced labour
market support, are administered by the Social Insurance Institute.
The detailed provisions of the unemployment benefit schemes have been changed
several times. A major reform took place in 1985, when both insurance benefit and
the basic allowance became liable to tax. Moreover, instead of being a flat-rate
benefit, insurance benefit was changed to an earnings-related benefit. The reform
sharply Increased the replacement rates for the Insured unemployed. Basic
allowances were payable, on a means-tested basis, to uninsured people for an
unlimited time.
In the late 1980s, the maximum duration of the earnings-related benefits was
increased in phases, and in 1991, limits on Ul duration were removed for all workers
aged 55 or over. To curb the growth In unemployment Insurance expenditure, the
level of Ul benefits was lowered from the beginning of 1992. The compensation
percentage of the earnings-related part was then lowered. The following year, a few
more amendments were made to tighten the qualifying conditions. The initial waiting
period of the basic allowance for those entering the labour market was lengthened
from six weeks to three months and the disqualifying period for those who had quit
their last job was lengthened from six to eight weeks. Legitimate reasons for refusing
job offers without a disqualification from benefits were also tightened and students'
benefits were dropped, even during summer vacations. Disqualifying decisions are
made by tripartite bodies at local public employment service offices (cf, section 2.1).
In 1994, the basic unemployment allowance was changed to become more similar
to unemployment insurance by introducing a qualifying condition of employment
record and a maximum duration of payment and by waiving means-testing. New
labour market support was introduced for those who are not eligible for the benefits
or whose benefits have been exhausted.
4.1.2 Unemployment benefit schemes: The present position
There are three kinds of unemployment allowances:
• earnings-related unemployment allowance;
• basic unemployment allowance; and
■61 -
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
•
labour market support.
These are payable depending on whether or not the employment condition is
satisfied and whether or not the person concerned belongs to the unemployment
Insurance fund (Chart 11), All the benefits are payable to unemployed people
between 17 and 64, who have registered with a public employment office, seek full-
time employment and are fit and available for work. However, unemployed people
are obliged to a c c e pt job offers given to them by the public employment offices,
but during the first three months an unemployed person is not obliged to a c c e pt
work which does not m a t ch his or her professional skills or qualifications. Thereafter,
beneficiaries have to a c c e pt any full-time job as long as pay is in a c c o r d a n ce with
collective agreements a nd pay minus travel expenses exceed unemployment
benefit, However, the low number of registered job vacancies a nd the shortage of
staff resources at public employment service offices may have resulted, in practice,
to a relaxation of this work test,
Chart 11 : Unemployment benefit schemes in Finland
Employment condition satisfied
Member of unemployment
fund
Non-member
Earnings-related
unemployment
allowance
500 days
Labour market support (unlimited period")
Non-means
tested-180 days
Means-tested
Waiting period - 5 days
Basic
unemployment
allowance
500 days
Labour market suDDort (unlimited Deriod)
Non-means
tested- 180 days
Means-tested
Waiting period - 5 days
Employment condition not satisfied
Newly graduated people
Labour market support (unlimited period)
means tested
Others
Labour market support (unlimited period)
means tested
Waiting period - 3 months
Source: Social Insurance Institution (1995)
- 6 2-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
People satisfying the employment condition are entitled to either the earnings
related unemployment allowance (fund members) or the basic unemployment
allowance (others). The condition of employment record Is considered to be satisfied
if the person has been employed for at least 6 months during the previous 24 months
in a job where the regular working time was at least Ì 8 hours per week and pay was
in a c c o r d a n ce with collective agreements. The same condition holds for the
duration of membership of the Ul fund. Benefits are payable for a maximum of 500
working days without any meanstesting. However, those who reach the a ge of 55
before the exhaustion of benefits are entitled to extra days so that unemployment
benefits are payable till the age of 60, when the person qualifies for unemployment
pension. Otherwise, where benefits have been exhausted, the unemployed person
may receive labour market support of 180 days without meanstesting. Thereafter,
meanstested labour market support is payable for an unlimited time,
The days during which the person participates In active labour market policy
measures (either labour market training, rehabilitation or work) are not counted as
unemployed days. Working for six months during a period of eight months requallfies
for unemployment benefits (return condition). In cases of recurrent unemployment,
the reference pay in calculating the earningsrelated benefits dates back to the pay
before first becoming unemployed, as long as the temporary work lasts up to six
months. As the condition of employment c an be renewed by a job of six months, the
incentive to a c c e pt an uncertain, lower paid job for more than six months is
distorted since, if becoming unemployed again, the Ul benefit would be paid on the
basis of the lower paid job.
Labour market support is available for those who are not eligible for benefits or
whose benefits have been exhausted. This labour market support Is equal In amount
to the basic allowance, although firsttime entrants to the labour market who live
with their parents get 60% of the full amount of the benefit. However, young people
without any vocational or other training beyond the basic compulsory education
are not eligible for the labour market support before the a ge of 20, A person who
receives labour market support may participate in apprenticeship training, labour
market training, rehabilitation or practical training in a job (without an employment
relationship and pay). In exchange for the support, he or she may also be obliged to
participate in such measures. During participation in these measures, labour market
support Is always paid at the full rate.
People temporarily laidoff, as well as those on shorttime schedules, are entitled to
adjusted daily allowances. In cases of casual earnings, the benefitcut rate applied
in calculating the adjusted daily unemployment allov/ances is 80% of the earnings in
excess of FIM 750 per month.
The earningsrelated benefit consists of the basic allowance plus an earningsrelated
part, which is 42% of earnings above this basic allowance up to a second break
point (which is slightly higher than average earnings), plus 20% of earnings a b o ve this
level. The benefit is increased for dependent children. The amount of the fund
benefit including the child supplements could be up to 90% of the Insured person's
earnings.
■63
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
In 1994, the average amounts of paid unemployment benefits (including child
supplements) by type of benefit were as follows:
• earnings-related unemployment allowance - FIM 4,487 per month, on average;
• basic unemployment allowance, flat rate - FIM 2,554;
•
labour market support, flat rate equal to the basic unemployment allowance,
reduced rate for first-time entrants to the labour market living with their parents -
FIM 2,367.
In the case of earnings-related benefits, the replacement rate is inversely related to
the level of earnings, and because of child supplements, the replacement rate is
higher for those with dependents (Table 11).
Table 11 : Gross replacement rates of earnings-related unemployment benefits by level of
earnings gnd family status
Monthly Pay
Replacement Rate
FIM 5,000
FIM 6,000
FIM 7,000
FIM 8,000
FIM 9,000
FIM 10,000
FIM 12,000
FIM 15,000
No Child
70%
65%
62%
59%
57%
55%
49%
43%
Two Children
85%
78%
72%
68%
65%
63%
56%
49%
Since the previous monthly earnings of unemployed people usually vary between
FIM 6,000 and FIM 9,000, the average gross replacement rate amounts to about 60%,
or slightly more. The replacement rate corresponds to average European levels,
although for basic unemployment allowance and labour market support, the
replacement rate is clearly lower than in most other countries. Due to the low level of
basic compensation, many of the beneficiaries are also entitled to other means-
tested cash benefits, like living allowance.
Against this background, empirical findings on the impact of unemployment benefits
on the duration of unemployment spells are interesting. These studies (Eriksson, 1985;
Lilja, 1993; Kettunen, 1993) - admittedly from the late 1980s - using Finnish individual
panel data suggested that people eligible for Ul benefits had a much higher
probability of becoming employed than recipients of basic unemployment
allowances, even though the replacement rate in the Ul scheme is generally much
higher. Kettunen (1993) found a strong negative effect of the replacement rate on
the duration of unemployment among the recipients of basic unemployment
allowance, whereas the corresponding effect for Ul claimants was Insignificant.
One possible interpretation of these findings is that they reflect selection into the two
compensation schemes; recipients of Ul benefits were more closely attached to the
labour market before becoming unemployed, Another explanation arises from the
combined effect of various social security benefits, not only that of unemployment
•64-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
benefit, Due to the low level of compensation, claimants of basic unemployment
allowance are often entitled to other cash benefits. In respect of living allowances,
for Instance, the effective marginal tax rate is 100%.
Even though the unionisation rate has been very high in Finland, the coverage of Ul
scheme a m o ng unemployed people has been much lower. This is due to several
factors related to the incidence of unemployment (the unionisation rate a m o ng
those with high risks of unemployment, e.g. youths and those in irregular jobs, are
lower than on average), the qualifying condition of employment record, waiting
periods and the exhaustion of benefits. On the other hand, the share not receiving
any compensation at all has hovered at about one-fifth. In recent years, due to the
broader incidence of the risk of unemployment in the services sector a nd a m o ng
white-collar workers as well as those closely a t t a c h ed to the labour market, the non-
coverage share fell to less than 10% in autumn 1993. Along with longer spells of
unemployment, it is plausible that the exhaustion of benefits will increase sharply.
Thereafter, a tight means-testing which is tied to the spouse's income will lead to a
marked drop in the coverage of unemployment benefit schemes.
Tgble 12: Coverage of earninas-relgted gllowonces end bgsic allowances (as percentage of
total beneficiaries of unemployment benefits), 1989-1995
Year
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
Earnings-related
allowances
Basic
allowances
54.8%
57.6%
59.0%
60.0%
62.1%
57.4%
49.1%
45.2%
42.4%
41.0%
40.0%
37.9%
42.6%*
50.9%*
Note: In 1994 and 1995, the figures consist of two elements: shares of basic
allowonce and labour market support. The shares of basic allowance were
29.6% and 22.6% in 1994 and 1995, respectively. Similarly, the shares of labour
market support were 13.0% and 28.3%.
There is some overlap in the coverage since due to the exhaustion of the
primary unemployment benefit, the same person may have received two
types of benefits during a year. That is why the share of earnings-related
benefits tend to reflect changes in the coverage with a lag.
Source: Statistics by the Ministry of Social Affairs and Health.
In recent years, some 60% of those receiving unemployment benefits were paid
earnings-related benefits (Table 12). The position is changing rapidly, however. There
are several illustrations of this shift. In April 1996, the number of registered jobseekers
entitled to labour market support amounted to 206,800, slightly less than a half of
them because their employment records did not satisfy the qualifying criteria for
unemployment allowance a nd the rest (52%) because of the exhaustion of other
unemployment benefits.
-65-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Despite the activating tendency involved in the labour market scheme, most of the
beneficiaries -161,000 - were unemployed and they accounted for 36% of total
unemployed jobseekers, However, among teenagers, placements with labour
market support make up a great majority of all measures under active labour market
policy,
In assessing the Finnish unemployment benefit system, a few features have recently
been given increasing attention. They include the following:
• the way reference pay is determined in the calculation of earnings-related Ul
benefits;
• the high benefit-cut rate (80%) applied in calculating the adjusted daily
unemployment allowances in respect of casual earnings;
• the unlimited duration of unemployment benefits for those over 55 years of age;
• the relatively long duration of unemployment benefits (500 working days) by
international standards; and
• the relatively short employment record qualifying for unemployment benefits.
4.1.3 Reform of the unemployment benefit schemes in Spring 1996
In May 1996, the Government submitted a proposal to Parliament for reforms to
achieve savings in earnings-related unemployment benefits and to render the
scheme more proactive. The reform was first negotiated on a tripartite basis, but,
since the social partners were not able to reach an agreement, the Government
itself made the proposal. The main elements of the reforms, which are to be
implemented from the beginning of 1997, are as follows:
• The condition of employment record (as well as the condition of Ul membership)
will be extended from 6 to 10 months.
• The period for renewing the condition of employment record will be prolonged
from 6 to 10 months; the accounting period will be lengthened from 8 to 24
months. Up to 16 weeks of labour market training can be included in the
condition of employment record.
The pay of the last job will make up the reference pay in calculating the earnings-
related unemployment allowance. However, the new benefit will amount to at
least 80% of the previous Ul benefit.
In calculating the adjusted unemployment allowances, the benefit-cut rate will
be lowered from 80% to 50%. The benefit-cut rate will be applied for all monthly
earnings without any protected part (FIM 750 at present).
The waiting period will be seven days instead of five, but the waiting period will be
applied just once during the 500 days of benefit eligibility.
Accrued days of annual leave must be taken before the calculation of waiting
period starts.
■66-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
• Older people's entitlement to extra benefit days will be restricted by raising the
qualifying age from 55 to 57 years. However, older people whose benefits would
therefore be exhausted will be granted a subjective right to a subsidised job for 10
months.
• Young people without any vocational or other training beyond the basic
compulsory education will not be eligible for labour market support before the
age of 25 (20 at present).
• No index adjustments will be made to the level of unemployment benefits in 1997-
1999.
• The employment pension that accrues from the period of Ul benefits will be
reduced to 80% of the current level.
In autumn 1995, the Government decided to allocate a certain amount of money
for granting (under certain conditions) to unemployed people within the Ul scheme,
the right to income support equal to his or her earnings-related benefit for periods of
vocational training. At present, participation in labour market training entitles people
to a similar training allowance. In optional training, however, the person is entitled to
an adult study grant which is much lower than the Ul benefit. The Government
decided in May 1996 that an employment record of 8 years would entitle an
unemployed person to this training insurance. Other details are still open, and the
Government has agreed that an administrator will be nominated to continue
preparations for the introduction of this Insurance In 1998,
4.1.4 Funding of the unemployment benefit schemes
The current reform of the unemployment benefit schemes has been motivated both
by the aim of improving the functioning of the labour market and by the aim of
achieving savings in unemployment expenditure. Basic allowances and labour
market support are entirely financed by central government through tax revenues.
Central government also finances part of the earnings-related benefits which
corresponds to the amount of basic allowances. The earnings-related part Is
financed by employers, by insured people and, temporarily, by all employees. The
evolution of total expenditure on unemployment benefits is displayed in Table 13.
-67-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 13: Evolution of unemployment benefit expenditure (FIM million) by type and financier,
1985-1995
Year
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
Year
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
Basic
Allowance
1,163
1,323
1,406
1,267
906
860
£321
4,464
6,789
5,133
Ζ 703
Type at Benefit
Total
Labour market
support
Unemployment
insurance
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
1,306
4,089
1,620
1,928
2,034
2,098
1,906
2,217
5,678
10,879
15,176
14,828
12,977
2.783
3,251
3,440
3.365
2,812
3,077
7,999
15,343
20,965
21,267
19,769
State
Employers
Insured
Employees
Financier
1,940
2,248
2,382
2,274
1,821
1,924
5,046
9,632
12,684
8,798
8,798
761
906
956
986
896
1,042
2,669
5,113
7,133
4,153
4,153
81
96
102
105
95
111
284
598
835
714
714
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
314
2.016
2,016
Source: Statistics by the Social Insurance Institute and Ministry of Social Affairs
and Health
Since the financing of the earnings-related part takes place on a pay-as-you-go
basis, the huge rise in unemployment resulted in a substantial rise in the employers'
unemployment insurance contribution. This c o m p o n e nt of the payroll tax increased
from less than 1 % regularly, to more than 5% in 1994 a nd 1995. To alleviate the
upward pressure, a general employees' contribution (1,87%) was introduced in 1994.
In 1996, the private employers' unemployment insurance contribution is 1% of the
part of the payroll not exceeding the first FIM 5 million, and 4% of the remainder. The
employees' contribution is 1.5%. Moreover, membership fees of Ul funds vary within
the range of 0.1 and 2.2%. The division of costs between employers and employees
has been c h a n g ed a few times; notwithstanding this sharing, the surge in
unemployment has caused a marked rise In the tax w e d ge (cf. Sections 1.5 a nd 5.3).
4.1.5 Unemployment pension scheme
Beside unemployment allowance, there Is also an unemployment pension scheme in
operation. The aim of the scheme is to provide income security for long-term
- 6 8-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
unemployed people aged 6064, who have received unemployment allowance for
the maximum period. In order to qualify for the pension, claimants must have been
employed for at least five years during the previous 15 years and be entitled to an
employment pension that includes a part based on the hypothetical accrual of the
pension after the pension contingency. It is paid at a rate equal to the disability
pension the claimant would have received if he or she had become disabled
instead of unemployed. Unemployment pensions are granted from the statutory
pension schemes and financed through the following: national pensions by
employer and employee contributions and central government; and employment
pensions by Insurance premiums paid by employers and employees.
The whole scheme was Introduced in 1972, but during the period 19801989 the
qualifying age limit was temporarily lowered to 5559, as in the early 1980s.
Withdrawal of older people from the labour market was favoured as a means of
tackling unemployment and alleviating industrial restructuring. Owing to the large
number of unemployment pensioners, the scheme became very costly by the
mid1980s. This led to a tightening of eligibility, and the qualifying age limit was
gradually increased to 60 years, As retirement on this scheme has usually meant a
final exit from the labour market, unemployed pensioners were excluded from the
unemployment figures. This change was made in the employment service statistics
by the Ministry of Labour in 1981 and in the Labour Force Survey by Statistics Finland
In 1987. The number of people on unemployment pension has decreased from a
peak of 69,000 in 1987, to some 40,000 in 1995, The latter number accounted for 16%
of the age group.
4.1.6 The balance of passive and active measures
Despite the expressed target to resort more to active than to passive measures, the
emphasis has changed markedly towards passive measures during the early 1990s. In
the late Ì 980s, active labour market measures accounted for about 40% of total
spending on labourmarket programmes (active measures plus income
maintenance), a figure very close to the OECD average. National differences are
substantial, however, with labour market policy being the most active in Sweden
and the most passive in Spain. The striking thing Is that during the economic
recession, the Finnish position in international comparisons has deteriorated. In 1993
and 1994, the proportion of total expenditure for active measures was only 25%,
similar to countries with the most passive policy stance (OECD, 1995a, Statistical
Annex).
Total labour market policy expenditure (passive and active) averaged 2.5% of GDP
from 1985 to 1991. As a result of the steep rise in unemployment, It reached almost
7% of GDP in 1993 and 1994, the highest in the EU area. Passive expenditure,
adjusted for the rise in unemployment, however, declined relative to GDP between
1990 and 1993. Expenditure on active measures for each 5% of the labour force
unemployed was around 0.5% of GDP in 1993 (European Commission, 1995). By this
criterion, labour market policy was more active in Portugal, Belgium, Denmark,
■69
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Austria, Germany, Netherlands and, in particular, Sweden, where the corresponding
figure was 1.5%. Given the very high level of unemployment in Finland, however, it is
obvious that any substantial increase in the volume of active measures is difficult
without harmful or distortionary side-effects. On the other hand, the division
between active and passive measures has become less clear-cut, along with the
pro-active changes in unemployment benefit schemes.
4.2 Active measures
Historically, labour market policies in Finland were designed to sustain employment
through active measures rather than passive income support. Until the 1960s, there
was no state unemployment benefit system and unemployment benefits from
vocational funds were insignificant, while local and central governments were
committed to providing jobs for unemployed people through public works. The
Employment Act of 1971 shifted the emphasis of labour market policy in a supply
direction, by giving a much greater role to vocational training and promotion of
regional and occupational migration.
The reorientation in labour market policies in the 1970s did not, however, totally
displace the old emphasis on job creation programmes, In fact, selective
employment measures (such as temporary public sector or subsidised private sector
jobs) were substantially stepped up in response to the economic recession in the late
1970s.
A new impetus to active labour market programmes was given by the 1987
Employment Act (operative in high-unemployment regions since 1988 and in the
whole country since 1990). This reinforced the policy emphasis given to youth and
long-term unemployed people and committed central and local governments - as a
measure of last resort - to providing either a temporary job or training for young
people under 20 years of age and for long-term unemployed people (after an
unemployment period of three and twelve months, respectively). In addition, the Act
was intended to balance regional discrepancies so that unemployment in any
district would not deviate essentially from the country average. The upper limit for
the unemployment rate in any region was set at a level 80% higher than the country
average.
The statutory obligations were lifted at the beginning of 1992 by removing, from the
definition of long-term unemployment, the accumulation of individuals' short-term
unemployment spells. In addition, from August 1992, the qualifying unemployment
period for teenagers was lengthened to six months. To prevent a sharp rise in
statutory placements, the provision of temporary jobs was changed so that they
could only be provided in response to requests from unemployed people. This
meant that withholding benefits for a definite period was no longer used as an
incentive to accept work or training offered by the labour administration. The
waiting period was extended from six to eight weeks in September 1993.
Statutory obligations for arranging training or work for long-term and young
unemployed people were totally lifted from the beginning of 1993. Nevertheless,
■70-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
these groups of people, together with those at risk of long-term unemployment,
continued to be the main target groups for active labour market policy.
Active labour market measures did not have significant coverage, even whilst
statutory obligations were in force. At best, In 1989, about 35% of all unemployed
job-seekers were either in training or employed In subsidised jobs. This proportion was
comparable to that In 1980. Alongside the growth in statutory obligations, there was
a corresponding cut in discretionary measures (see Table 14 for subsidised
employment). In addition, the proportion of completed spells of unemployment
which were terminated by active labour market measures rose quite moderately -
from 21% in 1987, to 26% in 1992. It was, therefore, the incidence of the measures
rather than their scope that was mostly affected by the binding obligations. The
most significant effect of the obligations was in tackling the problem of long-term
unemployment.
Table 14: People employed in subsidised ¡obs, annugl gveraaes, 1987-1992
Year
Total
Discretionary
placements
Statutory
placements
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
35672
36863
34481
30538
40137
52080
35672
19406
10396
5177
5165
8664
0
17430
24085
25361
34972
43416
Statutory, % of
total placements
0
47
70
83
87
83
Source: Ministry of Labour, Employment Service Statistics.
Given that the statutory obligation to provide either training or temporary jobs has
been abolished, it could be argued that, since 1993, any placements that have
been made through wage subsidies have been discretionary. However, the
abolition of the measures did not apply to those people who had been covered by
them before 1993. Employment allocations continued to be targeted at those
people unemployed for at least six months (especially long-term unemployed
people and youths), as well being used to promote employment of disabled people
and to reduce regional disparities in unemployment. Indeed, the statutory obligation
to minimise regional discrepancies was retained In the new Employment Act. Since
regional disparities In open unemployment narrowed during the recession, however,
the provision lost much of its previous effect.
Subsidised work was meant as a measure of last resort. The aim was to allow a
combination of subsidised work with other activities like training, attending
introduction courses or counselling groups, in a more flexible way than previously in
order to improve people's position on the open labour market. However,
opportunities in the normal labour market were scarce. The provision of temporary
jobs helped, therefore, to maintain people's involvement in the labour market. Given
high unemployment and low demand for labour, the measures were not particularly
effective In leading to gainful employment shortly after subsidy periods.
71
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
A majority of those employed in subsidised jobs worked in the public sector. The
employers' organisations have emphasised that wage subsidies exert harmful effects
on the competitive position of various firms and tend to cause rigidities in the
functioning of the labour market. Subsidies to private companies led to speculation
and all too often it was the company applying for the subsidy, rather than the
employment office, that determined which unemployed job-seekers were selected.
This reduced the scope for targeting the measures on sound labour-policy grounds.
There also seemed to be some tension in the views of specific companies and
employers' organisations. Employers' organisations have argued for greater flexibility
in wage determination, lower payroll taxes and relaxation of hiring and firing rules, as
alternatives to wage subsidies,
In the early 1990s, there were almost 20 different forms of employment subsidies. The
very strict and detailed subsidy rules rendered the system inflexible and time
consuming. As the problems inherent in the system were aggravated by mass
unemployment, the employment subsidy schemes were again changed In April
1995. The number of subsidies was reduced to five, the discretionary power and
freedom of action by the employment offices were increased and the condition of
a minimum spell of unemployment as a prerequisite for subsidised placements was
lifted. Moreover, conditions for granting subsidies to enterprises were tightened while
the amount of the subsidy relative to wages was lowered. And most importantly, in
exchange for the subsidy, private enterprises were required either to sign a
permanent (i.e. valid until further notice) contract of employment or to provide
apprenticeship training or, for people with poor employment opportunities, to
provide other training and rehabilitation.
The amendment was introduced to decrease dead-weight effects and any
distortionary effects of the previous scheme. An alternative way of tackling those
harmful effects would have been to target the scheme on the most hard-hit groups,
like long-term unemployed people. The changes signified a new direction,
compared to the previous tendency to provide more temporary job opportunities in
the private sector, where the chances for lasting employment after the subsidy
period were better. The reform caused a fall of one fifth in the total number of
placements into subsidised jobs in the private sector.
In the 1980s, the average number of people employed with wage-related measures
amounted to 33,000. The number peaked at 66,400 In 1994 and in 1995 about 64,000
people (2.6% of the labour force) were employed in subsidised jobs, each for an
average period of five months. Similar developments were also apparent in labour
market training. The number of labour market trainees increased from 16,800, on
average, in 1990, to 34,000 - or 1,4% of the total labour force - in 1995. The number of
people who started training increased correspondingly from 36,000 to 90,000, while
the average duration of courses fell from six to four months. The increase in the
demand for training was even stronger, however, making access to training more
difficult, in 1995, about a half of all applicants were accepted for training.
Labour market training is primarily vocational training. Trainees are selected by
labour authorities and, since 1990, the authorities have been free to purchase
72-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
training from any provider. Although job-related training is chiefly a responsibility of
employers, labour market training may be purchased jointly by local authorities and
employers, In order to meet companies' specific needs.
Labour market training has been increasingly targeted at unemployed people and
people at risk of unemployment. This reflects the acute need to sharpen the focus of
labour market policy during the depression. The training Is particularly directed at
adults, while teenagers and young adults tend to be guided to optional training.
Due to lack of job opportunities, the scope of training has also been extended to
help those interested in entrepreneurship and self-employment. About 10% of those
who have completed labour market training have participated in entrepreneurial
training. Attempts have also been m a de to combine training and start-up grants -
with very satisfactory results, according to an assessment by the labour
administration.
People taking part in labour market training are eligible for training allowances.
Members of unemployment funds receive earnings-related allowances equal to
unemployment insurance benefits. For non-members, the training allowance is not
means-tested but equates to basic unemployment allowance. People dismissed for
economic or production reasons c an also, under certain conditions, apply for tax-
free vocational grants from the Training a nd Redundancy Fund. Furthermore, the
students c an be paid additional compensation for travel and a c c o m m o d a t i on
costs. However, social benefits related to adult training were cut and restricted in
1993.
Options for other labour market training improved in 1991, when a study leave
system with financial aid for adult training was established. Since the training
allowance for this optional training is considerably lower than the unemployment
benefit, this option has been used primarily by young people a nd those who are not
unemployed.
The role of active measures in terminating spells of unemployment has remained
fairly stable, hovering between 22% and 25% of total terminated spells, Due to
differences in employment prospects in the normal labour market and the priority
given to young and long-term unemployed people when targeting active measures,
the importance of active measures in terminating unemployment spells varies across
different groups of unemployed job-seekers (Table 15).
- 7 3-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 15. Termination of unemployment spells by reason, %, and bv group of unemployed
¡ob-seekers, 1995
Employed in the normal labour market
Employed through employment service
Employed on own account
Subsidised work
Labour market training
Outside the labour market
Other reason or unknown
Number of terminated employment spells
Long-term
unemployed
14
3
11
41
12
18
15
134,048
Youths
<25 years
39
6
33
21
6
20
13
239,342
Others
65
6
59
8
10
9
8
482,953
Source: Ministry of Labour, Employment Service Statistics.
The contents of subsidised job placements by employer sector a nd target group are
illustrated in Table 16. We see that the private sector a c c o u n t ed for about 24,000
subsidised jobs - 37% of the total. Yet three quarters of long-term unemployed
people had worked in the public sector, whereas young people a nd other groups
were over-represented In placements to the private sector. The type of measures in
private sector placements may be illustrated by a few more figures: normal w a ge
subsidy a c c o u n t ed for 50%, start-up grants for 15% a nd various on-the-job training
schemes for 25% of total subsidised jobs in the private sector in 1995,
Table 16: Number of people in subsidised work by employer sector and target group, annual
averages, 1995
Employer sector
Central Government
Share of:
youths
long-term unemployed
disabled
others
Local aovemment
Share of:
youths
long-term unemployed
disabled
others
Private sector (enterprises & households)
Share of:
youths
long-term unemployed
disabled
others
Number of
people
As % of total
placements within
target group
12100
6%
72%
6%
16%
27350
21%
65%
3%
11%
23950
29%
38%
2%
31%
6%
25%
38%
15%
42%
50%
38%
26%
52%
25%
24%
59%
Source: Ministry of Labour, Työllisyyskertomus 1995 (Employment Report 1995)
-74-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4.3 Implementation of active labour market policy measures by public employment
offices
The successful implementation of active labour market policy measures requires
a d e q u a te staff resources in the public employment offices. Most active labour
market policy (ALMP) spending passes directly through the public employment
service (PES) in the form of payments to training providers or employment subsidies
paid to private or public sector employers. The public employment services also
Include placement, vocational guidance a nd information services. To qualify for
unemployment benefits, unemployed people have to register at a public
employment office. Since most unemployed people are claiming benefits, their rate
of registration with the PES Is very high. However, more than a quarter of all
jobseekers are employed, perhaps because many notified vacancies are filled by
closed methods and people have to register in order to hear of them.
The 1987 Employment Act introduced a requirement on employers to notify
vacancies to the PES. The obligation which applies to all vacancies for which outside
labour is sought remained in place despite the abolition of the PES monopoly on
placements in 1994. However, the legislation is only partially respected because
there are no sanctions for non-compliance. Notifications of vacancies to the PES as
a proportion of new hirlngs in the economy was estimated by OECD (1995) to be
about 30% in 1994. Comparing the pension register data on the number of new
employment contracts with the PES register d a ta suggests, however, that the actual
share might be somewhat lower. Such a low share needs to be seen in the light of
evidence that only roughly half of all vacancies are publicly announced, the rest
being filled by Informal methods.
The work load at local offices has increased greatly, while staff resources have
t e n d ed to fall, reaching a low in 1994. Table 17 provides some indicators on the
performance of the PES since the late 1980s. The annual number of clients in the
employment service has doubled in recent years. In order to serve larger numbers of
clients, the organisation and procedures of the PES have been revised by increasing
the opportunities for self- and group-services. In 1995, there were about 8,000 groups
in action In local employment offices, involving about 90,000 clients (an average of
just over 10 people per self-help group). The procedures for filling temporary jobs
have been increasingly separated from those for arranging placements Into ordinary
jobs. Since 1996, hiring of temporary work started in some public employment offices,
75-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Toble 17: Work-load and staff resources at the public employment service offices 1990-1995
Activities during the year
Job-seekers
- unemployed
Job vacancies
Monthly averages
Job-seekers
- unemployed
Job vacancies
Staff resources
Labour districts
Local PES offices
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
528800
318700
340900
719400
464900
196900
907300
646800
127800
1028600
768800
114200
1047000
819400
153800
1015000
805000
167000
236100
105400
26900
365100
213200
13400
538600
363100
7100
680400
480200
5900
721000
494200
7400
694000
466000
8400
396
2520
405
2489
402
2408
375
2269
346
2203
334
2346
Source: Ministry of Labour (1996c)
Due to changes in the composition of clients - both jobseekers and employers - there
are increasing pressures for diversified, individually tailored and more labour-intensive
services. The public employment offices offer the employers, for a fee, special
recruitment, selection and staff development services alongside the free basic
services. Recent experiences from Sweden, for instance, suggest that the attainment
of sustainable results by means of active labour market policy measures depends
crucially on whether the measure is a well-motivated part of a concrete and
individual upgrading plan. Any kind of measure can be wasted if it is not
incorporated in such a development plan based on a common agreement
between the individual and the employment officer.
The adoption of an operational method which yields good results makes heavy
demands on the PES offices; it requires an extensive input of time and professional
skills in order for personnel to draft suitable plans. From this point of view, it could be
asked whether the current balance between budgets reserved for human resources
and those for measures is appropriate or whether an increase in staff resources
would produce a considerable improvement in the effectiveness of the measures.
76-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4.4 Description of existing active measures
4.4.1 Employment subsidy for employers
The aim of this scheme is to provide temporary job opportunities for unemployed
people to Improve their employabillty by upgrading skills and maintaining
involvement in the labour market. Wage subsidies can be granted for employers
and enterprises both in the public and private sector. For work in central
government, the subsidy covers all wage costs, while in municipalities and in the
private sector a partial wage subsidy is paid, The exact amount of subsidy varies
from person to person, and is between FIM 2,500 and 4,500 per month. The subsidy is
granted for a fixed period of up to 10 months.
The employment subsidy system was renewed in April 1995 and the conditions for
granting subsidies to companies were changed. Companies are now required to
sign a permanent contract of employment or to provide apprenticeship training (or
other forms of training for special groups with poor employment prospects). The
intention is that the subsidy should be used increasingly as part of a package of
services - including training and rehabilitation - tailored to job-seekers' needs. The
maximum duration of the whole package is 18 months.
The private employer's subsidy can also be granted to associations, foundations or
households, as well as to companies. If the subsidy is paid to private households for
employing an unemployed person, It is exempt from income tax.
Figure 1 : Key features of the employment subsidy scheme
Date of introduction
In the present form, the legal basis is provided by an
Employment Decree Amendment 1995
Cost
FIM 2,468 million in 1995
Method of financing
Central Government budget
Administration
Target group
Number of beneficiaries
Labour Administration
Special emphasis is given to long-term unemployed
people, young people and disabled people
A total of 150,400 people in 1995, 108,700 of them
placed during the year; a monthly average of 51,500
people
Length of the programme
22 weeks, on average, in 1995
■77-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4.4.2 Labour market training
Labour market training (LMT) is basically further vocational training and
supplementary training. Traditionally, basic vocational education has been a small
proportion of training overall. In recent years, training aimed at entrepreneurship
and self-employment has increased. Moreover, to complement the advisory work of
employment offices, instruction guidance for work and training as well as guidance
to foreigners are also arranged as LMT.
The 'KEKO' project is a further example of the LMT initiative. KEKO has been piloting
development training in small and medium-sized enterprises for professionally
educated unemployed people (such as engineers and business graduates). The aim
is to improve and utilise professional competence by combining the supplementary
training with the company-related development ventures. Beside the normal training
allowance, the participants receive a minor compensation paid by the company -
in general, amounting to FIM 750 per month.
The Labour Administration purchases LMT from various organisers through a
tendering procedure. The administration can procure training in co-operation with
employers, who then contribute to the funding.
During training, students are paid a subsidy equivalent to unemployment benefit. In
addition, a maintenance allowance is paid to cover meal expenses and a refund of
accommodation costs can also be granted.
Figure 2: Key features of labour market training schemes
Date of introduction
The legal basis is provided by the Labour Market
Training Act 1990
Cost
2,369 FIM million in 1995, excluding administrative
expenses (this includes the procurement of training as
well as social benefits paid to the participants)
Method of financing
The Ministry of Labour (and ESF in respect of projects
implemented under ESF programmes)
Administration
Labour administration, education authorities as well as
the Ministry of Trade and Industry. Education authorities
are responsible for planning the content of the training,
and in the KEKO-project for example, the Ministry of
Trade and Industry selects the enterprises for
development projects.
Target group
Unemployed people (over 20 years of age) and those
at risk of unemployment
Number of beneficiaries
90,000 people in 1995; a monthly average of 34,000
Length of the programme
Four months, on average, in 1995
- 7 8-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4.4.3 Apprenticeship training
The aim of apprenticeship training is to develop vocational skills as well as to provide
basic vocational training.
In 1995, apprenticeship training was linked more closely to youth education by giving
students access to qualifying examinations, In ESF activities, the apprenticeship
system was linked with innovative youth workshops leading to vocational
qualifications for practically oriented young people, In addition to basic vocational
training, further training or retraining is provided as part of apprenticeship training.
The labour administration supports apprenticeship training by paying employment
subsidies to employers, In addition to normal government compensation for the costs
incurred.
Figure 3: Key features of apprenticeship training
Date of introduction
The legal basis is provided by the Apprenticeship Training
Act 1992
Cost
The public cost is 390 FIM million in 1995
Method of financing
State budget funds channelled through the Ministry of
Labour and additional employment subsidies paid to
employers by the Labour Administration. In the case of
ESF-projects, there is partial finance through EU funds.
Administration
Educational and labour administration
Target group
People in need of enhancement of vocational skills and.
increasingly, young people without any vocational
training
Number of beneficiaries
A monthly average of about 12,000 people in 1995
79-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4.4.4 Start-up grants
A registered unemployed job-seeker who has a feasible business idea can receive
counselling and financial assistance when setting up a new business. A taxable start
up allowance amounting to between FIM 2,500 and FIM 4,500 can be granted for a
maximum of 10 months. The allowance Is not intended to provide capital for the
new enterprise, but to cover living expenses during the initial phase.
In some ESF-projects (pathways to entrepreneurship), efforts are being made to
facilitate entrepreneurship by combining entrepreneurship training and financial
start-up grants into packages including individually tailored consultation, as well as
evaluation and elaboration of the business idea (Ministry of Labour, 1996d). Efforts
have also been made to facilitate the co-operation and integration of the various
organisations which support entrepreneurship and provide consultative services for
enterprises. Special associations - centres for newly established business enterprises -
have also been created to provide free counselling. These are being financed jointly
by business firms, labour administration and municipalities. In April 1996, there were
27 such centres, with 54 branch offices. A new centre is planned, to serve women in
particular.
Figure 4: Key features of start-up grants
Date of introduction
Available since 1984, the legal basis is provided by an
Employment Decree 1993
Cost
189 FIM million in 1995
Method of financing
State budget appropriation
Administration
Target group
Labour administration in co-operation with the Industrial
administration
Unemployed people with previous business experience
and/or training. Training can also be provided during
the payment of the start-up grant.
Number of beneficiaries
7,800 during 1995; a monthly average of 3,500 people
Length of the programme
21 weeks, on average, in 1995
•80-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4.4.5 Part-time pay supplement
To encourage job sharing, a part-time pay supplement can be paid (as
compensation for loss of earnings) to a person who voluntarily changes from full-time
to part-time working. The replacement rate Is 50%, with a ceiling defined for the pay
supplement.
The arrangement is based on a voluntary agreement between the employee and
the employer. The maximum duration of the pay supplement Is twelve months and
the employee is entitled to return to full-time work after this period. The employer has
to recruit for the job an unemployed person for the same period, so that about half
of the reduction in working time is assigned to the unemployed job-seeker.
Figure 5: Kev features of the part-time pav supplement scheme
Date of introduction
Experiment valid from March 1994 to end December
1996
Cost
59 FIM million in 1995
Method of financing
State budget appropriation
Administration
Labour Administration
Target group
Not specified
Number of beneficiaries
4,500 new beneficiaries in 1995; a monthly average of
2,000 people
Length of the programme
29 weeks, on average, in 1995
31 -
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4.4.6 Job rotation scheme
This scheme is intended to encourage work sharing and broaden the scope for
individual career breaks. It is based on a voluntary agreement between a full-time
employee and his or her employer for the employee to take unpaid leave (i.e. not
paid by the employer) for studies, training or personal reasons for a fixed period
between three months and a year, The employee is entitled to return to the same
job, and the employer is obliged to recruit an unemployed job-seeker for the same
period, but not necessarily in the same job.
The person on job rotation leave receives 60% of the unemployment benefit
allowance he or she would be entitled to, up to a ceiling of FIM 4,500 per month. In
the case of full-time vocational training, a training supplement of FIM 1,000 per
month can also be granted.
Figure 6: Kev feotures of the job rotation scheme
Date of introduction
Temporary experiment started in January 1996
Cost
Method of financing
State expenditure is estimated to be between FIM 100-
150 million annually, while the annual savings in state
unemployment expenditure would amount to some FIM
130 million
Unemployment funds and the Social Security Institution
cover the allowances paid to those on job rotation
leave. Impact on state budget is negligible.
Administration
Labour Administration
Target group
Not specified
Number of beneficiaries
About 5,000 people a year are expected to make use
of the option
Length of the programme
From three to twelve months
■82-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
4.5 Evaluation of good practice in active measures
Finnish evaluation studies have mostly dealt with the two measures - employment
subsidies and labour market training - that make up the great majority of all active
labour market policy measures. In general, the findings of the researchers have been
more favourable than have general opinions of the measures.
Recent econometric studies by Eriksson (1993) and Pehkonen (1994) found
favourable impacts of targeted employment subsidies in curbing long-term
unemployment. Rantala (1995) found that labour market training provided the best
results for long-term unemployed, while for young adults a g ed 20-24 years the
employment subsidies were effective in increasing the probability of gainful
employment. On the other hand, there Is some evidence that the displacement
effects may be quite substantial in the youth labour market (Eriksson a nd Pehkonen,
1995; Pehkonen, 1996); job-creation schemes targeted at young people under 20
displace those a g ed 20-24 in regular employment.
The evaluation of labour market training has also produced mainly positive
outcomes (Juuti et al, 1995). Individual assessments of the participants have been
particularly favourable, although short-term outcomes in terms of gainful
employment following the training have clearly deteriorated. As to the experiences
of companies, managers and corporate executives expressed favourable attitudes
towards labour market training, although three quarters of the respondents felt that
there was room for further improvement in terms of efficiency. The need for closer
co-operation between companies and the labour administration was emphasised
by the managers, as well as the need to use labour market training for in-company
training purposes.
Even though there are many follow-up studies on ALMP measures, few of them have
m a de use of econometric methods to control for the effects of individual
characteristics and to disentangle the specific effects of the policy measures.
Moreover, many of the existing measures are quite new so that little evidence Is
available on their performance. The following conclusions are, therefore, necessarily
based partly on subjective assessments.
Employment subsidies paid to private and public employers are an established
measure containing few innovatory elements. However, within a slack labour
market, participation In subsidised job schemes has contributed to firmer
involvement In the labour market for long-term unemployed people. The most
striking finding concerns the crucial role of the employer sector in subsidised work.
The position of those placed Into the private sector has been more favourable in
many respects (Santamäki-Vuori, 1996b). The subsidy period has resulted In gainful
employment more often In the private sector. Moreover, in the private sector, job
opportunities c an be provided for people with a broader spectrum of vocational
qualifications, compared to servicejobs in the public sector.
There have been problems, however, in designing schemes to encourage private
companies to provide subsidised job opportunities, while avoiding dead-weight
effects as well as distortionary effects on competition between companies. The
83-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
heavy concentration of subsidised jobs in the public sector, where the possibilities to
continue in employment after the subsidy period are negligible and where the
number of permanent staff is being cut, tends to result in many disadvantageous
effects. The critical issue, therefore, is how to encourage even private companies to
participate in these schemes.
In respect of the youth labour market, an additional viewpoint is arising from the
expansion of practical training alongside labour market support. Employment
subsidies and compensation for apprenticeship training are less attractive
alternatives for companies, compared with the increasingly popular option of
employing young unemployed people without pay.
Efforts have also been made to provide unemployed people with individually
tailored packages of service, with subsidised employment making up a vital part of
the overall package. This objective was emphasised in the renewal of the
employment subsidy system, when more discretion was given to local authorities in
the implementation of active labour market programmes. It Is acknowledged that
any success of active measures may be critically dependent on their presenting
reasonable prospects for beneficiaries in the future. Schemes that acquire a
reputation for disguising unemployment for creating new forms of cheap labour
and for failing to provide adequate training will merely lead to a deterioration in the
labour market position of beneficiaries. The better the measures are tailored to meet
individual needs, the lower the risk of disappointment among participants and the
smaller the reduction in cost effectiveness. Staff resources at local employment
offices have been scarce, however, thereby restricting the wholesale
implementation of individually tailored services.
The vital role of private employers is also obvious in job rotation schemes and part-
time pay supplement schemes, which tend to encourage work sharing through
voluntary and transitory shifts to leave or part-time work. Given the large number of
people who would prefer shorter working time, the strains experienced by many
employees during recent years and the increasing need for life-long learning, one
would expect such schemes to be popular. However, the take-up of the schemes
has so far been very low. This may be due partly to the existence of alternative
schemes designed, for instance, to take care of employee's children (home-care
allowance combined with child-care leave). Furthermore, employees may consider
it too risky to leave their job, in particular if their employers are not keen on these
schemes. There seems, therefore, to be a need for some incentives for employers to
implement such schemes and to handle the extra burden of hiring and inducting
replacement unemployed people,
In the KEKO-project (cf. 4.4.2), there is close co-operation with small and
medium-sized enterprises by combining on-the-job training with company-based
development ventures under an expert's supervision and guidance. These
innovatory elements have been regarded as successful. In some regions, efforts to
foster closer co-operation between companies and labour administration in
identifying and anticipating vocational needs have also been seen as a very useful
tool for planning labour market training by both partners. So far the feedback from
■84-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
both individual participants, tutors and companies has been positive (Ministry of
Labour, 1996e). Due to the difficulties of finding suitable development ventures, the
volume of these kinds of schemes has been quite limited. However, for some
professionally educated unemployed people with previous work experience, the
motivation to work as an unpaid expert in the KEKO-project has been low. The
motivation of newly graduated people seeking work experience has clearly been
much higher.
•85-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
5 OTHER POLICIES HAVING AN IMPACT ON THE LABOUR MARKET
5.1 Macro-economic policies
The Government, appointed in April 1995, set itself the objective of halving
unemployment and turning central government indebtedness (the ratio of gross
debt to total output) into decline by the end of its four-year election period, Strong
competitiveness and lower real interest rates were considered to be essential
preconditions for sustained economic growth a nd a permanent reduction in
unemployment. The austerity measures which had been implemented by the
previous government were maintained and new expenditure cuts totalling FIM 20
billion, or 3.5% of GDP, were agreed by the new government.
The consolidation of public finances eliminated the pressure on interest rates caused
by growth in public debt. The easing of monetary policy and lowering of interest
rates were further supported by moderate w a ge settlements In October 1995
(covering a period of more than two years up to February 1998). Long-term interest
rates (yields of taxable 5-year Finnish government bonds) fell from 9.3% in the first
quarter of 1995, to 6.5% at the year-end. Consequently, marked improvements in
fundamental macro-economic conditions were attained, with attention turned
thereafter to structural reforms to improve the functioning of the labour market and
to encourage working and entrepreneurship.
In September 1995, the Council of State a d o p t ed the Finnish convergence
programme outlining Finland's potential to fulfil the convergence criteria a nd
describing the measures aimed at satisfying the criteria. The convergence
programme was based on the government's political programme which, in some
respects - e.g. concerning public finances a nd the halving of unemployment - is
more demanding than the criteria of the convergence programme.
According to the basic scenario of the convergence programme, economic growth
was expected to average 3.5% over the five-year period, the growth rate
decelerating smoothly from 4.5% in 1996, to 2.5% in 1999. The projection assumes:
• satisfactory international developments;
•
real GDP in the OECD countries growing at an annual rate of 2.5% and inflation
constant at 2.5%;
• domestic fiscal policy in line with the government's programme; and
• moderate price and cost behaviour.
Finland was projected to have g o od prospects of satisfying all the convergence
criteria within the next few years. Public finances (general government net lending)
was expected to be balanced and indebtedness to stabilise as soon as 1996. As to
labour market performance, the unemployment rate was expected to be down to
12.5% in 1999. The government's objective of halving unemployment would require a
fall of 100,000 in the number of unemployed people.
In autumn 1995, a working group drew up a multi-annual employment programme
in line with the recommendations of the European Council meeting in Essen,
- 8 6-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
outlining the measures to be taken to meet this challenge. On 19 October, the
Council of State based Its decisionsinprinciple on the proposals of this working
group. The main measures included the following elements:
• Reductions in the tax wedge by lowering income taxation, especially In respect of
low and medium income groups, and cutting employers' social security
contributions.
• A relaxation of labour regulation related, for example, to job security and fixed
term employment contracts and diversification of working hours.
• An increase in vocational training.
• Promotion of entrepreneurship.
• Encouragement of building, launching suburban renovation programmes and
environmental protection schemes.
• A shift in the main focus of labour market policy from passive measures (granting
unemployment benefits) to active measures.
A large number of the measures were estimated to require no additional funds from
the State budget, as they would be carried out by reallocating existing
appropriations. Since economic growth was also expected to be faster than that
specified by the convergence programme criteria, It was expected that slight
Increases in public expenditure would not jeopardise the attainment of the
convergence criteria concerning general government debt.
Since January 1996, economic policy d e b a te has Taken place In the context of less
favourable economic developments. Weaker economic growth will lead to a
greater budget deficit, jeopardising the aim of reducing central government
indebtedness during the fouryear period. Therefore, in February 1996, the
government established new measures for stabilising Indebtedness In order to offset
the impact of a greater budget deficit. Lower ceilings for central government
expenditure In 19971999 were agreed and new measures to increase tax income
were a d o p t ed by abandoning, for instance, the previous plan of reducing value
a d d ed tax on food from 1998 onwards.
Unlike previous decisions on the consolidation of public finances, the new ones were
received with more disquiet. The advisability of the expenditure ceilings was
questioned, in particular given that economic developments could be weaker than
expected. In any event, the scope for action on fiscal policy is extremely limited over
the next few years; In the short term, monetary policy constitutes the main tool of
macroeconomic policy.
As to policy coordination, some criticism has been directed at the Bank of Finland
due to the delayed and excessively cautious measure of cutting shortterm interest
rates in Ì995. The Bank of Finland raised its tender rate, as late as June 1995, to
d a m p en inflationary expectations. The fear seemed to be misplaced, however. The
latest figures March 1996 show that Inflation in Finland, at 0.6% over 12 months.
■87
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
remained the lowest in the EU. Projections suggest that inflation will remain low
throughout 1996 and into 1997.
The monetary authorities are now confident that the official target of 2% underlying
inflation (measured by the consumer price index less indirect taxes, subsidies and
mortgage interest rates) will be attained, although temporary dampening factors,
such as the fall in food prices, are unlikely to exert any influence in the future.
Towards the end of 1995, the easing of monetary policy did not generate problems
in the market. The Bank of Finland's tender rate was decreased from 6% in
September 1995 to 3.75% at the beginning of May 1996. It is generally considered
that monetary policy can - and should - be eased still further,
Economic recovery in Finland began at the end of 1993, as nearly two years of
strong economic growth in exports were finally reflected elsewhere in the economy.
The economic recovery gained momentum in 1994 as domestic demand grew
substantially. Aggregate output grew some 4.4% on average, in both 1994 and 1995.
A substantial deceleration in economic growth took place In the latter half of 1995,
mainly as an effect of the unexpected halt in economic growth in the EU. Its
restrictive impact was immediately visible In export industry. The general decline in
prospects in Europe also increased uncertainty among households and companies,
and thus had a direct impact on domestic consumption and investment demand.
There has recently been a general tendency to produce less favourable short-term
economic projections for 1996 and 1997. However, the preconditions for faster
growth in years to come do exist; real interest rates have fallen, prices are
competitive and household indebtedness has decreased, allowing a revival in the
housing market, for instance. Economic growth is generally expected to rebound In
the latter half of 1996. This is based largely on a similar scenario of the gradual
speeding-up of economic growth in the EU. Despite slower growth, the current
account will be in surplus In Finland, the general government deficit is decreasing,
inflation is extremely low, the long-term Incomes agreement should keep prices
down for the next few years and the floating of the markka has not prompted any
major turbulence In interest rates. The fact that economic development has been
less robust than expected means, however, that the public budget deficit will not be
reduced as fast as originally planned. Even so, the government economy will go on
improving, and in 1997 the general government financial deficit will probably be one
of the lowest in the EU.
It is clear that the poorer economic outlook will result in few positive labour market
developments. In particular, unemployment is likely to fall more slowly than
expected, Medium-term projections serve to illustrate plausible labour market
developments, but they also serve as a guideline in assessing the need for any
further measures necessary to attain the target of a halving of unemployment.
- 8 8-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 18: Medium-term projections on labour market developments
MEDIUM-TERM PROJECTIONS:
Convergence programme (Sept 95);
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
GDP growth
Unemployment
5.0
16.7
4.5
14.5
4.0
13.5
3.0
13.0
2.5
12.5
Ministry of Labour (Jan 96):
GDP growth
Unemployment
5.0
17.2
4.5
15.0
3,5
14.1
3.0
13.1
3.0
13.0
Ministry of Finance (Feb 96):
GDP growth
Unemployment
4.4
17.2
3.8
16.0
4.0
14.5
3.5
12.5
3.5
11.0
Ministry of Finance (June 96):
GDP growth
Unemployment
4.2
17.2
3.0
16.3
3.8
15.4
4.0
14.0
3.5
12.0
SHORT-TERM PROJECTIONS:
Res Inst of the Finnish Economy (Mar 96):
GDP growth
Unemployment
3.0
16.5
2.5
16.0
Pellervo Economic Res Inst (May 96):
GDP growth
Unemployment
2.0
17.0
2.5
16.5
Lab Inst for Economic Res (May 96):
GDP growth
Unemployment
2.0
16.3
2.5
15.9
European Commission, DG II (May 96):
GDP growth
Unemployment
3.0
16.3
3.6
15.0
Ministry of Finance (May 96):
GDP growth
Unemployment
3.0
16.3
3.8
15.4
Source for medium-term projections: Ministry of Labour (1996) Labour force
2010, Labour study 130, Ministry of Finance (Feb 1996) Prospects of the Central
Government Finance in 1996-1999 and Ministry of Finance (June 1996)
Talouspolitiikan linja, Kansantalouden kehitys ja talouspolitiikka vuosina 1996-
2000 (Outline of the economic policy. Economic developments and
economic policy in 1996-2000).
None of the projections suggest a halving of unemployment by spring 1999.
Economic growth in 1995, as well as the most recent forecasts on economic
performance in 1996, are clearly worse than In any of the basic scenarios. The most
favourable short-term forecasts are those by the European Commission (Directorate-
General, II) a nd by the Ministry of Finance. Total output is expected to grow 3.0%
and 3.6%-3.8% in 1996 and 1997, respectively, while the corresponding figures for the
unemployment rate are 16.3% a nd 15.0%-15.4%.
■89-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Given these unsatisfactory scenarios, further measures to boost economic growth
are sought. There have not been any substantial changes in the employment effects
of output growth. The main reason for the diminished employment effect of growth
at the macro level is the structural change in the composition of output at the early
stages of economic upswing. In the near future, growth In service production and
some revival in the construction industry should promote employment despite the
distinct slow-down in industrial output. Therefore, the employment effects of output
growth, along with the more balanced production structure, are expected to
improve in the latter half of the 1990s.
The slow fall in unemployment means that the problem of long-term unemployment
has become more serious. Some 10% of the labour force can now be counted as
long-term unemployed, if the figures include recurrent unemployment interrupted by
short-term periods of work or traineeship. The emphasis on cutting long-term
unemployment becomes more of a priority in all structural policies designed to
promote job creation.
5.2 Education and vocational training
Safeguarding equal opportunities for education and training has been a primary
goal of education policy since the late 1960s. Two major reforms were implemented
in the 1970s. Firstly, compulsory education for 7-16 year olds was remodelled on a
nine-year comprehensive school. The tenth class in the comprehensive school gives
pupils the opportunity to stay in education for a further year. Secondly, upper
secondary education was renewed with the aim of providing a student place for all
of the age group, either In senior secondary schools or in vocational and
professional institutes.
In Finland, responsibility for education rests mainly with the public sector. There are
relatively few private educational institutes, and even they receive state support.
Spending on public education accounted for 14% of all public expenditure In 1993;
this figure Is among the highest in the OECD. The Finnish educational system Is also
characterised by the fact that education and training are mainly provided in
educational institutes. In vocational training, both theoretical and practical
instruction are usually arranged in training institutes even though compulsory on-the-
job training is also offered,
The number of students in regular education has increased sharply. In the early
1990s, enrolment rates were three or four times as high as in I960, both in senior
secondary schools, vocational and professional educational institutes and in
universities (Table 19). At present, immediately after comprehensive school, over 90%
of young people continue in upper secondary education - more than half of them
In general education. Nearly 60% of the age group qualify for a place in university.
However, competition for student places Is tough and only about one third of the
applicants are admitted.
•90-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table 19: Enrolment rates in upper secondary and tertian/ education
Year
1960
1970
1980
1991
Senior secondary
school students as % of
those aged 15-19
Vocational Institute
students as % of those
University students as
% of those aged 20-24
aged 15-24
8
12
18
28
8
13
22
34
10
20
30
37
NB: Because of the age groups used, the figures indicate better the change over
time than the level of enrolment. In respect of the threeyear senior secondary
school, for instance, the relevant age group is narrower being mostly those aged
1618.
Source: Vartia and YldAnttila (1992), p. 193.
As discussed earlier in Section 1.2.1, the substantial increase in participation in
education a c t ed as a buffer against the impact of the deterioration of the labour
market position of young people. Recent findings suggest that the benefits of
education are clear, even for new labour market entrants. Along with the economic
recovery, disparities in unemployment rates by educational level appear to be
widening. Moreover, although unemployment rates are much higher a m o ng newly
qualified people than a m o ng those with more work experience, the decline in
unemployment Is more pronounced among newcomers. Table 20 displays the
unemployment rates in 1995 for people newly qualified during the preceding five
years. The range of variation is from more than 60% for those with a basic education
(admittedly a small group), to about 2% for those with a postgraduate education. In
1990, the corresponding range of variation was narrower, from about 17% to less
than one per cent.
Table 20: Unemployment rates of people certified during the preceding five years, 1995, for
the 20 to 64 aae group
Level of education
Unemployment rate
Basic education
Lower level of upper secondary
Upper level of upper secondary
Lowest level of higher education
Undergraduate level of higher education
Graduate level of higher education
Postgraduate education
Source: Haven (1996)
1995
1990
62.7%
32.5%
26.2%
15,9%
10.2%
6.7%
2.2%
17.4%
7.2%
5.4%
1.8%
1.7%
1.4%
0.6%
In recent years, the importance of vocational training has been further emphasised.
Since Ì99Ì, a system of polytechnics, still at the experimental stage, has been
developed In tertiary education. The polytechnics offer theoretical learning, but are
also geared to practice learning and to advances in apprenticeship training. The
■91
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
popularity of this form of training has clearly increased, admittedly from a low
starting base. The apprenticeship system was traditionally used on a small scale in
adult education. Efforts have been made to draw up apprenticeship contracts in
new fields and to widen the system into youth education, At the moment, basic
education for students under 20 years of age and further training for students under
25 years of age is developed under ESF. The apprenticeship system was modified in
1995 to lead to a final examination and, if approved, to a qualification.
A significant increase has also taken place In adult education. In open universities,
adults can attend basic university education irrespective of their educational
background. The credits are similar, and can be accepted as credits towards a
university degree. The open university enjoys growing popularity: some 3% of the
adult population attend open university every year. Moreover, a network of liberal
education institutes covers the whole country, and about 25% of the adult
population attends their courses, In addition to general courses, these institutes can
now also provide basic and supplementary vocational training.
Vocational adult education consists of staff training, self-motivated training and
labour market training. Staff training is arranged and financed by employers for their
employees. It is primarily short-term supplementary training, with an average of six
training days per annum, per participant. Although, the provision of staff training
decreased during the recession, some 40% of employees continue to take this type
of training every year.
Self-motivated training is largely further vocational training, where the government
and the student share the costs. The opportunities for adults to take such training has
been improved by developing the study leave system. To maintain income during
education, students can receive an adult study grant, housing supplement and
state guarantee for a study loan. New starts in long-term self-motivated vocational
training tripled between 1989 and 1993. Participation by adults in these courses
increased similarly, amounting to a total of 59,000 participants In 1993, including six-
month follow-up courses. However, recent cuts in adult study grants resulted in lower
participation in adult training in 1995, In addition to long-term training, nearly 200,000
adults have taken short periods of self-motivated training at vocational institutes.
In vocational adult education, the learning process has until now been structured
through a national curriculum, However, a shift is being made towards competence-
based examinations. In the spring of 1994, an Act on Vocational Examinations came
into force, enabling a person to demonstrate his or her competence irrespective of
the way in which It was acquired. Any working experience, as well as training, can
be counted as a whole or partial qualification toward a diploma.
Co-operation between educational institutions and Industries has increased.
Vocational curricula and competence-based qualifications are being prepared in
close co-operation with educational committees within each branch. The
committees include social partners, teachers' representatives and administrators. In
universities, co-operation is organised through project participation.
- 9 2-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
The volume of adult training, overall, has been regarded as inadequate in relation to
ever increasing needs. Moreover, there is a tendency for training to accumulate
among those with the best qualifications. This group of people also has the highest
expressed need for additional training. The mismatch between expressed need and
actual participation in training is greatest among those with lower educational
qualifications. This may be taken as an indication of hidden willingness to undertake
further education, in particular among the least educated people (Table 21). To
provide equal opportunities for adequate adult training, a discussion about regular
training under a study insurance scheme has recently been raised.
Table 21 : Participation in vocational adult education and expressed need for further
education, as percentage of total employees in 1990
GROUP
Females
Males
18-24 years
25-29 years
30-34 years
35-44 years
45-54 years
55 +
Blue collar workers
White collar employees:
- lower level
- upper level
Central government
Local government
Private sector
Education level:
Basic level
Upper secondary
- lower level
- upper level
Higher level
PARTICIPATION DURING THE
PRECEDING 12 MONTHS
48
41
EXPRESSED NEED FOR
FURTHER EDUCATION
57
50
36
50
49
48
44
28
27
59
73
65
56
39
28
40
57
75
51
59
64
58
49
26
37
63
72
65
61
50
40
52
66
72
Source: Simpanen and Blomgvist (1993) and Simpanen (1993)
In 1989-1994, the number of full-time students increased by 74,000, or by about 30%.
Most of the increase occurred in youth education, and to tackle youth
unemployment, efforts have been made to improve further the labour market
competencies of young people. The government has recognised that the transition
from training to working life can be difficult for many young people. A working group
consisting of secretary generals of three Ministries was established to facilitate the
transition by dissolving the boundary between work and training, through an
-93-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
increase in apprenticeship training. The group also Intended to make it easier for
newly graduated people to acquire work experience and to facilitate their
integration into working life through an increase in employment subsidies for newly
qualified people.
In March 1994, the working group proposed that starter places in basic and further
training (including apprenticeship training) would be increased by 33,000 in 1994
and that the number of starter places would exceed the initial level by 34,000 in 1995
(Prime Minister's Office, 1994). The implementation of the proposals was delayed and
the targets have not been attained. However, the aim to increase the number of
training places has not been abandoned; on the contrary, It forms a vital part of the
multi-annual employment programme, which was prepared for the meeting of the
European Council in December 1995.
Higher education and research is regarded as a vital part of Finland's development
strategy. According to the long term objectives, universities and polytechnics will
cater for 60-65% of the age group. The policy concerns In education are expansion
of the scope of programmes, provision of multi-dlsclpllnary learning and wider
choice for individuals. The main aims in the near future are the flexibility of the
educational system as a whole, the development of evaluation systems and
widening the use of pathways. A system of lifelong learning is to be created, where
educational modules are approved as part of a qualification.
5.3 Tax and benefit
By European standards, the gross tax rate (total taxes per GDP) in Finland is not high,
particularly if one takes into account the fact that almost all income transfers are tax
liable, unlike other countries. The comparison between different time periods is
complicated by structural changes In taxation in the early 1990s, such as replacing
tax reductions based on the number of children with higher income transfers in the
form of child benefits. These changes did not affect the average net tax rate,
although Income taxation Is very high. It is one of the highest in the EU, comparable
to that in Denmark, Netherlands, Germany and Belgium (Lehtinen, 1996b). Due to
the sharp rise in unemployment expenditure In the early 1990s, Income taxation was
further tightened to avoid excessive deficits in public balances. Although capital
taxation has also been raised, the difference between the two is particularly large.
There is a uniform tax rate - 28% since 1996 (25% earlier) - for both capital income
and profits. Steps to alleviate the taxation of earned income started in 1996, and in
relation to the incomes policy settlement concluded in September 1995, the
government decided to continue to reduce income taxation in 1997.
To mitigate increases in non-wage costs, the employers' share of unemployment
insurance expenditure was decreased in 1993, from 47% to 32%. The corresponding
rise in the share funded by central government was financed by a special
earmarked unemployment tax. In addition to the contribution paid by the insured, a
general unemployment insurance contribution was introduced for all employees.
Since July 1993, the employers' contribution was graded so that a lower contribution
■94-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
was paid for the first million of the payroll (since 1995, for the first five million). As there
is no funding in the finance of unemployment insurance, the total payroll taxes paid
by employers, employees and Insured people increased greatly during the
depression - from a low of 0.67% In 1990, to 8.3% in 1994. This was a significant
contributory factor in the rise of the tax w e d ge at the time of soaring unemployment
In the early 1990s.
In spring 1996, the government decided on new cuts In unemployment insurance
benefits, from 1997 onwards. It was simultaneously agreed that the employers' share
of unemployment insurance expenditure would be gradually Increased, up to the
original level of 47%, by 1999. To mitigate the tendency for unemployment insurance
contributions - and hence the tax w e d ge - to exhibit a harmful counter-cyclical
variation, there has been some discussion on the advisability of shifting towards a
partially funded financing scheme for unemployment Insurance (Klander, 1996). To
eliminate most of the pressure for increases in employment pension contributions in
the future, substantial amendments to the accrual of employment pensions were
agreed in 1995.
Table 22: Unemployment insurance contributions fas percentage of pay") and the
unemployment rote
YEA*
EMPLOYER
INSURED
EMPLOYEE
TOTAL
'¿ .
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993*
1994*
1995*
1996*
0.80
0.95
1,30
1.20
0.85
0.60
1.40
3.70
5.70
5.40
4.50
3.00
0.09
0.11
0.15
0.14
0.10
0.07
0.16
0.43
0.70
1.03
1.03
1.03
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
0.20
1.87
1.87
1.50
0.89
1.06
1.45
1.34
0.95
0.67
1.56
4.13
6.60
8.30
7.40
5.53
UNEMPLOYMENT
RATE
5.0
5.4
5.1
4.5
3.5
3.4
7.6
13.1
17.9
18.4
17.2
'Since 1993, the employers' contribution has been an estimate of the average
contribution for a private employer.
In June 1994, there was a shift from turnover tax to value-added taxation. The
change extended the coverage of consumption tax to many personal services that
were previously exempt from taxation. The full tax rate of 22% applies also to
restaurants and staff canteens. Amid a prolonged depression in the domestic
market, the reform - or at least Its timing - was generally considered to be harmful.
For foodstuffs, the value-added tax rate is normally 12%, but a higher rate of 17% will
be applied temporarily in 1995-1997. Other indirect consumption taxes for
households - such as excise taxes or user charges for cars - have also been raised.
- 9 5-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
There has also been great concern about the problem of incentive traps. The
problem of very high effective tax rates among some particular groups of people -
like low-Income families with small children or unemployed people - may arise from
the combined effects of income taxation, means-tested income transfers and
graded fees for public services (like children's day-care). A working group charting
these problems made Its proposals on measures to abolish the most apparent
defects in April 1996. The measures included alleviation of the taxation of low
earnings, alleviation of means-testing in unemployment benefits with respect to
earned income, as well as changes In the schemes for support care for small
children. Efforts have also been made to identify any remaining inequalities in
entitlement to social security depending on the form of employment; In the existing
schemes, thresholds either on working hours or earnings may place atypical forms of
employment at a disadvantage in respect of annual or sick leave and employment
pension.
5.4 Industrial policies
According to the political programme for government policy in 1995-1999, the
government will promote competitiveness based on innovations, research and
development, skilled labour and high standards of environmental protection. The
creation of new jobs in SMEs and service enterprises is an important goal. The
government is also committed to promoting job-creation in recycling and other
areas of environmental protection. Self-employment will be supported by promoting
service co-operatives,
Active industrial policy also concerns state-owned companies, which will be partly
privatised. However, the state will retain its majority ownership in some companies -
like IVO, Kemijoki, Vapo and Neste - that are vital for the nation's energy supply. The
value of State property amounts to FIM 120 billion, of which FIM 50 billion is in equities.
Parliament has empowered the authorities to sell equities up to FIM 25 billion.
The multi-annual employment programme spelt out policies to enhance
entrepreneurship and encourage local initiatives. Several working groups have been
set up, under tight deadlines, to draft detailed proposals on new measures. The
national productivity programme, which was launched in 1993 to raise productivity
by developing the quality and flexibility of working life, will continue until spring 1999.
A similar programme was introduced in 1996, with a focus on the development of
skills and innovations based on local initiatives. The latter involves research-driven
development within enterprises in co-operation with universities and research
institutes. Its core features are the development of multi-skilled work and teamwork in
organisations capable of using networking methods. Finally, an action programme
for developing the Information society was initiated. Its aim is to provide all citizens
with the basic skills and technical opportunities to use the services of the information
society.
Finland has reached advanced levels of development, implementation and
diffusion of telecommunications systems and services. The percentage of employees
■96-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
using information technology at work rose from 17% in 1984, to 55% in 1993. The
proportion of INTERNET users among the population is the highest of all EU countries.
In 1994, 26% of Finnish households possessed a PC; Denmark Is the only EU state with
a higher figure.
As to intangible investments, the volume of Investments In research and
development (as a percentage of GDP) Is relatively high, Sweden and France are
the only EU countries with higher investment rates and, in Finland, efforts are being
m a de to Increase such investment further.
There have been ambitious efforts to Improve the economic performance of the
manufacturing sector, through the use of modern IT products and concepts. By
1994, there were 38 industrial robots for every 10,000 people employed In
manufacturing. This was the fourth highest figure in Europe. Flexible manufacturing
systems have been rapidly penetrating the engineering industry. Reflecting these
trends, the growth of manufacturing output is based heavily on the increase of total
factor productivity rather than Increases in labour or capital Inputs. The level of
labour productivity in manufacturing is now one of the highest by international
standards. This is due in part to the substantial growth in capital intensity over the last
few years, In other sectors, productivity performance is not as positive, The OECD has
argueä that less attention has been given, In Finland, to the service sector and how
it might benefit from greater use of information technology (OECD, 1992),
Service enterprises currently account for 70% of all SMEs. The significance of SMEs as
a group of employers is highlighted by the fact that about 800,000 people work in
enterprises of less than 500 employees. Furthermore, micro-businesses, employing less
than 10 people, provide work for 300,000 people. A new programme for SME policy
was launched in early 1996 by a working group commissioned by the Ministry of
Trade and Industry. The programme addressed the administrative procedures that
place a disproportionate burden on SMEs. Proposals for easing this burden included
elimination of various permit procedures, increases in joint use of public data files
and simplification of the procedures for levying employers' social insurance
contributions. An information c a m p a i gn targeted at SMEs, to publicise the substance
of labour legislation and collective agreements, will also be carried out in
collaboration with labour market organisations.
There is comprehensive reform of the Hours of Work Act, intended to improve
operating conditions for SMEs. Specific aims include the extension of flexible working
time arrangements (as outlined in collective agreements), to enterprises that are not
obliged to observe the collective agreement In their own field.
Ways of reinforcing the capital structure and alleviating the problem of insufficient
securities for loans will also be investigated. The Finnish Guarantee Board participates
in risk-sharing by granting guarantees. The guarantees used to be restricted to
industrial enterprises, but were recently extended to intangible Investments by
service companies. However, the direct public funding of SMEs is mainly targeted
only at industrial enterprises. This emphasis was reinforced in the new programme for
SME policy. The volume of direct state aid to enterprises - consisting of tax
-97-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
concessions and transfer payments - has traditionally been high in Finland, with a
strong emphasis on regional aspects in the allocation of the funds (one third of total
aid). The structure of the business subsidy system is also of concern, with too much
aid directed to support normal business activities at the expense of supporting
research and development and training (Raatikainen, 1993).
There has been a rapid growth of internationalisation during the past 10-15 years,
dominated by the largest manufacturing firms. The 30 largest Finnish firms had 40% of
their employment abroad In 1993, compared to 15% in 1985. Moreover, knowledge
Intensive firms have been increasing their foreign production faster than basic
industry firms (Braunerhjelm et al, 1996). The favourable home country effects of
outward foreign direct investment (FDI) seem to have diminished greatly, however.
The rapid increase in FDI in nearby former socialist economies has contributed to the
growth of Internationalisation. Despite these developments, policy thinking continues
to emphasise the favourable dynamic effects of integration on economic growth.
Industrial policy has, therefore, been aimed at promoting the strength and
competitiveness of Finland's technical and social infrastructure, in order to attract
Investment by both domestic and foreign firms. This implies that the policy emphasis is
moving more and more from product markets to factor markets.
■98-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
6 THE NATIONAL DEBATE: POLICY PERSPECTIVES
6.1 Macro-economic conditions
In recent years, the fundamental macro-economic conditions in Finland have
improved markedly. Slower than expected economic growth c an be attributed to
the unexpected halt In economic growth in Europe a nd may also be seen as a
persistent after-effect of a profound macro-economic disturbance. It has b e c o me a
commonplace, however, to interpret the problems In the economy as a structural
crisis, Moderate pay developments, fiscal consolidation, low inflation, exchange rate
stability and the resultant lower level of Interest rates are then taken as necessary but
not sufficient conditions for a significant reduction in unemployment. Subsequently,
In line with this view, considerable easing in Income taxation and further
deregulation in the labour market are called for. Scope of tax policy measures and
reforms in the labour market make up the two major Issues characterising the policy
d e b a te in Finland. Work-sharing is also an emerging issue,
6.2 Income taxation
The government has decided that fiscal consolidation should be achieved without
any increase in the overall level of taxation. The structure of taxation Is, however, to
be c h a n g ed in order to facilitate employment. In practice, this involves taking steps
to ease income taxation and increase environmental a nd other indirect taxes. In
addition, the capital and corporate tax rates were raised from 25% to 28% In 1996.
An easing of the taxation of earned income was initiated in 1996, through a
reduction of employees' social insurance fees. The government has agreed similar
reductions in 1997 and 1998, as well as relaxation of tax scales in 1998. Beside capital
and corporate taxes, taxes levied on fuel as well as on gifts a nd inheritance were
raised and extra allowances for interest payments v/ere curtailed in order to finance
these changes in 1996. The funding of income tax changes in the future Is still to be
decided.
Scope for further shifts in the structure of taxation seem to be quite limited, The
government is committed to no increases in the general rate of value-added
taxation in 1996 and 1997. According to the Ministry of Finance, existing
environmental taxes like energy taxes cannot be raised further without jeopardising
the competitiveness of manufacturing industry. International co-ordination of energy
taxes is considered a prerequisite for any major advances. The possibility of any
increases in environmental taxes is focused chiefly on waste and final consumption.
However, such potential tax revenues are estimated to be quite modest.
The convergence programme a d o p t ed by the government in autumn 1995 stated
that despite substantial reductions in central government expenditure, there is barely
scope for a general reduction in tax rates in the near future. However, demands for
substantial easing in income taxation have b e c o me more c o m m on a m o ng
economists a nd politicians, although such demands remain highly contentious.
- 9 9-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
A working group established by the Economic Council discussed fiscal policy in a
report delivered In February 1996. The group argued that under conditions of rapid
increases in public Indebtedness, the expansionary effects of the large public deficits
were less favourable than in circumstances in which there is better control of public
indebtedness. The effect could not be explained solely by the deficit-driven rises in
interest rates, but it also worked through increases in uncertainty and deterioration in
households' expectations about future disposable Income. The working group
emphasised the importance of a consistent fiscal policy with no risks to be taken in
public balances, either through expenditure increases or tax cuts. A stable
economic policy was considered vital in order to avoid harmful rises in interest rates
and to dispel the current lack of confidence among households and businesses.
In the ongoing policy debate, the issue is far from settled, however. At one end,
considerable across-the-board easing in income taxation is called for, even at the
expense of major cuts In public expenditure. At the other end, substantial cuts In
public expenditure In order to finance tax reductions are dismissed and a high
priority is placed on targeted measures for reducing the tax wedge. Two types of
targeting are advocated - targeting people on low incomes and targeting the
consumption of personal services. Targeting low-Income people, for example
through work-related tax allowances, is based on two premises, First, long-term
unemployment constitutes the worst structural problem, and the ongoing tendency
towards labour market polarisation threatens to aggravate the problem. Second,
the highest marginal tax rates apply to those with the lowest Incomes, not the
highest incomes, because means-tested transfers give rise to an implicit positive
marginal tax rate. If the benefits of government programmes were work-related,
either directly or via taxes paid, the effective marginal tax rate would be lowered.
Enhancing the employment-intensity of growth, in turn, calls for the targeting of
personal services through, for example, a selective reduction In value-added tax
rates or grading the level of employers' mandatory social security contributions.
There is some further discussion about other demand-side measures to provide an
inducement for firms to hire low-skilled workers. One suggestion has been to make
employers' payroll taxes progressive, through individual grading relating to monthly
pay. It is claimed that this could also induce employers to offer a wider selection of
part-time employment opportunities. This kind of measure may be viewed primarily
as an income maintenance scheme, but the argument is that it could be one with
fewer effects on labour force participation than would result from most welfare
programmes.
100-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
6.3 Labour market deregulation
Labour market regulation in Finland has differed little from that in other European
countries. In line with the general tendency in Europe to search for a new balance
between employment protection and flexibility, much concern in Finland has
focused on designing structural reforms that may Improve the functioning of the
labour market In the medium term. As a result, a few amendments concerning pre-
notification periods, fixed-term employment relationships and flexible working time
arrangements have been recently Introduced or agreed upon, and a few more
reforms are being planned.
Instead of using such incremental reforms, a more profound deregulation has been
called for as a remedy to exceptionally high unemployment. Most of the
recommendations aimed at increasing flexibility involve the removal of existing
constraints that are thought to worsen the functioning of the labour market.
Eliminating negative influences - rather than accentuating positive ones through
training, mobility or active labour market policies - has, therefore, become the basis
for improving the operation of the labour market.
The pursuit of deregulation focuses chiefly on employment security provisions and
determination of wages. Criticisms of the universally binding collective agreements
can be interpreted as a demand for greater room to adjust wage changes to local
workplace conditions and for lower minimum wages. At present, firms can recruit
new employees at lower wages than those paid to existing staff, as long as the pay is
in line with minimum standards laid down in collective agreements. However, in
addition to initial pay levels, collective agreements also prescribe subsequent
minimum pay increases irrespective of the level of actual pay relative to scheduled
pay. There is some consensus to move towards local pay bargaining, as long as
there Is adherence to the minimum standards on scheduled pay.
The issue of minimum wages is more controversial. Wage differentials have increased
substantially since the mid-1980s and the risk of young people being particularly hard
hit by minimum wages seem largely to be have been averted, The potentially
detrimental effects have been mitigated by setting minimum wages for young
people at a lower level than those for adults, and by scaling employers' social
security contributions by age (in firms employing at least 50 people). Such measures
clearly favour the employment of young people.
A further issue concerning minimum wages has been highlighted by the OECD Jobs
Study. This called for a reassessment of the role of minimum wages as an instrument
to achieve re-distributive goals and to switch to more direct measures. Abolishing
minimum wages by increasing income transfers is a further proposal. However, it is
also argued that income transfer schemes emphasise, rather than reduce, the role
of minimum wages. The point is that minimum wages function to prevent social
welfare from being transferred to employers in the guise of low pay. If so, minimum
wages may be an essential element in any strategy involving social welfare and
labour market policies, if the package is to be both socially equitable and
economically efficient.
101
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Minimum wages have multiple functions, including that of raising productivity. Low
wages encourage low productivity and favour enterprises unconcerned with long-
term employment relationships and skill upgrading. Yet an eye for the long-term may
be important for dynamic efficiency - that Is, for increasing the volume and quality
of productive resources available to the economy in the long run,
6.4 Work sharing
Clearly, a major part of the pressure for increased flexibility of working hours has
come from firms. They have sought to increase the flexibility of hours of work so as to
match Increased variations in product demand. Flexible working time arrangements
have been increasingly introduced through collective agreements and the scope of
action will be extended by the comprehensive reform of the Hours of Work Act.
The government has introduced policies designed to improve employment by
means of reductions in the hours of existing employees on a voluntary individual
basis. Such measures include the job rotation scheme, part-time pay supplement,
part-time pension and 6+6 hours shift work. So far, the take-up of such schemes has
been rather low, partly as a result of economic factors and partly because of
employees' concerns to avoid giving their employers the impression that they lack
commitment. Employers themselves are not very keen to promote working time
arrangements that include an element of individual choice. Employers' organisations
also resist general reductions in regular working hours. As employment trends show
improvements, the idea of work sharing gains popularity. Since the voluntary basis of
the arrangements has hitherto led to tensions, it may be that a more prescriptive
approach can be put on the agenda.
Results from recent opinion polls suggest that there Is willingness amongst employees
to shorten working hours, at the expense of reductions in wages. Moreover, in the
last two decades, reduction of annual working hours has slowed markedly. However,
there has consistently been a large mismatch between people's actual and
preferred working time arrangements. There is little part-time working overall, but with
considerable variation between sectors. Indeed, from the employees' point of view,
there is excessive part-time work in some branches like retail and catering. Uniform
approaches may involve the risk, however, that the very diversified needs and
preferences of individuals, employers and society are met in an unsatisfactory way.
-102-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
REFERENCES
Aho, S 8c Koski, Ρ (1995) Yrittäjyyden rakennemuutos ja kasvualat (Structural c h a n ge
of and growth branches in entrepreneurship), Ministry of Labour, Labour study
106, Helsinki.
Allén, T & Kiander, J (1996) The social p a ct of Finland in 1995, European Trade Union
Institute, Brussels (forthcoming).
Asplund, R (1995a) Palkkaerot Suomessa ja muissa maissa (Pay differentials in Finland
and other countries), Kansantaloudellinen aikakauskirja, Vol. 91, No 4, Helsinki.
Asplund, R (1995b) The gender w a ge g ap In Finnish industry in 19801994, Research
Institute of the Finnish Economy, Discussion Paper 541, Helsinki.
Blöndal, S & Pearson, M (1995) Unemployment a nd other nonemployment benefits,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 11, No, 1, 136161.
Bordes, C, Currie, D & Söderström, Η T (1993) Three Assessments of Finland's Economic
Crisis and Economic Policy. Bank of Finland, Publications C:9, Helsinki.
Braunerhjelm, P, Heum, Ρ & YlãAnttlla, Ρ (1996) Internalization of industrial firms,
Implications for growth and industrial structure in the Nordic countries, The
Research Institute of the Finnish Economy, Discussion Papers No. 551, Helsinki.
Bruun, N (1987) Työelämän oikeudellistuminen Näkökulma suomalaiseen
kehitykseen (The juridlficatlon of working life A Viewpoint on Finnish
developments), Oikeus, Voi. 16, No. 1.
Centre of Economic Policy Research (1995) Unemployment: Choices for Europe,
Monitoring European Integration 5, London.
Economic Council (1996) Julkinen velka, kasvuja työllisyys työryhmäraportti (Public
debt, economic growth and employment a working group report), Helsinki.
Eriksson, Τ (1985) Some investigations into Finnish Unemployment dynamics.
Meddelanden från stiftelsens för Åbo Akademi forskningsinstitut, No 107, Turku.
Eriksson, T (1993) Unemployment in Finland, in A Björklund & T Eriksson (Eds.)
Unemployment In the Nordic countries, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Eriksson, T & Jäntti, M (1995) The Distribution of Earnings in Finland 19711990,
EkonomiskStatsvetenskapliga Fakulteten vid Åbo Akademi, Working Paper,
Turku.
Eriksson, T Se Pehkonen, J (1995) Unemployment flows in Finland; a timeseries analysis.
Working Paper No. 156, School of Business and Economics, University of
Jyväskylä, Jyväskylä.
European Commission (1995) Improving the effectiveness of labour market policy,
Employment In Europe, Brussels.
European Commission (1996) Finland, Institutions, Procedures and Measures, Basic
Information report by the MISEP network, Employment Observatory.
Giorno, C, Richardson, Ρ, Roseveare, D & van den Noord, Ρ (1995) Potential Output,
Output Gaps and Structural Budget Balances, OECD Economic Studies No. 24,
167209.
Halving Unemployment, Programme for Employment in Finland 19961999, October
1995.
Havén, Η (1996) Työttömyys tutkinnon jälkeen 19891995 (Unemployment after the
certification 19891995), Tilastokeskus, Education 1996:4, Helsinki.
103
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
llmakunnas, S (1994) Perhetuki ja syntyvyys (Family support and birth rate), Labour
Institute for Economic Research, Studies No 51, Helsinki.
Ilmonen, K 8c Kevätsalo, K (1995) Aylilkkeen vaikeat valinnat (Difficult choices of the
trade union movement), Labour Institute for Economic Research, Studies No 59,
Helsinki.
Julkunen, R & Nätti, J (1995) Muuttuvat työajat ja työsuhteet (Changing working
times a nd employment contracts), Ministry of Labour, Labour Studies No 104,
Helsinki.
Juuti, P, Mikkonen, I 8c Räisänen, H (1995) Three Essays on Labour Market Training.
Company, Individual a nd Policy Perspectives, Ministry of Labour, Labour
Studies No. 108, Helsinki,
Kalrinen, M, RantanenLahtl, A &. Uhmavaara, H (1995) Yhteistoiminta ty=elõmõssõ
(Cooperation a nd participation within enterprises), Ministry of Labour, Labour
Study 195, Helsinki.
Kauppinen, Τ (1992) Suomen työmarkkinamallin muutos (Transformation of Finnish
Labour Relations), Finnish Labour Relations Association, Publication 1, Helsinki,
Kauppinen, T. (1994) Labour Relations in Finland, Ministry of Labour, Helsinki.
Kettunen, J (1993) Reemployment of Finnish unemployed workers, Research Institute
of the Finnish Economy, Series A 16, Helsinki.
Kiander, J (1996) Työttömyysturvan rahoitus ja työllisyys (Financing Unemployment
Insurance in Finland), Social Insurance Institution, Social Security a nd Health
Reports 8, Helsinki.
Komiteanmietintö (1995) Perhe ja väestötoimikunnan mietintö (Report of the
Committee on Family a nd Population Affairs), No 1995:4, Helsinki.
Lehtinen, Τ (1996) Kansainvälinen palkkaverotusvertailu 1996 (International
Comparison of Pay Taxation), Taxpayers' Association of Finland, Helsinki.
Lehtinen (1996b) Taxation of Labour 1996 A Comparative Study of Seventeen OECD
Countries, Taxpayers' Association of Finland, Helsinki.
Lilja, R (1993) Unemployment benefit system and unemployment duration In Finland,
Finnish Economic Papers, Vol. 6, No. 1, Helsinki
Lilja, R, SantamäkiVuori, Τ 8c Standing, G (1990) Unemployment a nd labour market
flexibility: Finland, International Labour Office, Geneva.
Lilja, R 8c SantamäkiVuori, Τ (1992) Näkökulmia työttömyyden kohtaantoon
Suomessa (Perspectives on the incidence of unemployment ¡n Finland), Labour
Institute for Economic Research, Studies 41, Helsinki.
Ministry of Finance (1996) Valtiontalouden näkymät 19961999 (Prospects of Central
Government Finance in 19961999), Helsinki.
Ministry of Labour (1990) Labour Relations ¡n Finland, Helsinki.
Ministry of Labour (1994) The Finnish Labour Legislation, Helsinki.
Ministry of Labour (1995) Työolobarometri, Lokakuu 1995, Ennakkotietoja (Working
Conditions Barometer, October 1995, A d v a n ce Information), 7.12.1995, Helsinki.
Ministry of Labour (1996a) Työvoima 2010, Integroituva Eurooppa ja Suomen
työllisyysnäkymät (Labour Force 2010 Finland's Employment Prospects In
Integrated Europe), Labour Studies No. 130, Helsinki.
104
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Ministry of Labour (1996b) Selvitys epätyypillisiin työsuhteisiin liittyvistä ongelmista ja
niiden korjausmahdollisuuksista (A report on problems related to atypical
pattern of work and possibilities remedies), mimeo, 5.3.1996, Helsinki.
Ministry of Labour (1996c) Työllisyyskertomus 1995 (Employment Report 1995),
Publications of the Labour Administration, Helsinki.
Ministry of Labour (1996d) Polut yrittäjyyteen (Pathways to entrepreneurship), Helsinki.
Ministry of Labour (1996e) KEKO-kyselyn tuloksia vuonna 1995 alkaneesta
koulutuksesta (Results of the KEKO survey on the training started In 1995),
Helsinki.
OECD (1991) Unemployment benefit rules a nd labour market policy, Employment
Outlook 1991, Ch. 7, Paris.
OECD (1992) ICCP Review of Information and Communications Policies: Finland,
Paris,
OECD (1993) Earnings inequality: Changes in the 1980s, Employment Outlook, Ch. 5,
Paris.
OECD (1994a) Job gains and job losses In firms, Employment Outlook, Ch. 3, Paris.
OECD (1994b) Collective bargaining: levels a nd coverage, Employment Outlook, Ch,
5, Paris.
OECD (1994c) Labour standards and economic integration, Employment Outlook,
Ch. 4, Paris.
OECD (1995a) The public employment service in Denmark, Finland and Italy,
Employment Outlook 1995, Paris.
OECD (1995b) The OECD Jobs Study, Evidence a nd Explanations, Part II - The
Adjustment Potential of the Labour Market, Paris.
Pehkonen, J (1994) Long-term Unemployment in Finland: A Macro-Economic View, in
Proceedings of the Symposium on Unemployment, Government Institute for
Economic Research, Publications No 14, 96-121, Helsinki.
Pehkonen, J (1996) Displacement Effects of Active labour Market Policy: The Youth
Labour Market In Finland, University of Jyväskylä, School of Business a nd
Economics, Working Paper No. 158, Jyväskylä
Pekkarinen, J (1995) From golden a ge to crisis: patterns of stabilization policy In
Sweden and Finland compared. Transfer, European Review of Labour and
Research, Vol 1, No 4, 554-568.
Pekkarinen, J & Vartiainen, J (1995) Millaiseen työehtosopimusjärjestelmään?
(Towards which kind of collective bargaining system?), Talous 8c Yhteiskunta,
Vol.23, No, 3, 61-72, Helsinki.
Prime Minister's Office (1994) Vaihtoehto työttömyydelle 2.
Nuorisokansllapäällikkötyöryhmän loppuraportti (An Alternative to
Unemployment 2. Final report of the Working Group for the Youth Training and
Employment Programme), Helsinki.
Raatikainen, J (1993) Suomalaisen elinkeinotukijärjestelmän muutospaineet (Pressure
for change in the Finnish system of business subsidies), Government Institute for
Economic Research, Discussion Paper 43, Helsinki.
Rantala (1995) Aktiivisten työvoimapoliittisten toimenpiteiden työllistävyys
(Employment effects of active labour market policy measures), Government
Institute for Economic Research, Research Reports 25, Helsinki.
105-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Repo, Ρ (1994) Henkilöstörahastot Suomessa (Personnel funds in Finland), Ministry of
Labour, Labor Study 65, Helsinki,
Repo, Ρ (1996) Työlait ja työsopimukset Suomessa, Ruotsissa, Saksassa, Ranskassa ja
Britanniassa (Labour laws and collective agreements in Finland, Sweden,
Germany, France a nd Great Britain), Ministry of Labour, Labour Study 128,
Helsinki.
Robinson, Ρ (1994) Is there an explanation for rising pay inequality in the UK?, Centre
for Economic Performance, London School of Economics, Discussion Paper
206, London.
Rytkönen, Ρ (1995) Työlllsyystilastot ja työllisyyden mittaaminen kansantalouden
tilinpidossa (Employment statistics and measurement of employment in
National Accounts), Helsinki (unpublished).
Saari, E (1996) Joustoilla työtä? (Employment by way of w a ge flexibility?),
Työministeriö, Työpoliittinen tutkimus 139, Helsinki.
Sandqvist, L (1996) Palkansaajien järjestäytyminen Suomessa 1994 (Unionisation of
employees in Finland in 1994), Ministry of Labour, Labour Study (forthcoming),
Helsinki,
SantamäkiVuori, Τ (1995) Työttömyysturva, palkkaerot ja kasaantuva työttömyys
(Unemployment benefits, w a ge differentials and accumulating
unemployment), Talous 8c Yhteiskunta, Vol. 23, 2/1995, Helsinki.
SantamäkiVuori, Τ (1996a) Labour market experiences a m o ng young people In
Finland during the recession years 199194, Paper presented at a Nordic
Conference on Youth Unemployment, January 1996. Forthcoming in the
publication NORD by the Nordic Council of Ministers.
SantamäkiVuori, Τ (1996b) Labour market experiences of the longterm unemployed
in 19921994, Ministry of Labour, Labour Studies No, 131, Helsinki,
SantamäkiVuori, Τ (1996c) Varttuneet alakynnessä Miten lievittää ikäsyrjlntää
työmarkkinoilla? (Older people beaten How to alleviate a ge discrimination in
the working life?), Talous 8c yhteiskunta 2/1996, 4349,
SantamäkiVuori, Τ 8c Sauramo, Ρ (1995) Nuorten työttömyys Suomessa vuosina 1993
1994 (Youth unemployment in Finland in 19931994), Labour Studies No 107,
Ministry of Labour, Helsinki.
Simpanen, M (1993) Aikulskoulutustutkimus 1990, Aikuiskoulutus ja työelämä (Adult
Education Survey, Adult Education and Working Life), Statistics Finland, Studies
201, Helsinki.
Simpanen, M 8c Blomqvist, I (1993) Aikuiskoulutustutkimus 1990, Aikuiskoulutukseen
osallistuminen (Adult Education Survey, Participation In Adult Education),
Statistics Finland, Studies 192, Helsinki.
Social Insurance Institution (1995) Statistical Yearbook 1994, Helsinki.
Statistics Finland (1994) Education in Finland 1994, Education Statistics and Indicators,
Education 1994:3, Helsinki.
Statistics Finland (1995a) Labour Force: Educational Level and Occupations 1984
1993/1994, Labour Market Statistics 1995:7, Helsinki.
Statistics Finland (1995b) Prices and Wages Review 1995, Wages and Salaries 1995:4,
Helsinki.
Statistics Finland (1995c) Corporate enterprises and personal businesses in Finland
1993, Enterprises 1995:4, Helsinki.
106
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Statistics Finland (1995d) Työvoiman liikkuvuus ja työelämän joustot (Mobility of
Labour and Flexibility of Working Life), Labour Market Statistics 1995:12, Helsinki.
Statistics Finland (1995e) Statistical Yearbook of Finland 1995, Helsinki.
Suomen Yrittäjät (Finnish Entrepreneurs) (1996) Joustotiedustelu (Flexibility Survey),
February, Helsinki.
Tulopoliittinen selvitystoimikunta (Incomes Policy Information Commission) (1995)
Inflaatioraportti (Inflation report), 6.4.1995, Helsinki.
Tyrväinen, Τ (1995) Wage Determination, Taxes, and Employment: Evidence from
Finland, Bank of Finland Studies E:3, Helsinki.
Vartia, Ρ 8c YläAnttila, Ρ (1992) Kansantalous 2017 (Economy in 2017), The Research
Institute of the Finnish Economy, Series B80, Helsinki.
Ylöstalo, Ρ 8c Kauppinen, Τ (1995) Työolobarometri, marraskuu 1994 (Working
Conditions Barometer, November 1994), Labour Studies No. 112, Helsinki.
107
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
INDEX
Active labour market policy measures, 39, 69, 70.
Fiscal policy, 36, 86, 87, 100
73.75,77,83,84,87
Affirmative action, 50
Age structure. 12, 15
Annual leave. 55, 58, 67
GDP, 12,69,86,89,94,97
Apprenticeship, 31, 63, 72, 77, 79, 84, 91, 94
Gender, 12-14, 17, 21, 24-26, 30, 31, 50
Β
Bargaining process, 40, 43, 45
Business sector, 20, 29, 30
Η
Halving unemployment, 86
Collective agreements. 31, 40-46, 49, 52, 54, 55,
Incomes policy, 32, 40. 41, 43, 45, 94
Income taxation, 37, 87, 94, 96, 99, 100
59,62,63,97, 101, 102
Collective bargaining, 41-43, 105
Convergence programme. 86. 87, 99
_
Deflation. 33, 37
Depreciation, 33
Disabled people, 50, 71,77
Inflation, 32-34, 36, 37, 45, 59, 86-88, 99
Job creation, 27, 53, 70, 90
Job gains, 28
Job loss. 19,21,27,28,49
Job rotation, 56, 58, 82, 84, 102
Earnings, 29. 30, 42, 43, 51, 52, 55-58, 61, 63-68,
Labour market support, 61-67, 84
Labour force participation rate, 12, 13, 15-18, 24
Long-term unemployment, 70, 71, 83, 90. 100
_
Manufacturing sector, 30, 97
Migration, 12-14.70
Minimum pay, 43, 101
Multi-annual employment programme, 53. 86. 94,
96
73,81,96
Earnings-related benefits. 63-65
Economic growth. 88. 89
Education, 18. 23, 24, 52, 63, 67. 78, 79, 90-94
Educational system, 90, 94
EFO model. 32, 34
Employment subsidies, 39, 72, 75, 79, 83, 94
Equal opportunities, 47, 50, 90, 93
European Commission. 37, 39, 69, 89
European Union, 12. 18, 20, 21. 37, 55, 69, 79. 87,
88, 94, 97
Exchange rates, 34. 36
- 1 0 8-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
N
NAIRU. 37
O
U
Unemployment allowance, 56, 61, 63-66, 68, 73
Unemployment benefits, 24, 39, 63-67, 70, 75, 87.
96
Unemployment insurance. 34, 35, 40, 61, 62, 68,
OECD. 18, 24, 25, 28, 31, 36, 37, 39, 40, 43. 69,
73, 94, 95
75,86,90.97, 101
Older people. 12. 15,24.67,69
Overtime, 21. 32,54,55,57,58
Passive measures, 69. 70, 87
Personnel funds, 46, 47
Unemployment pension scheme, 68
Unemployment rate, 15, 23-25, 27, 35-37, 70, 86,
89,91,95
Unemployment spells, 25, 26, 64, 70, 73, 74
Unionisation rate, 40, 65
Public employment service. 39, 75-76
Vocational training, 56, 67, 70, 72. 78, 79, 82, 87,
Population size. 12
Private sector, 15, 22, 29, 40-43, 46, 70. 72. 74. 77,
83
Profit sharing. 32, 45. 47
Public debt. 86
90-92
w
Wage differentials, 29, 30
Public sector. 15, 18, 20, 29, 40, 41, 43-46, 57, 70,
Wage drift, 42, 43
71,74,75,83,84,90
Working hours, 29, 30, 54, 55, 57, 58, 87, 96, 102
R
Recession. 13, 16, 19, 21-23, 25, 31, 32, 35. 36.
Young people, 13, 16, 17. 22, 24, 31, 45, 54, 59,
40.45,47,54,69-71,92
Recruitment practice, 50
63. 70, 73, 74, 77, 79, 83, 90, 91, 93, 101
Youth labour force, 14, 24
Services sector, 65
Social partners, 39, 41, 53, 55-57, 66, 92
Social security, 33-35, 37, 41, 65, 87, 96, 100, 101
Tax rate, 35, 65, 94. 95, 99, 100
Tax wedge, 37, 68, 87, 94, 95, 100
Taxation, 18, 35, 37, 47, 87, 94-96, 99, 100
Temporary work, 22. 39, 50, 63, 75
Trade unions, 39, 40, 42. 43, 45, 61
Training, 27, 31, 39. 45. 46, 50-52, 56. 58, 63. 66.
67, 70-75, 77-80, 82-84, 87. 90-94, 98, 101
109-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
ANNEX
110-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table A l: Total population Π.000) by aae and gender, 1980-1995
FEMALES
Aged 0-14
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
Aged 75+
MALES
Aged 0-14
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
Aged 75+
1980
1985
J990
1995
475
187
187
844
409
233
133
496
195
197
879
338
147
60
465
172
185
897
412
228
156
487
179
194
937
362
141
67
471
147
171
937
408
235
196
492
154
177
979
379
151
85
476
160
148
965
413
251
207
498
167
155
1003
397
178
89
Source: Statistics Finland, Population Statistics.
Table A2: Labour force (Ί,OOP') by age and gender, 1980-1995
FEMALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
MALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
1980
1985
1990
1995
68
128
710
223
13
84
140
823
228
25
64
132
783
240
11
63
141
888
230
15
56
116
811
223
7
55
130
919
227
12
38
83
819
241
5
39
99
923
240
9
Table A3: Employment d,0001 by aae a nd gender, 1980-1995
FEMALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
MALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
7950
1985
1990
1995
52
111
792
216
7
49
121
888
219
12
27
59
697
200
5
26
70
783
193
9
58
120
685
212
13
73
131
792
218
25
56
123
759
225
11
54
130
849
217
15
111
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table A4: Unemployment CI,0001 by a ae a nd gender, 1980-1995
FEMALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
MALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
1980
1985
1990
1995
9
9
25
10
-
11
8
32
9
-
8
9
25
14
-
10
12
39
13
-
4
5
17
7
-
6
9
30
8
-
11
23
122
42
-
13
30
141
47
-
Tgble A5: Lgbour force porticipgtion rgtes by g ge g nd gender, 1980-1995
FEMALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
MALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
Aged 65-74
1980
1985
1990
1995
36.2
68.5
84.1
54.5
5.6
43.2
71.0
93.6
67.5
15.0
37.1
71.4
87.3
58.3
4.9
35.4
73.0
94.8
63,5
10.8
38,0
68.2
86.6
54.7
3.0
35.7
73.2
93.9
59.9
7.8
23.8
55.6
84.9
58.4
2.0
23.3
63.9
92.0
60.5
5.0
Table A6: Unemployment rates bv aae and gender. 1980-1995
FEMALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
MALES
Aged 15-19
Aged 20-24
Aged 25-49
Aged 50-64
1980
1985
1990
1995
14,0
6.7
3.5
4.5
13.1
6,1
3.9
3.9
12.9
6.9
3.2
5,8
15.4
8.3
4.4
5,6
7.0
4,4
2.1
3.1
10.3
7.3
3.3
3.5
29.8
28.0
14.9
17.4
34.1
30.0
15.3
19.6
112-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table A7: Changes in labour force, employment a nd unemployment by region CI ,000
people-). 1980-1995
Labour Force
Uusimaa
Rest of:
Southern Finland
Central Finland
Northern Finland
Country
Employment
Uusimaa
Rest of:
Southern Finland
Central Finland
Northern Finland
Country
Unemployment
Uusimaa
Rest of:
Southern Finland
Central Finland
Northern Finland
Country
1980
1990
1995
Change
1980-90
Change
1990-95
619
700
702
+81
887
557
380
2442
899
565
390
2555
871
543
381
2497
+12
+8
+10
+113
+2
-28
-22
-9
-58
602
691
610
+89
-81
848
532
347
2328
867
542
367
2467
717
441
299
2068
+19
+10
+20
+ 139
-150
-101
-68
-399
17
39
25
33
114
9
32
23
23
88
92
154
102
82
430
-8
+83
-7
-2
-10
-26
+122
+79
+59
+342
Source: Statistics Finland, Labour Force Survey.
Table A8: Employment a nd the proportion of w o m en bv occupation, 1994
% OF TOTAL
EMPLOYMENT
% OF WOMEN
INOCCUPATION
Technical, scientific,
juridical, humanistic
and artistic work
Health care and social work
Managerial, administrative
and clerical work
Commercial work
Agricultural, forestry
and fishing work
Transport and
communication work
Manufacturing, machine
operation, mining and
quarrying and
construction work
Service work
All occupations
15.2
12.6
16.3
9.6
8.3
6.2
20.3
11.0
100.0
42.4
88.4
64.3
54.7
34.3
19.5
17.9
66.3
48.5
-113-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table A9: Main reasons for working part time Cas percentage of total part-time employed,
a g ed 15-641, 1980-1993
Main reason
Lack of work or difficulty in obtaining a full-time job
Home-making or care of children
III health or age
Education or training
Economically not necessary to work longer hours
Nature of work
Other reasons or unknown
1980
1989
1993
17.7
22.5
8.9
13.0
6.5
13,6
17.8
7,1
16.0
7.1
28.9
4.3
17.6
19.0
45.8
10.7
7.3
20.8
2.4
9.1
3.9
Source: Statistics Finland, Supplementary Labour Force Survey
Table AIO: Fixed term employment contracts bv employer, aae, tenure of service a nd
gender Cas percentage of total employees, a g ed 15-641, 1982-1993
Current contracts:
Total
Central government
Local government
Private sector
Aged 15-24
Aged 25-34
Aged 35-44
Aged 45-54
Aged 55-64
Current contracts with a tenure of:
less than a year
1 -2 years
at least 3 years
Women
Men
7952
1989
1993
11.3
14.9
19.5
8.3
26.5
13.9
8.3
6.4
5.2
13,3
9.3
11.9
13,2
21.6
8.6
45.5
18.6
8.6
5.3
5.1
37.8
16.9
2.9
15.3
8.7
13.5
17.7
19.4
10.2
60.4
29.7
3.5
14.7
12.3
Source: Statistics Finland, Supplementary Labour Force Survey
114-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table Al 1 : Unemployed jobseekers Ctemporarv laid-offs excludedl bv the duration of current
unemployment spells in Finland, a sa percentage of total unemployed, 1981-1995
Vear
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
-12 weeks
53.0
49.6
47.4
48.2
48.7
46.3
47.3
51.0
55.5
61.3
54.0
39.3
31.0
27.9
28.4
Duration of the current unemployment spell
13-26 weeks
27-52 weeks
53- weeks
21.6
22.5
22.0
22.1
23.2
23.1
22.4
22.1
22.3
21.9
26.4
27.6
24.3
21.0
20.2
14.4
14.9
17.3
17,2
18.0
19.7
17.5
16.8
15.5
13.4
16.8
24.9
26.3
24.0
21.3
11.0
11.5
13.3
12.5
10.2
10.9
12.8
10.1
6.6
3.2
2.7
8.2
18.4
27.1
30.1
Average
24
25
27
27
25
25
26
24
20
15
16
22
30
39
45
Note: Older people retired on the unemployment pension scheme are not
included in the unemployment figures.
Table Al 2: Relative semi-annual outflow rate from long-term unemployment Cas percentage
of total long-term unemplovedl from the beginning of 1991 to mid-1995
Period
1991. 1-6
1991.7-12
1992. 1-6
1992.7-12
1993. 1-6
1993.7-12
1994. 1-6
1994. 7-12
1995. 1-6
Terminated spells
ofLTU(l)
Long-term
unemployed (2)
Total (3)=(l+2)
Relative outflow
rate
(1/3)Ί00
11 519
15 509
32 960
52 236
35 099
49 639
68 622
72 303
65619
3 330
6 500
17 020
35 300
62 800
97 600
120 950
132 700
136 600
14 849
22 069
49 980
87 536
97 899
147 239
189 572
205 003
202 219
77.6
70.5
65.9
59.7
35.9
33.7
36.2
35,3
32.4
Source: Statistics from the Ministry of Labour.
115-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Table Al 3: Registered employers and enterprises subject to turnover tax in 1984-1993
Year
1984
1986
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
Number of
employers
Personnel
98 900
104 700
117 800
122 700
129 000
126 800
125 700
117 300
Number
1,322 000
1,330 000
1,356 000
1,372 000
1,377 000
1,257 000
1,131 000
1,037 000
Annual Change
+1.2%
+0.4%
-8.7%
-10,0%
-8.3%
Note: To be included, firms must operate for at least six months and have a
turnover of at least FIM 47,000
Source: Statistics Finland, Business Register.
Table Al 4: Earnings dispersion in some OECD countries bv gender
Country
Finland
Germany
Japan
Italy
Canada
Australia
Austria
Belgium
France
Netherlands
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
Year
1990
1990
1990
1987
1990
1991
1989
1990
1991
1990
1991
1991
1989
D9/D5
D1/D5
Females
1.46
1.58
1.63
1.29
1.75
1.49
1.79
1.32
1.69
1.48
1.40
1.93
2.15
Males
1,60
1.65
1.73
1.56
1.75
1.59
1,65
1.37
2.11
1.65
1.57
1.99
2.14
Females
0.62
0.66
0.70
0.64
0,44
0.75
0.52
0.73
0.67
0.74
0.77
0.62
0.44
Males
0.58
0.71
0.61
0.75
0.44
0.70
0.60
0.73
0.66
0.72
0.73
0.59
0.38
Source: OECD (1993) ond Statistics Finland
116-
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Chart Al : The employment rate of young people Cthe shore of employed of the populotion in
the oge groupl in relotion to the employment rote of odults gged 2574, 19861995
Source: Stotistics Finlgnd, Lgbour Force Survey.
Chert A2: Developments in reol wgges gnd sglgrv earrings bv sector of employer, 19701994
~* Π57
180
160
140
120
100 r
80
60
40
20
♦— Private sector
■— Local govt
— Central govt
- ï — ι — ι — ι — ι — 1 ~ ~ ι — ι — ι — ι — ι — ι — ι — ι — ι — ι — τ — ι — ι — ι —ï —I — r — τ —I
70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94
Source: Statistics Finland, Index of Wages and Salary Earnings and Consumer
Price Index.
17
THE LABOUR MARKET IN FINLAND
Chart A3: Women's earnings relative to men's earnings, 1977-1994
77 78
Note: Data refers to total annual wages and salary earnings of people
engaged in full-time work for the whole year.
Source: Statistics Finland, Distribution of Incomes Statistics.
Chart A4: The ratio of product to consumption pay rise from 1980 to 1994
2.5
1.5
0.5
80
—ι—
82
84
ι
86
88
90
92
1
—ι
94
-118-
European Commission
Labour Market Studies — Finland
Document
Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities
1997 — 124 pp. — 21.0 χ 29.7 cm
ISBN 92-827-8754-0
Price (excluding VAT) in Luxembourg: ECU 29.50
N E D E R L A ND
C Y P R US
SDU Servicecentrum Uitgevers
Cyprus C h a m b er Of C o m m e r ce & Industry
Venta · Salg · Verkauf · Πωλήσεις · Sales · Vente · Vendita · Verkoop · Venda · Myynti · Försäljning
BELGIQUE BELGIË
G R A N D D U C HE DE L U X E M B O U RG
S C H W E I Z / S U I S S E / S V I Z Z E RA
ISRAEL
Moniteur belge Belgisch Staatsblad
Messageries du livre Sari
O S EC
Stampfenbachstraße 85
CH8035 Zurich
Tel. ( 4 1 1 ) 3 65 53 15
F a x ( 4 1 1) 365 54 11
Email: urs [email protected]
URL: www.osee ch
R.O.Y. International
17, S h i m on Hatarssi Street
PO Box 13056
61130 Tel Aviv
Tel. ( 9 7 2 3 ) 5 46 14 23
Fax (9723) 546 14 42
Email: [email protected]
Run de Louvain 4042/
Leuvenseweg 4042
B 1000 Bruxelles Brussel
Tel (322; 552 22 11
Fax ( 3 2 2 ) 5 11 01 84
Jean De Lannoy
Avenue du Roi 202
Koningslaan 202
B1060 Bruxelles Brussel
Tel (32-2) 538 51 69
Fax ( 3 2 2 ) 5 38 08 41
Email ¡ean de lannoy@intoboard be
Librairie e u r o p é e n n e ' E u r o p e se Boekhandel
R u e de la Loi 2 4 4'
Wetstraat 244
B 1040 Bruxelles'Brussel
Tel ¡ 3 2 2 ) 2 95 26 39
Fax ( 3 2 2 ) 7 35 08 60
J. H. Schultz Information A/S
Herstedvang 1012
DK2620 Albertslund
TU ( 4 5 ) 43 63 23 00
Fax ( 4 5 ) 43 63 19 69
Email [email protected]
URL: www Schultz dk
D E U T S C H L A ND
Bundesanzeiger Verlag
Breite Straße 7880
Postlach 10 05 34
D 5 0 6 6 7 K o ln
Tel (49-221)20 29-0
' ax (49-221)20 29 278
G R E E CE Ε Λ Λ Α ΔΑ
G.C. Eleltheroudakis SA
International Bookstore
Panepistirniou 17
GR105 64 Athens
Tel (301) 331 41 80 1.2 3
Fax ( 3 0 1 ) 3 23 98 21
Email: [email protected]
Mundi Prensa Libros, SA
Castello. 37
E28001 Madrid
Tel ( 3 4 1 ) 4 31 33 99 431 32 22
Fax (341) 575 39 98
Email: mundiprensa@tsai es
URL www.tsai es/mprensa
Boletín Oficial del Estado
Trafalgar. 2729
E28071 Madrid
Tel (341) 538 22 95 (Libros);
384 17 15 (Suscripciones)
Fax (341) 538 23 49 (Libros)
384 17 14 (Suscepciones)
URL www boe.es
Mundi Prensa Barcelona
Conseil de Cent. 391
E08009 Barcelona
Tel ( 3 4 3 ) 4 88 34 92
Fax (343) 487 76 59
Journal officiel
Service des publications des CE
26. rue Desaix
F75727 Paris Cedex 15
Tél. ( 3 3 1 ) 40 58 77 01 31
Fax (33 1 ) 40 58 77 00
Government Supplies Agency
Publications Section
45 Harcourt Road
Dublin 2
Tei ( 3 5 3 1 ) 6 61 31 11
Fax ( 3 5 3 1 ) 4 75 27 60
ITALIA
Licosa SpA
5. rue Raiffeisen
L2411 Luxembourg
Tel ( 3 5 2 ) 40 10 20
Fax [ 3 5 2 ) 4 90 661
Email: [email protected]
Abonnements
Messageries Paul Kraus
11 rue Christophe Plantin
L2339 Luxembourg
Tel (352) 499 8B 88
Fax (352) 499 888 444
Email: mpk@pt lu
URL: www mpk lu
Christoffei Plantijnstraat 2
Postbus 20014
2500 EA 'sGravenhage
Te!. ( 3 1 7 0 ) 3 78 98 80
Fax (3170) 378 97 83
Email: [email protected]
URL: www.sdu.nl
O S T E R R E I CH
Manz'sche Verlags und Universitäts
buchhandlung G m bh
Siebenbrunnerigasse 21
Posttach 1
A1050 Wien
Tel ( 4 3 1 ) 53 161 3 3 4 / 3 40
Fax (431) 53 161 339
Email: [email protected] at
URL: www.austna.EU net:81/manz
Imprensa NacionalCasa da M o e d a, EP
Rua Marquês de Sá da Bandeira. 16 A
Ρ1050 Lisboa Codex
Tel ( 3 5 1 1 ) 3 53 03 99
Fax ( 3 5 1 1 ) 3 53 02 94384 01 32
Distribuidora de Livros Bertrand Ld.5
Rua das Terras dos Vales. 4 A
Apartado 60037
P2701 Amadora Codex
Tel (351 1 ) 495 90 50 495 87 87
Fax ( 3 5 1 1 ) 4 96 02 55
S U O M I F I N L A ND
Akateeminen Kirjakauppa /
Akademiska Bokhandeln
Pohjoisesplanadi 3 9'
Norra esplanaden 39
P L ' PB 128
FIN00101 Helsinki/Helsingfors
Tel (358-9) 121 41
Fax (3589) 121 44 35
Email: [email protected]
URL booknet.cultnetfi/aka'index htm
BTJ AB
Traktorvägen 11
PO Box 200
S 2 2 1 0 0 L u nd
Tel (4646) 18 00 00
Fax (4646) 18 01 25
Email: btj [email protected]
URL: www.btj se 'media'eu
U N I T ED K I N G D OM
The Stationery Office Ltd
(Agency Section)
5 1, Nine Elms Lane
London SW8 5DR
Tel (44171) 873 9090
Fax (44171) 873 8463
URL: www.thestationeryotfice co uk
Bokabud Larusar Blöndal
Skolavordustig, 2
IS101 Reykjavik
Tel. ( 3 5 4 ) 55 15 650
F a x ( 3 5 4 ) 55 25 560
Via Duca di Calabria. 1/1
Casella postale 552
150125 Firenze
Tel 13955)64 54 15
Fax ( 3 9 5 5 ) 64 12 57
Email: [email protected]
URL: ICI382 cilea it Virtual Library bibliot vetrina
licosattl htm
NIC Info A'S
Ostenjoveien 18
Boks 6512 Etterstad
N0606 Oslo
Tel. (4722) 97 45 00
Fax (4722) 97 45 45
C E S K A R E P U B L I KA
NIS CR prodejna
Konviktská 5
CZ113 5 7 P r a ha 1
Tel (422) 24 22 94 33
Fax (422) 24 22 94 33
Email: nkposp@dec nis.cz
URL: www.nis.cz
38, Grivas Digenis Ave
Mail crders:
P O B ox 1455
CY1509 Nicosia
Tel (357-2)44 95 00/46 23 12
Fax (3572) 361 044
Email: [email protected]
M A G Y A R Q R S Z ÁG
Euro Info Service
Europa Haz
Margitsziqet
PO Box 4*75
H-1396 Budapest 62
Tel. (36-1) 11 16 061/11 16 216
Fax (36-11 302 50 35
Email: [email protected]
URL: www.euroinfo.hu/index.htm
MALTA
Miller Distributors Ltd
Malta International Airport
PO Box 25
LQA 05 Malta
Tel. (356) 66 44 88
Fax ( 3 5 6 ) 67 67 99
P O L S KA
Ars Polona
Krakowsk e Przedmiescie 7
Skr poeztowa 1001
PL00950 Warszawa
Tel (482) 26 12 01
Fax (482) 26 62 40
T U R K I YE
Dünya Infotel A.S.
Istiklãl C a d. No: 469
TR80050 TünelIstanbul
Tel. ( 9 0 2 2 ) 2 51 91 96
( 9 0 3 2 ) 4 27 02 10
Fax ( 9 0 2 2 ) 2 51 91 97
BALGARIJA
EuropressEuromedia Ltd
59. Bid Vitosha
BG1000 Sofia
Tel. ( 3 5 9 2 ) 80 46 41
Fax ( 3 5 9 2 ) 80 45 41
H R V A T S KA
Mediatrade Ltd
Pavia Hatza 1
HR10000 Zagreb
Tel. ( 3 8 5 1 ) 43 03 92
Fax (3851 ) 44 40 59
R O M A N IA
Euromedia
Str. Gral Berthelot Nr 41
RO70749 Bucuresti
Tel. ( 4 0 1 ) 2 10 44 01/614 06 64
Fax ( 4 0 1 ) 2 1 0 4 4 0 1 / 3 1 2 96 46
SLOVAKIA
Slovenska Technicka Kniznica
Nämestie slobody 19
SLO81223 Bratislava 1
Tel ( 4 2 7 ) 53 18 364
Fax ( 4 2 7 , 53 18 364
Email: [email protected] stuba.sk
S L O V E N IA
Gospodarski Vestnik
Zalozniska skupina d d
Dunajska cesta 5
SI1000 Ljubljana
Tel ( 3 8 6 ) 61 133 03 54
Fax ( 3 8 6 ) 61 133 91 28
Email: [email protected]
URL: w ww gvestnik.si
Subagent for the Palestinian Authority:
Index Information Services
PO Box 19502
Jerusalem
Tel. (972-2)27 16 34
Fax ( 9 7 2 2 ) 27 12 19
RUSSIA
C C EC
60letiya Oktyabrya Av. 9
117312 Moscow
Tel. ( 0 9 5 ) 1 35 52 27
Fax (095) 135 52 27
A U S T R A L IA
Hunter Publications
PO Box 404
3167 Abbotsford, Victoria
Tel. ( 6 1 3 ) 9 4 17 53 61
Fax (613) 9419 71 54
C A N A DA
Uniquement a b o n n e m e n t s'
Subscriptions only:
Renouf Publishing Co. Ltd
1294 Algoma Road
K1B 3W8 Ottawa. Ontario
Tel. ( 1 6 1 3 ) 7 41 73 33
Fax (1613) 741 54 39
Email: [email protected]
URL: fox N S T N C a z r e n o uf
E G Y PT
T he Middle East Observer
4 1, Sherif Street
Cairo
Tel. (20-2)39 39 732
Fax (202) 39 39 732
J A P AN
PSIJapan
Asahi Sanbancho Plaza #206
71 Sanbancho. Chiyodaku
Tokyo 102
Tel. ( 8 1 3 ) 3 2 34 69 21
Fax (813) 3234 69 15
Email: [email protected]
URL: www.psiiapan.com
S O U TH AFRICA
Safto
5th Floor Export House.
CNR Maude S. West Streets
PO Box 7B2 706
2 1 4 6 S a n d t on
Tel. ( 2 7 1 1 ) 8 83 37 37
Fax ( 2 7 1 1 ) 8 83 65 69
UNITED S T A T ES OF A M E R I CA
Bernan Associates
4611 F Assembly Drive
MD20706 Lanham
Tel. (301 ) 459 2255 (toll free telephone)
Fax (800) 865 3450 (toll (ree fax)
Email: [email protected]
URL: www.bernan.com
M E X I CO
MundiPrensa Mexico, SA de CV
Rio Panuco. 141
Delegación C u a u h t e m oc
M E 0 6 5 00 México DF
Tel. (525) 553 56 5 8 ' 60
Fax (525) 514 67 99
Email: 104164.23compuserve.com
R E P U B L I Q UE DE C O R ÉE
Kyowa Book C o m p a ny
1 F 1. Phyung Hwa Bldg
4112 Hap Jeong Dong, M a po Ku
121220 Seoul
Tél. (822) 322 6780 1
Fax (822) 322 6782
Email: [email protected].
A N D E RE L Ä N D E R ' O T H ER C O U N T R I E S'
A U T R ES P A YS
Bitte w e n d en Sie sich an ein Büro Ihrer
W a hl / Please contact the sales office of
your choice / Veuillez vous adresser au
bureau de vente de votre choix
rice (exciuuiriQ
;U 29.50
ISBN T2-fl27-fl7£i4-0
OFFICE FOR OFFICIAL PUBLICATIONS
OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES
789282"787540
|
Dyrektywa Komisji 97/6/WE z dnia 30 stycznia 1997 r. zmieniająca dyrektywę Rady 70/524/EWG dotyczącą dodatków paszowychTekst mający znaczenie dla EOG | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"animal nutrition",
"antibiotic",
"food additive",
"food chemistry",
"foodstuffs legislation",
"veterinary drug"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/bb896151-d74b-4918-acdc-cb20345cf86c | pol | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 250
PL
Dziennik Urzędowy Unii Europejskiej
03/t. 20
31997L0006
5.2.1997
DZIENNIK URZĘDOWY WSPÓLNOT EUROPEJSKICH
L 35/11
DYREKTYWA KOMISJI 97/6/WE
z dnia 30 stycznia 1997 r.
zmieniająca dyrektywę Rady 70/524/EWG dotyczącą dodatków paszowych
(Tekst mający znaczenie dla EOG)
KOMISJA WSPÓLNOT EUROPEJSKICH,
uwzględniając Traktat ustanawiający Wspólnotę Europejską,
uwzględniając dyrektywę Rady 70/524/EWG z dnia 23 listo-
pada 1970 r., dotyczącą dodatków paszowych (1), ostatnio
zmienioną dyrektywą Komisji 96/66/WE (2), w szczególności jej
art. 11,
a także mając na uwadze, co następuje:
na podstawie art. 11 dyrektywy 70/524/EWG Państwo Człon-
kowskie, które z powodu pojawienia się nowych informacji lub
ponownej oceny istniejących danych, dokonanej od czasu przy-
jęcia omawianych przepisów, dysponuje szczegółowym uzasad-
nieniem stwierdzenia, że stosowanie jednego z dodatków
wymienionych w załączniku I stanowi zagrożenie dla zdrowia
zwierząt
lub ludzi bądź dla środowiska naturalnego, może
przejściowo zawiesić zezwolenie na stosowanie tego dodatku;
Dania i Niemcy zakazały używania na swoich terytoriach anty-
biotyku awoparcyna w paszach zwierzęcych odpowiednio w
dniu 20 maja 1995 r. i w dniu 19 stycznia 1996 r. Zgodnie z
przepisami dyrektywy 70/524/EWG każde z tych dwóch
Państw Członkowskich powiadomiło inne Państwa Członkow-
skie i Komisję o przyczynach swoich decyzji, właściwie umoty-
wowanej szczegółowymi argumentami. Informacja ta została
przekazana przez Danię w dniu 20 maja 1995 r. i w dniu 13
lipca 1995 r., i przez Niemcy w dniu 5 marca 1996 r.;
Dania i Niemcy, argumentując, że przez paszę podawaną zwie-
rzętom ten antybiotyk glikopeptydowy wytwarza odporność na
glikopeptydy stosowane przez człowieka, przyjmują stano-
wisko, że awoparcyna przedstawia niebezpieczeństwo dla
zdrowia ludzkiego; ich zdaniem ten transfer odporności może
ograniczać skuteczność głównej kategorii antybiotyków zare-
zerwowanych wyłącznie dla leczenia poważnych infekcji
lub
zapobiegania im u ludzi i w związku z tym nie jest spełniany
jeden z wymaganych na mocy dyrektywy 70/524/EWG
warunków upoważniających do stosowania dodatku;
Komisja zasięgnęła opinii Komitetu Naukowego ds. Żywienia
ten
Zwierząt. Po starannym zbadaniu sytuacji Komitet
stwierdził w opinii wyrażonej w dniu 21 maja 1996 r., że z
braku elementów niezbędnych do ustalenia przyczyny i skutku,
jeżeli chodzi o rolę odpornych na glikopeptydy organizmów
pochodzenia zwierzęcego (enterokoki) lub ich genów w choro-
bach u ludzi, nie jest konieczne rezerwowanie stosowania
że
stwierdza,
zaproponowałby,
glikopeptydów wyłącznie dla użytku przez człowieka. Jednakże
i Niemiec zadają
Komitet uznaje fakt, że raporty z Danii
poważne pytania,
aby
i
ponownie rozważono stosowanie awoparcyny jako dodatku
paszowego od razu w przypadku wykazania, że możliwy jest
transfer odporności od zwierząt do człowieka. Ponadto jako
środek ostrożności Komitet zaleca, aby nie zatwierdzano
żadnego następnego glikopeptydu posiadającego to samo
położenie i mechanizm działania antybiotycznego co awopar-
cyna, dopóki nie otrzyma on zadowalających wyników badań,
które zostaną dopiero przeprowadzone;
podczas gdy istnieją niewystarczające dane do tego, aby ustalić
rozstrzygająco ryzyko transferu odporności, do którego
odwołują się Dania i Niemcy, dostępne dowody nie pozwalają
na wykluczenie tego ryzyka z pewnością, z braku dalszych
informacji naukowych;
powinno się podjąć różnorodne badania w celu określenia z
maksymalną dokładnością problemu możliwej odporności na
antybiotyki wywołanej stosowaniem dodatków w paszy zwie-
rzęcej
i przekazanej człowiekowi. Trzeba szybko stworzyć
schemat nadzoru odporności mikrobiologicznej u zwierząt,
które otrzymują antybiotyki;
w tym klimacie niepewności bardziej wskazane jest wykazanie
najwyższej ostrożności
ryzyka
zmniejszenia skuteczności pewnych glikopeptydów, takich jak
wancomycyna, które są zasadnicze dla użytku przez człowieka;
i unikanie podejmowania
zakaz stosowania awoparcyny powinien być postrzegany jako
przejściowy środek ochronny stosowany jako środek ostroż-
ności, który można by było poddać ponownej rozwadze, gdyby
wyrażone wątpliwości w sprawie stosowania awoparcyny jako
dodatku zostały rozwiane w świetle przeprowadzonych badań i
utworzonego programu nadzoru;
środki przewidziane w niniejszej dyrektywie są zgodne z opinią
Stałego Komitetu ds. Pasz,
PRZYJMUJE NINIEJSZĄ DYREKTYWĘ:
Artykuł 1
(1) Dz.U. L 270 z 14.12.1970, str. 1.
(2) Dz.U. L 272 z 25.10.1996, str. 32.
W załączniku I do dyrektywy 70/524/EWG wprowadza się
zmiany wymienione w Załączniku do niniejszej dyrektywy.
03/t. 20
PL
Dziennik Urzędowy Unii Europejskiej
251
Artykuł 2
Komisja przed dniem 31 grudnia 1998 r. ponownie zbada
przepisy niniejszej dyrektywy na podstawie wyników:
— różnych badań dotyczących wykształcania odporności
przez stosowanie antybiotyków, w szczególności glikopep-
tydów, i
— programu nadzorowania odporności mikrobiologicznej u
zwierząt, które otrzymywały antybiotyki, prowadzonego w
szczególności przez osoby odpowiedzialne za włączenie do
obrotu dodatków, o których mowa.
2.
Państwa Członkowskie przekażą Komisji teksty podstawo-
wych przepisów prawa krajowego, przyjętych w dziedzinach
objętych niniejszą dyrektywą.
Artykuł 4
Niniejsza dyrektywa wchodzi w życie trzeciego dnia po jej
opublikowaniu w Dzienniku Urzędowym Wspólnot Europejskich.
Artykuł 5
Artykuł 3
Niniejsza dyrektywa skierowana jest do Państw Członkowskich.
1.
Państwa Członkowskie wprowadzą w życie przepisy usta-
wowe, wykonawcze i administracyjne niezbędne do wykonania
niniejszej dyrektywy nie później niż do dnia 1 kwietnia 1997 r.
i niezwłocznie powiadomią o tym Komisję.
Przepisy te zawierają odniesienie do niniejszej dyrektywy lub
odniesienie to towarzyszy ich urzędowej publikacji. Metody
dokonywania takiego odniesienia określane są przez Państwa
Członkowskie.
Sporządzono w Brukseli, dnia 30 stycznia 1997 r.
W imieniu Komisji
Franz FISCHLER
Członek Komisji
252
PL
Dziennik Urzędowy Unii Europejskiej
03/t. 20
ZAŁĄCZNIK
W załączniku I do dyrektywy 70/524/EWG część A „Antybiotyki”, hasło nr E715 „awoparcyna” skreśla się łącznie z
wszystkimi danymi szczegółami (wzór chemiczny, opis, gatunek lub kategoria zwierząt, maksymalny wiek, minimalna
zawartość, maksymalna zawartość, inne przepisy).
|
RÈGLEMENT (CE) N° 168/97 DE LA COMMISSION du 30 janvier 1997 modifiant le règlement (CE) n° 2993/94 fixant les aides pour l'approvisionnement des îles Canaries en produits laitiers dans le cadre du régime prévu aux articles 2 à 4 du règlement (CEE) n° 1601/92 du Conseil | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"Canary Islands",
"aid system",
"milk",
"milk product",
"supply",
"supply balance sheet"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/f4114a94-a4b1-44e3-b5aa-e675eb5bcea7 | fra | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
SCHRIFTLICHE ANFRAGE Nr. 155/97 von Amedeo AMADEO an den Rat. Verarbeitungserzeugnisse aus Zitronen | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU aid",
"citrus fruit",
"economic support",
"food processing",
"fruit product",
"production aid"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/13c80ef1-d42a-4b24-b30c-52d51c02a6a9 | deu | [
"print"
] | null |
COST 819 : Entomopathogenic nematodes: Activity report 1995. | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"disease vector",
"fight against insects"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/a9465891-ddf9-4fb0-8007-8aac9ec018f5 | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print_sftcv"
] | null |
SCHRIFTLICHE ANFRAGE Nr. 148/97 von Amedeo AMADEO an den Rat. Solvabilitätskoeffizient für Kreditinstitute | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"approximation of laws",
"credit guarantee",
"credit institution",
"financial solvency",
"ratio",
"share capital"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/762b4ae5-517f-4c96-9c18-1a5624baaa76 | deu | [
"print"
] | null |
KOMMISSIONENS FORORDNING (EF) Nr. 173/97 af 30. januar 1997 om ændring af de restitutionssatser, der skal anvendes for visse produkter fra korn- og rissektoren, der udføres i form af varer, som ikke omfattes af traktatens bilag II | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal flour",
"cereals",
"export refund",
"groat",
"meal",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/c59d856e-0ced-4bee-8347-9375a372f4a3 | dan | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGLAMENTO (CE) N° 173/97 DE LA COMISIÓN de 30 de enero de 1997 por el que se modifican los tipos de las restituciones aplicables a determinados productos de los sectores de los cereales y del arroz exportados en forma de mercancías no incluidas en el Anexo II del Tratado | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal flour",
"cereals",
"export refund",
"groat",
"meal",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/c59d856e-0ced-4bee-8347-9375a372f4a3 | spa | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
Yttrande från Ekonomiska och sociala kommittén om "För en förnyelse av relationerna mellan Europeiska unionen och ASEAN-länderna" | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"ASEAN",
"EU relations",
"cooperation policy",
"economic relations",
"trade relations"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/b5d765a2-9473-4767-b3f2-a69686fc3d10 | swe | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
KOMMISSIONENS FORORDNING (EF) Nr. 171/97 af 30. januar 1997 om fastsættelse af produktionsrestitutioner i korn- og rissektoren | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereals",
"production refund",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/d196500f-e7d3-4057-a252-876f0dc521b1 | dan | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
COMMISSION REGULATION (EC) No 173/97 of 30 January 1997 altering the rate of refunds applicable for certain products of the cereals and rice sectors exported in the form of goods not covered by Annex II to the Treaty | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal flour",
"cereals",
"export refund",
"groat",
"meal",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/c59d856e-0ced-4bee-8347-9375a372f4a3 | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
COMMISSION REGULATION (EC) No 172/97 of 30 January 1997 establishing the standard import values for determining the entry price of certain fruit and vegetables | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"citrus fruit",
"fruit vegetable",
"import price",
"perennial vegetable"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/6c824bec-9666-42d6-a7e0-91d65c0ba87c | eng | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
VERORDENING (EG) Nr. 166/97 VAN DE COMMISSIE van 30 januari 1997 tot vaststelling van de restituties bij uitvoer in de sector melk en zuivelproducten | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"export refund",
"milk",
"milk product"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/16f0e789-75e8-4867-bc90-7233569d9860 | nld | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
REGOLAMENTO (CE) N. 173/97 DELLA COMMISSIONE del 30 gennaio 1997 che modifica i tassi delle restituzioni applicabili a taluni prodotti dei settori dei cereali e del riso esportati sotto forma di merci non comprese nell'allegato II del trattato | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"cereal flour",
"cereals",
"export refund",
"groat",
"meal",
"rice"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/c59d856e-0ced-4bee-8347-9375a372f4a3 | ita | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
EEZ Apvienotās komitejas Lēmums Nr. 1/97 (1997. gada 30. janvāris), ar ko groza EEZ līguma II pielikumu (Tehniskie noteikumi, standarti, testēšana un sertificēšana) | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"European Economic Area",
"agreement (EU)",
"fire protection",
"inflammable product",
"motor vehicle",
"technical standard"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/66b16bb2-9d37-4df2-b829-444fc88fe0ec | lav | [
"html",
"pdf",
"print"
] | 224
LV
Eiropas Savienības Oficiālais Vēstnesis
11/2. sēj.
21997D0327(02)
L 85/66
EIROPAS KOPIENU OFICIĀLAIS VĒSTNESIS
27.3.1997.
EEZ APVIENOTĀS KOMITEJAS LĒMUMS
Nr. 1/97
(1997. gada 30. janvāris),
ar ko groza EEZ līguma II pielikumu (Tehniskie noteikumi, standarti, testēšana un sertificēšana)
EEZ APVIENOTĀ KOMITEJA,
ņemot vērā Eiropas Ekonomikas zonas līgumu, kas pielāgots ar protokolu, ar kuru pielāgo Eiropas Ekono-
mikas zonas līgumu, turpmāk “līgums”, un jo īpaši tā 98. pantu,
tā kā līguma II pielikums ir grozīts ar EEZ Apvienotās komitejas 1996. gada 13. decembra Lēmumu
Nr. 76/96 (1);
tā kā līgumā jāiekļauj Eiropas Parlamenta un Padomes 1995. gada 24. oktobra Direktīva 95/28/EK par to
materiālu degšanas režīmu, kurus izmanto dažu kategoriju mehānisko transportlīdzekļu iekšējā apdarē (2);
IR PIEŅĒMUSI ŠO LĒMUMU.
1. pants
EEZ līguma II pielikuma I nodaļā pēc 45.s punkta (Eiropas Parlamenta un Padomes Direktīva 95/1/EK) pie-
vieno šādu punktu:
“45.t 395 L 0028: Eiropas Parlamenta un Padomes 1995. gada 24. oktobra Direktīva 95/28/EK par
to materiālu degšanas režīmu, ko izmanto dažu kategoriju mehānisko transportlīdzekļu iekšējā
apdarē (OV L 281, 23.11.1995., 1. lpp.).”
Eiropas Parlamenta un Padomes Direktīvas 95/28/EK teksti islandiešu, un norvēģu valodā, kas pievienoti
attiecīgajai šā lēmuma valodas versijai ir autentiski.
2. pants
Šis lēmums stājas spēkā 1997. gada 1. februārī, ja EEZ Apvienotajai komitejai ir iesniegti visi paziņojumi
saskaņā ar līguma 103. panta 1. punktu.
3. pants
Šo lēmumu publicē Eiropas Kopienu Oficiālā Vēstneša EEZ iedaļā un EEZ pielikumā.
4. pants
Briselē, 1997. gada 30. janvārī
EEZ Apvienotās komitejas vārdā —
priekšsēdētāja
C. DAY
(1) Vēl nav publicēts Oficiālajā Vēstnesī.
(2) OV L 281, 23.11.1995., 1. lpp.
|
REGLAMENTO (CE) N° 170/97 DE LA COMISIÓN de 30 de enero de 1997 por el que se fijan las restituciones aplicables a la exportación de piensos compuestos a base de cereales | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"animal nutrition",
"cereal product",
"export refund"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/04408c59-a2d6-404b-9452-aeb9d64fa228 | spa | [
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |
SCHRIFTLICHE ANFRAGE Nr. 137/97 von den Abgeordneten Claudio AZZOLINI , Antonio TAJANI an den Rat. Abschaffung der Netze für den Schwertfischfang in Italien | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EC Decision",
"EU financing",
"FIFG",
"Italy",
"fishing net",
"fishing vessel",
"redevelopment aid",
"sea fish",
"summary procedure",
"vocational retraining"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/39620153-c815-4170-a277-f29c8cabbfb5 | deu | [
"html",
"print"
] | null |
SKRIFTLIG FORESPØRGSEL nr. 155/97 af Amedeo AMADEO til Rådet. Produkter forarbejdet på basis af citroner | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"EU aid",
"citrus fruit",
"economic support",
"food processing",
"fruit product",
"production aid"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/13c80ef1-d42a-4b24-b30c-52d51c02a6a9 | dan | [
"print"
] | null |
Regolamento (CE) n. 164/97 della Commissione del 30 gennaio 1997 che istituisce misure eccezionali a sostegno del mercato delle carni bovine in Francia in applicazione della decisione 97/18/CE | 1997-01-30T00:00:00 | [
"France",
"animal disease",
"cattle",
"slaughter of animals",
"slaughter premium",
"veterinary inspection"
] | http://publications.europa.eu/resource/cellar/e26a4d72-7e08-46b0-baab-ccb095300b9b | ita | [
"html",
"pdfa1b",
"print"
] | null |